Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release Market, 37058-37093 [E8-14444]
Download as PDF
37058
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
18 CFR Part 284
[Docket No. RM08–1–000; Order No. 712]
Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity
Release Market
Issued June 19, 2008.
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: In this Final Rule the Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission revises
its regulations governing interstate
natural gas pipelines to reflect changes
in the market for short-term
transportation services on pipelines and
to improve the efficiency of the
Commission’s capacity release program.
The Commission permits market based
pricing for short-term capacity releases
and facilitates asset management
arrangements by relaxing the
Commission’s prohibition on tying and
on its bidding requirements for certain
capacity releases. The Commission
further clarifies that its prohibition on
tying does not apply to conditions
associated with gas inventory held in
storage for releases of firm storage
capacity. Finally, the Commission
waives its prohibition on tying and
bidding requirements for capacity
releases made as part of state-approved
retail open access programs.
This rule will become effective
July 30, 2008.
DATES:
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
William Murrell, Office of Energy
Market Regulation, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
William.Murrell@ferc.gov, (202) 502–
8703.
Robert McLean, Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426,
Robert.McLean@ferc.gov. (202) 502–
8156.
David Maranville, Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington DC 20426,
David.Maranville@ferc.gov, (202) 502–
6351.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Order No. 712
Final Rule
TABLE OF CONTENTS
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
Paragraph
Numbers
I. Background ..........................................................................................................................................................................................
A. The Capacity Release Program ..................................................................................................................................................
B. The NOPR ...................................................................................................................................................................................
C. Comments ....................................................................................................................................................................................
II. Overview of the Final Rule ...............................................................................................................................................................
III. Price Cap Issues ................................................................................................................................................................................
A. Removal of Maximum Rate Ceiling for Short-Term Capacity Releases ..................................................................................
1. Maximum Rate Ceiling Interferes With Efficient Transactions ........................................................................................
2. Assurance of Just and Reasonable Rates ............................................................................................................................
a. Market Conditions Ensure Just and Reasonable Rates ...............................................................................................
b. Recourse Rate Protection ..............................................................................................................................................
c. Short-Term Customers Are Not Captive ......................................................................................................................
d. Non-Cost Factors ..........................................................................................................................................................
e. Oversight .......................................................................................................................................................................
3. Comments .............................................................................................................................................................................
a. Lack of Competition in Certain Areas .........................................................................................................................
b. Benefits From Removing the Price Ceiling .................................................................................................................
c. Promotion of Construction ...........................................................................................................................................
d. Changed Circumstances ...............................................................................................................................................
e. Exemption From Bidding for Short-Term Releases at the Maximum Rate ...............................................................
B. Removal of Price Ceiling for Long-Term Releases ....................................................................................................................
C. Removal of Price Ceiling for Pipeline Short-Term Transactions .............................................................................................
1. Removal of the Price Ceiling Is Not Justified .....................................................................................................................
2. Response to Specific Comments .........................................................................................................................................
a. Evidentiary Record .......................................................................................................................................................
b. Infrastructure Incentives ...............................................................................................................................................
c. Competitive Market Structure ......................................................................................................................................
d. Differences in Flexibility Between Pipeline Capacity and Released Capacity .........................................................
e. Bifurcation of the Markets ............................................................................................................................................
IV. Asset Management Arrangements ...................................................................................................................................................
A. Background .................................................................................................................................................................................
B. Discussion ...................................................................................................................................................................................
1. Tying .....................................................................................................................................................................................
2. Bidding .................................................................................................................................................................................
3. Definition of AMAs .............................................................................................................................................................
a. NOPR Proposal ..............................................................................................................................................................
b. Comments ......................................................................................................................................................................
c. Modified Definition ......................................................................................................................................................
4. Supply AMAs .......................................................................................................................................................................
5. AMA Profit Sharing Arrangements .....................................................................................................................................
6. Exemption From Buy/Sell Prohibition ...............................................................................................................................
7. Other AMA Terms and Conditions .....................................................................................................................................
8. Posting and Reporting Requirements ..................................................................................................................................
9. Part 157 Capacity ...............................................................................................................................................................
V. Tying of Storage Capacity and Inventory .........................................................................................................................................
VI. Liquefied Natural Gas ......................................................................................................................................................................
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
2.
2.
15.
19.
24.
30.
30.
32.
38.
39.
48.
50.
51.
55.
57.
58.
63.
67.
68.
72.
74.
81.
82.
87.
87.
90.
92.
95.
103.
109.
110.
118.
127.
132.
138.
138.
141.
144.
148.
154.
163.
170.
172.
178.
186.
191.
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
37059
TABLE OF CONTENTS—Continued
Paragraph
Numbers
VII. State Mandated Retail Unbundling ................................................................................................................................................
VIII. Implementation Schedule ..............................................................................................................................................................
IX. Information Collection Statement ...................................................................................................................................................
X. Environmental Analysis ....................................................................................................................................................................
XI. Regulatory Flexibility Act ................................................................................................................................................................
XII. Document Availability ....................................................................................................................................................................
XIII. Effective Date and Congressional Notification .............................................................................................................................
Before Commissioners: Joseph T.
Kelliher, Chairman; Suedeen G. Kelly,
Marc Spitzer, Philip D. Moeller, and
Jon Wellinghoff.
Order No. 712
Final Rule
Issued June 19, 2008.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
1. In this Final Rule, the Commission
revises its Part 284 regulations
concerning the release of firm capacity
by shippers on interstate natural gas
pipelines. First, as proposed in its
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking,1 the
Commission will remove, on a
permanent basis, the rate ceiling on
capacity release transactions of one year
or less. Second, the Commission will
modify its regulations to facilitate the
use of asset management arrangements
(AMAs), under which a capacity holder
releases some or all of its pipeline
capacity to an asset manager who agrees
to either purchase from, or supply the
gas needs of, the capacity holder.
Specifically, the Commission will
exempt capacity releases made as part of
AMAs from the prohibition on tying and
from the bidding requirements of
section 284.8. Third, the Commission
clarifies that its prohibition on tying
does not apply to conditions associated
with gas inventory held in storage for
releases of firm storage capacity. Fourth,
the Commission will modify its
regulations to facilitate retail open
access programs by exempting capacity
releases made under state-approved
retail access programs from the
prohibition on tying and from the
bidding requirements of section 284.8.
This Final Rule is designed to enhance
competition in the secondary capacity
release market and to increase shipper
gas supply options. This rule will
become effective 30 days after
publication in the Federal Register.
1 Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release
Market, 72 FR 65,916, FERC Stats. and Regs.
¶ 32,625 (November 26, 2007) 121 FERC ¶ 61,170
(2007) (NOPR).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
I. Background
A. The Capacity Release Program
2. The Commission adopted its
capacity release program as part of the
restructuring of natural gas pipelines
required by Order No. 636.2 In Order
No. 636, the Commission sought to
foster two primary goals. The first goal
was to ensure that all shippers have
meaningful access to the pipeline
transportation grid so that willing
buyers and sellers can meet in a
competitive, national market to transact
the most efficient deals possible. The
second goal was to ensure consumers
have ‘‘access to an adequate supply of
gas at a reasonable price.’’ 3
3. To accomplish these goals, the
Commission sought to maximize the
availability of unbundled firm
transportation service to all participants
in the gas commodity market. The
linchpin of Order No. 636 was the
requirement that pipelines unbundle
their transportation and storage services
from their sales service, so that gas
purchasers could obtain the same high
quality firm transportation service
whether they purchased from the
pipeline or another gas seller. In order
to create a transparent program for the
reallocation of interstate pipeline
capacity to complement the unbundled,
open access environment created by
Order No. 636, the Commission also
adopted a comprehensive capacity
release program to increase the
availability of unbundled firm
transportation capacity by permitting
2 Pipeline Service Obligations and Revisions to
Regulations Governing Self-Implementing
Transportation; and Regulation of Natural Gas
Pipelines After Partial Wellhead Decontrol, Order
No. 636, 57 FR 13,267 (April 16, 1992), FERC Stats.
and Regs., Regulations Preambles January 1991–
June 1996 ¶ 30,939 (April 8, 1992), order on reh’g,
Order No. 636–A., 57 FR 36,128 (August 12, 1992),
FERC Stats. and Regs., Regulations Preambles
January 1991–June 1996 ¶ 30,950 (August 3, 1992),
order on reh’g, Order No. 636–B, 57 FR 57,911 (Dec.
8, 1992), 61 FERC ¶ 61,272 (1992), notice of denial
of reh’g, 62 FERC ¶ 61,007 (1993); aff’d in part,
vacated and remanded in part, United Dist.
Companies v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105 (DC Cir. 1996),
order on remand, Order No. 636–C, 78 FERC
¶ 61,186 (1997).
3 Order No. 636 at 30,393 (citations omitted).
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
194.
202.
203.
216.
217.
220.
223.
firm shippers to release their capacity to
others when they were not using it.4
4. The Commission reasoned that the
capacity release program would
promote efficient load management by
the pipeline and its customers and
would, therefore, result in the efficient
use of firm pipeline capacity throughout
the year. It further concluded that,
‘‘because more buyers will be able to
reach more sellers through firm
transportation capacity, capacity
reallocation comports with the goal of
improving nondiscriminatory, open
access transportation to maximize the
benefits of the decontrol of natural gas
at the wellhead and in the field.’’ 5
5. In Order No. 636, the Commission
expressed concerns regarding its ability
to ensure that firm shippers would
reallocate their capacity in a nondiscriminatory manner to those who
placed the highest value on the capacity
up to the maximum rate. The
Commission noted that prior to Order
No. 636, it authorized some pipelines to
permit their shippers to ‘‘broker’’ their
capacity to others. Under such capacity
brokering, firm shippers were permitted
to assign their capacity directly to a
replacement shipper, without any
requirement that the brokering shipper
post the availability of its capacity or
allocate it to the highest bidder.6
However, in Order No. 636, the
Commission found ‘‘there [were] too
many potential assignors of capacity
and too many different programs for the
Commission to oversee capacity
brokering.’’ 7
4 In brief, under the Commission’s current
capacity release program, a firm shipper (releasing
shipper) sells its capacity by returning its capacity
to the pipeline for reassignment to the buyer
(replacement shipper). The pipeline contracts with,
and receives payment from, the replacement
shipper and then issues a credit to the releasing
shipper. The replacement shipper may pay less
than the pipeline’s maximum tariff rate, but not
more. 18 CFR 284.8(e) (2007). The results of all
releases are posted by the pipeline on its Internet
web site and made available through standardized,
downloadable files.
5 Order No. 636 at 30,418.
6 See Algonquin Gas Transmission Corp., 59
FERC ¶ 61,032 (1992).
7 Order No. 636 at 30,416.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37060
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
6. The Commission sought to ensure
that the efficiencies of the secondary
market were not frustrated by unduly
discriminatory access to the market.8
Therefore, the Commission replaced
capacity brokering with the capacity
release program designed to provide
greater assurance that transfers of
capacity from one shipper to another
were transparent and not unduly
discriminatory. This assurance took the
form of several conditions that the
Commission placed on the transfer of
capacity under its new program.
7. First, the Commission prohibited
private transfers of capacity between
shippers and, instead, required that all
release transactions be conducted
through the pipeline. Therefore, when a
releasing shipper releases its capacity,
the replacement shipper must enter into
a contract directly with the pipeline,
and the pipeline must post information
regarding the contract, including any
special conditions.9 In order to enforce
theprohibition on private transfers of
capacity, the Commission required that
a shipper must have title to any gas that
it ships on the pipeline.10
8. Second, the Commission
determined that the record of the
proceeding that led to Order No. 636 did
not reflect that the market for released
capacity was competitive. The
Commission reasoned that the extent of
competition in the secondary market
may not be sufficient to ensure that the
rates for released capacity will be just
and reasonable. Therefore, the
Commission imposed a ceiling on the
rate that the releasing shipper could
charge for the released capacity.11 This
8 Order
No. 636–A at 30,554.
No. 636 emphasized:
The main difference between capacity brokering
as it now exists and the new capacity release
program is that under capacity brokering, the
brokering customer could enter into and execute its
own deals without involving the pipeline. Under
capacity releasing, all offers must be put on the
pipeline’s electronic bulletin board and contracting
is done directly with the pipeline. Order No. 636
at 30,420 (emphasis in original).
10 As the Commission subsequently explained in
Order No. 637, ‘‘the capacity release rules were
designed with [the shipper-must-have-title] policy
as their foundation,’’ because, without this
requirement, ‘‘capacity holders could simply
transport gas over the pipeline for another entity.’’
Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services and Regulation of
Interstate Natural Gas Transportation Services,
Order No. 637, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,091 at
31,300, clarified, Order No. 637–A, FERC Stats. &
Regs. ¶ 31,099, reh’g denied, Order No. 637–B, 92
FERC ¶ 61,062 (2000), aff’d in part and remanded
in part sub nom. Interstate Natural Gas Ass’n of
America v. FERC, 285 F.3d 18 (DC Cir. 2002), order
on remand, 101 FERC ¶ 61,127 (2002), order on
reh’g, 106 FERC ¶ 61,088 (2004), aff’d sub nom.
American Gas Ass’n v. FERC, 428 F.3d 255 (DC Cir.
2005).
11 Order No. 636–A at 30,560.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
9 Order
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
ceiling was derived from the
Commission-approved monthly
maximum tariff rates, necessary for the
pipeline to recover its annual cost-ofservice revenue requirement.12
9. Third, the Commission required
that capacity offered for release at less
than the maximum rate must be posted
for bidding, and the pipeline must
allocate the capacity ‘‘to the person
offering the highest rate (not over the
maximum rate).’’ 13 The Commission
permitted the releasing shipper to
choose a pre-arranged replacement
shipper who can retain the capacity by
matching the highest bid rate. The
bidding requirement, however, does not
apply to releases of 31 days or less or
to any release at the maximum rate. But
all releases, whether or not subject to
bidding, must be posted.14
10. Finally, the Commission
prohibited tying the release of capacity
to any extraneous conditions so that the
releasing shippers could not attempt to
add additional terms or conditions to
the release of capacity. The Commission
articulated the prohibition against the
tying of capacity in Order No. 636–A,
where it stated:
The Commission reiterates that all terms
and conditions for capacity release must be
posted and non-discriminatory and must
relate solely to the details of acquiring
transportation on the interstate pipelines.
Release of capacity cannot be tied to any
other conditions. Moreover, the Commission
will not tolerate deals undertaken to avoid
the notice requirements of the regulations.
Order No. 636–A at 30,559 (emphasis in the
original).
11. Subsequent to the Commission’s
adoption of its capacity release program
in Order No. 636, the Commission
conducted two experimental programs
to provide more flexibility in the
capacity release market. In 1996, the
Commission sought to establish an
experimental program inviting
individual shipper and pipeline
applications to remove price ceilings
related to capacity release.15 The
12 Order
No. 637 at 31,270–71.
CFR 284.8(e) (2007) provides in pertinent
part that ‘‘[t]he pipeline must allocate released
capacity to the person offering the highest rate (not
over the maximum rate) and offering to meet any
other terms or conditions of the release.’’
14 18 CFR 284.8(h)(1) provides that a release of
capacity for less than 31 days, or for any term at
the maximum rate, need not comply with certain
notification and bidding requirements, but that
such release may not exceed the maximum rate.
Notice of the release ‘‘must be provided on the
pipeline’s electronic bulletin board as soon as
possible, but not later than forty-eight hours, after
the release transaction commences.’’
15 Secondary Market Transactions on Interstate
Natural Gas Pipelines, Proposed Experimental Pilot
Program to Relax the Price Cap for Secondary
Market Transactions, 61 FR 41,401 (Aug. 8, 1996),
13 18
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Commission recognized that significant
benefits could be realized through
removal of the price ceiling in a
competitive secondary market. Removal
of the ceiling permits more efficient
capacity utilization by permitting prices
to rise to market clearing levels and by
permitting those who place the highest
value on the capacity to obtain it.16
12. In 2000, in Order No. 637, the
Commission conducted a broader
experiment in which the Commission
removed the rate ceiling for short-term
(less than one year) capacity release
transactions for a two-year period
ending September 30, 2002. In contrast
to the experiment that it conducted in
1996, in the Order No. 637 experiment
the Commission granted blanket
authorization in order to permit all firm
shippers on all open access pipelines to
participate. The Commission stated that
it undertook this experiment to improve
shipper options and market efficiency
during peak periods. The Commission
reasoned that during peak periods, the
maximum rate cap on capacity release
transactions inhibits the creation of an
effective transportation market by
preventing capacity from going to those
that value it the most and therefore the
elimination of this rate ceiling would
eliminate this inefficiency and enhance
shipper options in the short-term
marketplace.17
13. Upon an examination of pricing
data on basis differentials between
points,18 the Commission found that the
price ceiling on capacity release
transactions limited the capacity
options of short-term shippers because
firm capacity holders were able to avoid
76 FERC ¶ 61,120, order on reh’g, 77 FERC ¶ 61,183
(1996).
16 77 FERC ¶ 61,183 at 61,699 (1996).
17 Order No. 637 at 31,263. The Commission also
explained why it was lifting the price cap on an
experimental basis, instead of permanently, stating:
While the removal of the price cap is justified
based on the record in this rulemaking, the
Commission recognizes that this is a significant
regulatory change that should be subject to ongoing
review by the Commission and the industry. No
matter how good the data suggesting that a
regulatory change should be made, there is no
substitute for reviewing the actual results of a
regulatory action. The two year waiver will provide
an opportunity for such a review after sufficient
information is obtained to validly assess the results.
Due to the variation between years in winter
temperatures, the waiver will provide the
Commission and the industry with two winter’s
worth of data with which to examine the effects of
this policy change and determine whether changes
or modifications may be needed prior to the
expiration of the waiver. Order No. 637 at 31,279–
80.
18 Among other things, the data showed that the
value of pipeline capacity, as shown by basis
differentials, was generally less than the pipelines’
maximum interruptible transportation rates, except
during the coldest days of the year, and capacity
release prices also averaged somewhat less than
pipelines’ maximum interruptible rates.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
price ceilings on released capacity by
substituting bundled sales transactions
at market prices (where the market place
value of transportation is an implicit
component of the delivered price). As a
consequence, the Commission
determined that the price ceilings did
not limit the prices paid by shippers in
the short-term market as much as the
ceilings limit transportation options for
shippers. In short, the Commission
found that the rate ceiling worked
against the interests of short-term
shippers, because with the rate ceilings
in place, a shipper looking for shortterm capacity on a peak day who was
willing to offer a higher price in order
to obtain it, could not legally do so; this
reduced its options for procuring shortterm transportation at the times that it
needed it most.19 Throughout this
experiment, the Commission retained
the rate ceiling for firm and
interruptible capacity available from the
pipeline as well as for long-term
capacity release transactions.
14. On April 5, 2002, the United
States Court of Appeals for the District
of Columbia Circuit, in Interstate
Natural Gas Association of America v.
FERC,20 upheld the Commission’s
experimental price ceiling program for
short-term capacity release transactions
as set forth in Order No. 637.21 The
court found that the Commission’s
‘‘light handed’’ approach to the
regulation of capacity release prices
was, given the safeguards that the
Commission had imposed, consistent
with the criteria set forth in Farmers
Union Cent. Exch. v. FERC.22 The court
found that the Commission made a
substantial record for the proposition
that market rates would not materially
exceed the ‘‘zone of reasonableness’’
required by Farmers Union. The court
also found that the Commission’s
inference of competition in the capacity
release market was well founded, that
the price spikes shown in the
Commission’s data were consistent with
competition and reflected scarcity of
supply rather than monopoly power,
19 Order
No. 637 at 31,280–81.
F.3d 18 (DC Cir. 2002) (INGAA).
21 Specifically, the court found that: ‘‘[g]iven the
substantial showing that in this context competition
has every reasonable prospect of preventing
seriously monopolistic pricing, together with the
non-cost advantages cited by the Commission and
the experimental nature of this particular ‘‘light
handed’’ regulation, we find the Commission’s
decision neither a violation of the NGA, nor
arbitrary or capricious.’’ INGAA at 35.
22 734 F.2d 1486 (DC Cir. 1984) (Farmers Union)
(finding that a move from heavy-handed to lighthanded regulation can be justified by a showing
that under current circumstances, the goals and
purposes of the Natural Gas Act (NGA) will be
accomplished through substantially less regulatory
oversight.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
20 285
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
and that outside of such price spikes,
the rates were well below the estimated
regulated price.23 The Commission’s
experiment in lifting the price ceiling
for short term capacity releases ended
on September 20, 2002.24
B. The NOPR
15. On January 3, 2007, the
Commission, in response to petitions
from various gas industry participants
concerning issues related to capacity
releases,25 issued a request for
comments on the operation of the
capacity release program and whether
changes in any of its capacity release
policies would improve the efficiency of
the natural gas market.26 The
Commission also included in its request
for comments a series of questions
asking whether the Commission should
lift the price ceiling, remove its capacity
release bidding requirements, modify its
prohibition on tying arrangements, and/
or remove the shipper-must-have-title
requirement.
16. After review of the petitions,
comments, responses to its questions,
and available data, the Commission
issued a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(NOPR), proposing two major changes to
its capacity release regulations and
policies. First, the Commission
proposed to lift the price ceiling for
short-term capacity release transactions
of one year or less. The Commission
determined that the traditional cost-ofservice price ceilings in pipeline tariffs,
which are based on annual costs
recovered over twelve equal monthly
payments, are not well suited to the
short-term capacity release market,
because they do not reflect short-term
variations in the market value of the
capacity. Therefore, removing the price
ceiling for short-term capacity releases
would permit more efficient utilization
23 Id.
at 33.
24 Regulation
of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services and Regulation of
Interstate Natural Gas Transportation Services,
FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles July
1996–December 2000, ¶ 31,091 (Feb. 9, 2000), order
on rehearing, Order No. 637–A, FERC Stats. & Regs.,
Regulations Preambles July 1996–December 2000,
¶ 31,099 (May 19, 2000), order on rehearing, Order
No. 637–B, 92 FERC ¶ 61,062 (July 26, 2000), aff’d
in part and remanded in part, Interstate Natural
Gas Association of America v. FERC, 285 F.3d 18
(DC Cir. Apr. 5, 2002).
25 In August 2006, Pacific Gas and Electric Co.
(PG&E) and Southwest Gas Corp. (Southwest) filed
a petition requesting the Commission to amend
sections 284.8(e) and (h)(1) of its regulations to
remove the maximum rate cap on capacity releases.
Subsequently, in October 2006, a group of large
natural gas marketers (Marketer Petitioners)
requested clarification of the operation of the
Commission’s capacity release rules in the context
of asset (or portfolio) management services.
26 Pacific Gas & Electric Co., 118 FERC ¶ 61,005
(2007).
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37061
of capacity by allowing prices to rise to
market clearing levels, thereby
permitting those who place the highest
value on the capacity to obtain it. The
Commission determined that the data
obtained by the Commission both
during the Order No. 637 experiment
and more recently indicated that shortterm release prices reflect market value
of the capacity as revealed by basis
differentials, rather than the exercise of
market power. Moreover, the
Commission reasoned that shippers
purchasing capacity would be
adequately protected because the
pipeline’s firm and interruptible
services will provide just and
reasonable recourse rates limiting the
ability of releasing shippers to exercise
market power. Finally, the Commission
stated that reporting requirements in
Order No. 637 and the Commission’s
implementation of the Energy Policy
Act of 2005, specifically with respect to
market manipulation, give the
Commission an enhanced ability to
monitor the market and detect and deter
abuses. The Commission did not
propose to remove the price ceiling on
either long-term capacity releases or the
pipelines’ sale of their own primary
capacity.
17. Second, the Commission proposed
to revise its capacity release policies to
give releasing shippers greater flexibility
to negotiate and implement AMAs,
based on the Commission’s findings that
AMAs provide significant benefits to
participants in the natural gas and
electric marketplaces.27 Recognizing
that the linking of transportation
capacity with gas supply arrangements
would violate the Commission’s
prohibition against ‘‘tying’’ released
capacity to any extraneous conditions,
the Commission proposed to exempt
pre-arranged capacity release
transactions that met certain criteria 28
from the prohibition against tying.29
This proposal would permit a releasing
shipper in a pre-arranged release to
require that the replacement shipper
agree to supply the releasing shipper’s
gas requirements and take assignment of
the releasing shipper’s gas supply
contracts, as well as released
transportation capacity on one or more
pipelines and storage capacity with the
gas currently in storage.30
27 NOPR
at P 67–74.
Commission’s definition of AMA as
proposed in the NOPR is discussed in detail below.
29 NOPR at P 75–82.
30 In addition, the releasing shipper could require
that, upon expiration of the AMA, the replacement
shipper must return storage capacity included in
the release with an appropriate level of inventory,
28 The
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
Continued
30JNR2
37062
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
18. The Commission’s second
proposal to facilitate AMAs was to
exempt pre-arranged releases to
implement AMAs from competitive
bidding.31 The Commission stated that,
because the asset manager will manage
the releasing shipper’s gas supply
operations on an ongoing basis, it is
critical that the releasing shipper be able
to release the capacity to its chosen
asset manager. Requiring releases made
in order to implement an AMA to be
posted for bidding would thus interfere
with the negotiation of beneficial AMAs
by potentially preventing the releasing
shipper from releasing the capacity to
its chosen asset manager. The
Commission concluded that in the AMA
context the bidding requirement creates
an unwarranted obstacle to the efficient
management of pipeline capacity and
supply assets. The Commission
emphasized that AMAs would remain
subject to all existing posting and
reporting requirements.32
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
C. Comments
19. Over 60 entities from all segments
of the natural gas industry filed
comments on the NOPR. The vast
majority of those who filed comments
regarding the Commission’s proposal to
permanently remove the price cap for
short-term capacity releases of one year
or less support the proposal, generally
agreeing with the Commission’s
reasoning in support of removing the
cap. Many of the local distribution
companies (LDC), marketers, producers,
and end-users who support lifting the
price cap on short-term capacity
releases also support retaining the price
cap on long-term capacity releases 33
and/or primary pipeline capacity.34
e.g., to promise to replenish storage inventories to
a mutually agreed upon level.
31 See NOPR at P 83–90. Section 284.8 of the
Commission’s regulations require capacity release
transactions to be posted for competitive bidding
unless the transactions are at the maximum tariff
rate or are for a term of 31 days or less.
32 While the NOPR originally required that any
comments were due January 10, 2008, a number of
entities filed for an extension of that deadline until
February 8, 2008. On January 14, the Commission
granted an extension of time for filing comments
until January 25, 2008.
33 Those commenters include Direct Energy
Services, LLC (Direct Energy), New Jersey Natural
Gas Company (NJNG), Oklahoma Independent
Petroleum Association (OIPA), Reliant Energy Inc.
(Reliant), Statoil Natural Gas, LLC (Statoil), and
Weyerhaeuser Company (Weyerhaeuser).
34 Such commenters include Edison Electric
Institute (EEI), NJNG, NJR Energy Services
Company (NJR), Nstar Gas Company (Nstar), OIPA,
Piedmont Natural Gas Company, Inc. (Piedmont),
Statoil, Weyerhaeuser, and the Wisconsin
Distributor Group (WDG). American Gas
Association (AGA), American Public Gas
Association (APGA), and Independent Petroleum
Producers of America (IPAA) oppose lifting the
price cap for primary capacity, arguing that doing
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
These parties generally view retention
of these price caps as providing valuable
safeguards in preventing the exercise of
market power in the uncapped shortterm capacity release market.
20. Two commenters oppose the
Commission’s proposal to lift the price
cap for the short-term capacity release
market, arguing that the Commission
has not supported its proposed rule and
that the proposed rule would fail a costbenefit test.35 Other commenters
express concern over the potential for
capacity owners to exercise market
power under the proposed rule.36 For
example, some end-users of gas express
concerns about the concentration of
capacity ownership on lateral pipelines
and therefore argue that the Commission
should either not remove the price cap
for laterals or do so on a case-by-case
basis.37 Other parties generally urge the
Commission to carefully monitor
markets to ensure that they are
functioning properly. Some suggest a
final test period before permanently
removing the cap, periodic
reassessments of the uncapped market,
or a process to revisit the determination
if the market becomes dysfunctional.38
21. In general, commenters also
overwhelmingly supported the
Commission’s efforts to facilitate the
development of AMAs.39 Those
so would undercut a major premise for lifting the
price cap in the short-term secondary market,
namely, that the availability of recourse rates from
the pipeline will constrain the exercise of market
power in the secondary market.
35 Tenaska Marketing Ventures (Tenaska) and
National Energy Marketers Association (NEM).
36 See Comments of NEM.
37 Weyerhaeuser, Northwest Industrial Gas Users
(NWIGU), and Process Gas Consumers (PGC).
38 Direct Energy, OIPA, Honeywell International,
Inc. (Honeywell), Arizona Public Service Company
(APS) (arguing that the market currently served by
El Paso Natural Gas Pipeline east of California is not
competitive). Commerce Energy Group, Inc.
(Commerce Energy) suggests including a
contingency for replacing the price cap in
‘‘exceptional capacity situations.’’
39 See e.g., Comments of the AGA at 1–2,
Comments of APGA at 2–4; Comments of Atmos
Energy Corporation (Atmos) at 2–4, Comments of
BG Energy Merchants (BGEM) at 1–2, Comments of
BP Energy Company (BP) at 2, Comments of Direct
Energy at 3–4, Comments of Duke Energy
Corporation (Duke Energy) at 3, Comments of the
EEI at 6, Comments of the Electric Power Supply
Association (EPSA) at 2, Comments of Florida Cities
at 2, Comments of the Interstate Natural Gas
Association of America (INGAA) at 6, Comments of
Marketer Petitioners at 2, Comments of National
Grid Delivery Companies (National Grid) at 2,
Comments of NJNG at 1, Comments of the Natural
Gas Supply Association (NGSA) at 3, Comments of
NJR at 1, Comments of NWIGU at 6, Comments of
Nstar at 1–2, Comments of the Ohio Gas Marketers
Group (OGMG) at 1, Comments of Piedmont at 1,
Comments of PPM Energy, Inc., (PPM) at 1–3,
Comments of PGC at 5, Comments of the Public
Utilities Commission of Ohio (PUCO) at 5–7,
Comments of Puget Sound Energy, Inc. (Puget
Sound) at 8–9, Comments of Sequent Energy
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
commenters agree with the
Commission’s assessment that AMAs
provide value and benefits to market
participants and to natural gas markets
overall. Virtually all who commented
support the steps proposed by the
Commission to facilitate AMAs, though
many of those that support the
Commission’s proposal regarding AMAs
request that the Commission modify or
clarify the proposal in various ways in
order to permit broader use of AMAs
and greater flexibility in the terms of
permitted AMAs. They request, for
example, that the Commission permit
uncapped AMA releases of a year or less
to be rolled over without bidding,
clarify that profit sharing arrangements
in an AMA do not violate any
applicable price cap, relax the
requirements concerning the
replacement shipper’s obligation to
deliver gas to the releasing shipper,
exempt AMAs from the Commission’s
prohibition against buy/sell
arrangements, and allow supply side
AMAs. Williston Basin commented that
exempting AMAs from the tying
prohibition and bidding requirements
would encourage discrimination against
pipelines and provide preferential
treatment to asset managers.
22. The Commission also received
favorable comments on whether it
should clarify its prohibition against
tying agreements to allow a releasing
shipper to include conditions in a
storage release concerning the sale and/
or repurchase of gas in storage inventory
outside the AMA context. All comments
that addressed this issue supported
removing this prohibition for storage
services. They assert that a shipper
releasing storage capacity should be
permitted to require the replacement
shipper to take assignment of any gas
that remains in the released storage
capacity at the time the release takes
effect; and/or to return the storage
capacity to releasing shipper at end of
the release with a specified amount of
gas in storage.40 Commenters note that
tying storage capacity with storage
inventory will enable transactions to be
consummated more readily and that the
nature of the relationship between
storage capacity and storage inventory
calls out for a waiver of the tying rule.
Others add that the ability of releasing
shippers to ‘‘tie’’ storage capacity with
storage inventory such that releasing
Management, L.P. (Sequent) at 5–6, Comments of
the Financial Institutions Energy Group (FEIG) at 6–
7, Comments of Turlock Irrigation District (Turlock)
at 5, Comments of Ultra Petroleum Corporation
(Ultra) at 4, Comments of the WDG at 3, and
Comments of the Wyoming Pipeline Authority at 5.
40 Public Service Commission of New York
(PSCNY) comments at 20–21.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
shippers would be permitted to require
that replacement shippers take
inventory as a condition of release, even
in circumstances outside the AMA
context, will provide benefits to the
marketplace similar to those provided
by AMAs.41
23. The Commission also received
numerous comments on its inquiry
whether pre-arranged capacity release
deals necessary to implement retail
access programs should be treated as
similar to releases made as part of an
AMA, and thus accorded the same
exemptions. The majority of comments
on this issue advocated affording
capacity releases under state retail
choice programs the same blanket
exemptions from the tying prohibition 42
and bidding requirements as those
granted to asset managers.43 AGA, for
example, recommends that the
Commission add an exemption from the
bidding requirements for any
prearranged, recallable capacity release
from an LDC to a natural gas marketer
in accordance with the terms of a retail
choice program approved by a State
commission. AGA also asks that the
Commission clarify that LDC releases to
retail choice marketers would be
entitled to the same partial exemption
from the tying prohibition as would be
releases under AMAs. The SPSCNY
would extend the AMA exemption from
the tying prohibition to releases of
storage capacity conducted according to
state retail access programs.
II. Overview of the Final Rule
24. In this Final Rule, the Commission
is modifying its policies and regulations
concerning the release of capacity by
firm shippers on interstate pipelines in
order to enhance the efficiency and
effectiveness of the secondary capacity
release market. The Commission’s
capacity release program has created a
successful secondary market for
capacity.44 As a result, natural gas
41 Comments
of Marketer Petitioners.
commenters include AGA, Commerce
Energy, Duke Energy, Hess Corporation (Hess),
Interstate Gas Supply (IGS), NJNG, New York State
Electric and Gas Corporation (NYSEG), Rochester
Gas & Electric Corporation (RG&E), OGMG, the
Public Service Commission of North Carolina
(PSNC), South Carolina Electric and Gas Company
(SCE&G), SCANA Energy Marketing (SEMI),
PSCNY, and Sequent.
43 Those commenters include the AGA,
Boardwalk Pipeline Partners (Boardwalk), BP,
Commerce Energy, Direct Energy, Duke Energy, FPL
Energy, LLC (FPL Energy), Hess, IGS, NJNG,
NYSEG, RG&E, Nstar, OGMG, Peoples Gas System,
a Division of Tampa Electric Company (Peoples),
PG&E, PSCNY, PUCO, SEMI, Sequent, and the
WDG.
44 As the Commission observed in 2005, the
‘‘capacity release program together with the
Commission’s policies on segmentation, and
flexible point rights, has been successful in creating
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
42 Those
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
37063
markets in general, and the secondary
release market in particular, have
undergone significant development and
change in the sixteen years since Order
No. 636 and the inception of the
capacity release program. As this market
has developed, shippers and potential
shippers have sought greater flexibility
in the use of capacity. They seek to
better integrate capacity with the
underlying gas transactions, and are
looking for more flexible methods of
pricing capacity to better reflect the
value of that capacity as revealed by the
market price of gas at different trading
points. They also seek to implement
AMAs, in which capacity holders
release their capacity to asset managers
(generally marketers) that have greater
expertise in maximizing the value of
pipeline capacity and negotiating
beneficial transactions in the gas
commodity markets.
25. In this Final Rule the Commission
is taking actions to respond to the
industry’s request for greater flexibility
in the capacity release market and to
revise its policies and regulations to
reflect the changes and developments in
the marketplace. The first major revision
is the removal of the price ceiling on
short term capacity releases. The
permanent elimination of the price
ceiling for short term releases will
enable shippers to offer competitivelypriced alternatives to pipelines’
negotiated rate offerings and will permit
short-term capacity release prices to rise
to market clearing levels, thereby
allocating capacity to those that value it
the most. It will also provide more
accurate price signals concerning the
market value of pipeline capacity.
26. The Commission is also revising
its regulations and policies to
accommodate and facilitate AMAs, a
relatively recent development in the
industry. AMAs provide significant
benefits to many participants in the
natural gas and electric marketplaces
and to the secondary marketplace itself.
They maximize the utilization and value
of capacity by creating a mechanism for
capacity holders to use third party
experts to both (1) manage their gas
supply arrangements and (2) use that
capacity to make gas sales or re-releases
of the capacity to others when the
capacity is not needed to serve the
releasing shipper. AMAs result in
ultimate savings for end-use customers
by providing for lower gas supply costs
and more efficient use of the pipeline
grid.45 The Commission’s goal in
facilitating AMAs in this rule is to make
the capacity release program more
efficient by bringing it into line with the
realities of today’s secondary gas
marketplace.
27. To that end, the Commission in
this rule is adopting its NOPR proposal
to exempt capacity releases made to
implement AMAs from the prohibition
on tying and the bidding requirements
of section 284.8. The Commission is
also making several revisions to the
definition of AMAs as proposed in the
NOPR. The Final Rule modifies the
definition of AMAs proposed in the
NOPR to relax the delivery obligation of
the replacement shipper to the releasing
shipper and to permit supply side
AMAs. The Final Rule also clarifies that
short term AMAs may be rolled over
without bidding. Further, the Final Rule
clarifies that the price ceiling does not
apply to any consideration provided by
an asset manager to the releasing
shipper as part of an AMA. These steps,
requested by many industry
commenters that support the
Commission’s efforts in the NOPR to
facilitate AMA’s, will further enhance
the efficiency of AMAs by allowing
greater flexibility for parties to
customize arrangements to meet unique
customer needs while at the same time
ensuring that capacity releases that
qualify for the exemptions from tying
and bidding granted in this rule are
bona fide AMAs. The rule also extends
the benefits of AMAs to sellers of
natural gas, creating an even greater
diversity of potential suppliers and
participants in the secondary market.
28. The Commission is also revising
its policies to reflect the realities of
today’s marketplace by allowing a
releasing shipper to include conditions
in a release concerning the sale/and
repurchase of gas in storage inventory,
even outside the AMA context.
Allowing such arrangements reflects the
fact that in the storage context, storage
capacity is inextricably linked to storage
inventory. By permitting the tying of
releases of storage capacity to
conditions on storage inventory, the
Commission will enhance the efficient
use of storage capacity while at the same
time ensuring that releasing shippers
will have adequate storage inventories
for the winter.
29. The Final Rule also extends the
blanket exemptions from the prohibition
against tying and from bidding granted
to AMAs to capacity releases made to a
a robust secondary market where pipelines must
compete on price.’’ Policy for Selective Discounting
by Natural Gas Pipelines, 111 FERC ¶ 61,309, at P
39–41, order on reh’g, 113 FERC ¶ 61,173 (2005).
45 See Comments of BGEM at 2, Comments of BP
at 5, Comments of Nstar at 8, Comments of
Piedmont at 4–5, Comments of PUCO at 7,
Comments of WDG at 3.
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37064
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
marketer participating in a state
approved retail access program, finding
that such programs provide benefits
similar to AMAs.
III. Price Cap Issues
A. Removal of Maximum Rate Ceiling
for Short-Term Capacity Releases
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
30. In this Final Rule, the Commission
amends section 284.8 of its regulations
to eliminate the price ceiling for shortterm capacity release transactions of one
year or less. The Commission finds that
this action will improve shipper options
and market efficiency, particularly
during peak periods, by allowing the
prices of short-term capacity release
transactions to reflect short-term
variations in the market value of that
capacity. This will enable shippers to
better integrate capacity with the
underlying gas transactions, and will
permit more flexible methods of pricing
capacity to better reflect the value of
that capacity as revealed by the market
price of gas at different trading points.
The Commission has previously
provided pipelines with the flexibility
to enter into negotiated rate transactions
which are permitted to exceed the
maximum rate ceiling, and this rule will
permit releasing shippers similar
flexibility in pricing release
transactions.
31. At the same time, we are
convinced that the rates resulting from
removal of the price cap for capacity
release will be just and reasonable. The
data collected over many years shows
that the value of short term capacity
only exceeds the price ceiling in times
when capacity is scarce. These data are
confirmed by the data gathered during
the experimental release of the price
ceiling which showed that capacity
release prices exceed the price ceiling
only for brief periods of constraint.
Moreover, we are not relying solely on
competition to ensure just and
reasonable prices. We are maintaining
the rate cap on pipeline services that
will provide the same protection for
capacity release transactions as it now
does for pipeline negotiated rate
transactions. Further, we have required
informational postings of capacity
release transactions that will provide
transparency and facilitate the filing of
complaints if circumstances warrant.
The Commission will also continue to
actively monitor the release market.
1. Maximum Rate Ceiling Interferes
With Efficient Transactions
32. As we explained in Order No.
637,46 the traditional cost-of-service
46 Order
No. 637 at 31,271–75.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
maximum rates in pipeline tariffs are
not well suited to the short-term
capacity release market.47 Under the
traditional ratemaking methodology, the
Commission develops a maximum
annual transportation rate for each
pipeline that, when applied to the
pipeline’s contract demand and
throughput levels, will enable the
pipeline to recover its annual cost-ofservice revenue requirement. Each
pipeline’s maximum rates for services of
less than a year are simply the
maximum annual rate prorated over the
shorter period.
33. Such prorated annual rates bear
no relationship to the competitive rates
that would be established in the shortterm capacity market, particularly
during peak periods. The market value
of transportation service from the
production area to the downstream
market may be inferred by comparing
the downstream delivered gas price in
bundled sales to the market price at
upstream market centers in the
production area.48 As the DC Circuit
recognized in INGAA, ‘‘if the difference
between field prices and city gate prices
in a particular pathway is only $.07,
people will not pay more than $.07 for
the unbundled transportation.’’ 49 As
discussed in more detail below, the data
set forth in Order No. 637 and the
updated data in Figures 1 through 3
below concerning the implicit value of
transportation in the bundled sales
market demonstrates the variability of
transportation value in the short-term
market and the divergence between the
transportation value and cost-of-service
rates. This data shows that during most
of the year, the value of transportation
service is significantly less than the
pipelines’ annual cost-of-service
maximum transportation rates, but
during brief, peak demand periods, the
value of transportation service is
measurably greater than the maximum
transportation rates.
34. Because the existing capacity
release price ceiling does not reflect
short-term variations in the market
47 While the Commission offered pipelines the
opportunity to propose other types of rate designs,
such as seasonal and term-differentiated rates, only
a very few pipelines have sought to make such rate
design changes, although many pipelines have
taken advantage of negotiated rate authority.
48 In Order No. 637, the Commission explained
‘‘gas commodity markets now determine the
economic value of pipeline services in many parts
of the country. Thus, even as FERC has sought to
isolate pipeline services from commodity sales, it
is within the commodity markets that one can see
revealed the true price for gas transportation.’’
Order No. 637 at 31,274 (quoting M. Barcella, How
Commodity Markets Drive Gas Pipeline Values,
Public Utilities Fortnightly, February 1, 1998 at 24–
25).
49 INGAA at 31.
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
value of the capacity, the price ceiling
inhibits the efficient allocation of
capacity and harms, rather than helps,
the short-term shippers it is intended to
protect. The price ceiling operates to
prevent the shipper most valuing shortterm capacity on a peak day from being
able to obtain it, because that shipper
cannot offer a releasing shipper the full
value the shipper places on that
capacity. The price ceiling may also
reduce the amount of released capacity
available during peak periods. As the
Commission explained in Order No.
637, ‘‘As a result of the maximum rate,
firm capacity holders may not find it
sufficiently profitable to make their
capacity available for release. For
instance, a dual fuel industrial customer
might determine that it would be more
economic not to use gas, and to
substitute a different fuel, if it could
obtain a sufficiently high price for its
released capacity.’’ 50 Thus, during a
peak day the price ceiling may only
serve to limit a purchasing shipper’s
capacity options, with the result that it
must purchase gas in a bundled
transaction in the downstream market at
a price reflecting the market-determined
value of the transportation.
35. The increased use by pipelines
and shippers of negotiated rate
transactions based on gas price
differentials demonstrates that buyers
and sellers value the ability to calibrate
the price of transportation to its value in
the market. The maximum rate ceiling
applied to capacity release transactions
denies releasing and replacement
shippers the same ability to negotiate
transactions that reflect the market
value of capacity at all times. As the
Commission has found, providing the
ability to negotiate capacity release
transactions based on price differentials
will help in providing short-term
capacity to replacement shippers, such
as gas-fired electric generators.51 With
the price ceiling in effect, releasing
shippers are unable to effectively use
price differentials as a measure of
capacity value because they are denied
the ability to recover the value of
capacity during peak periods when that
value exceeds the maximum rate cap.
36. The price ceiling also harms
captive customers holding long-term
contracts on the pipeline. Those
customers pay maximum rates for both
peak and off-peak periods. During off50 Order
No. 637 at 31,279.
for Business Practices for Interstate
Natural Gas Pipelines, Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, 71 FR 64,655 (November 3, 2006),
FERC Stats. & Regs. Proposed Regulations ¶ 32,609,
P 17 (Oct. 25, 2006), Order No. 698, 72 FR 38,757
(July 16, 2007), FERC Stats. & Regs. Regulations
Preambles ¶ 31,251 at P 51 (Jun. 25, 2007).
51 Standards
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
peak periods, they can only recover a
small portion of the capacity cost
through capacity release because of the
low market value of off-peak capacity.
However, during peak periods, the price
ceiling prevents those customers from
releasing their capacity for its full
market value.
37. Finally, the price ceiling reduces
the dissemination of accurate capacity
pricing information. That is because the
price ceiling causes transactions to
move to the bundled sales market
during peak periods, so that there is no
separate capacity transaction to be
reported.
2. Assurance of Just and Reasonable
Rates
38. As the court stated in INGAA, the
Commission may depart from cost of
service ratemaking upon:
A showing that * * * the goals and
purposes of the statute will be accomplished
‘through the proposed changes.’ To satisfy
that standard, we demanded that the
resulting rates be expected to fall within a
‘zone of reasonableness, where [they] are
neither less than compensatory nor
excessive.’ [citation omitted]. While the
expected rates’ proximity to cost was a
starting point for this inquiry into
reasonableness, [citation omitted], we were
quite explicit that ‘non-cost factors may
legitimate a departure from a rigid cost-based
approach,’ [citation omitted]. Finally, we said
that FERC must retain some general oversight
over the system, to see if competition in fact
drives rates into the zone of reasonableness
‘or to check rates if it does not.’ 52
Accordingly, we analyze below (1) the
extent to which market conditions and
other factors may be expected to keep
short-term capacity release prices
within a reasonable zone despite the
removal of the price ceiling, (2) the noncost factors supporting a removal of the
price ceiling, and (3) our oversight of
the short-term capacity release market
after removal of the price ceiling.
a. Market Conditions Ensure Just and
Reasonable Rates
39. The Commission finds that the
short-term capacity release market is
generally competitive. Therefore
competition, together with our
continuing requirement that pipelines
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
52 INGAA
at 31.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
must sell short-term firm and
interruptible services to any shipper
offering the maximum rate, and the
Commission’s ongoing monitoring
efforts will keep short-term capacity
release rates within the ‘‘zone of
reasonableness’’ required by INGAA and
Farmers Union.
40. In Order Nos. 636 and 637, the
Commission instituted a number of
policy revisions which have enhanced
competition between releasing shippers
as well as between releasing shippers
and the pipeline. These revisions
provide shippers with enhanced market
mechanisms that will help ensure a
more competitive market and mitigate
the potential for the exercise of market
power. The Commission required
pipelines to permit releasing shippers to
use flexible point rights and to fully
segment their pipeline capacity.
Flexible point rights enable shippers to
use any points within their capacity
path on a secondary basis, which
enables shippers to compete effectively
on release transactions with other
shippers. Segmentation further
enhances the ability to compete because
it enables the releasing shipper to retain
the portion of the pipeline capacity it
needs while releasing the unneeded
portion. Effective segmentation makes
more capacity available and enhances
competition. As the Commission
explained in Order No. 637:
The combination of flexible point rights
and segmentation increases the alternatives
available to shippers looking for capacity. In
the example,53 a shipper in Atlanta looking
for capacity has multiple choices. It can
purchase available capacity from the
pipeline. It can obtain capacity from a
shipper with firm delivery rights at Atlanta
or from any shipper with delivery point
rights downstream of Atlanta. The ability to
segment capacity enhances options further.
The shipper in New York does not have to
forgo deliveries of gas to New York in order
to release capacity to the shipper seeking to
deliver gas in Atlanta. The New York shipper
53 In the example used in Order No. 636, a
shipper holding firm capacity from a primary
receipt point in the Gulf of Mexico to primary
delivery points in New York could release that
capacity to a replacement shipper moving gas from
the Gulf to Atlanta while the New York releasing
shipper could inject gas downstream of Atlanta and
use the remainder of the capacity to deliver the gas
to New York.
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37065
can both sell capacity to the shipper in
Atlanta and retain the right to inject gas
downstream of Atlanta to serve its New York
market.54
41. In addition to enhancing
competition through expansion of
flexible point rights and segmentation,
the Commission in Order No. 637 also
required pipelines to provide shippers
with scheduling equal to that provided
by the pipeline, so that replacement
shippers can submit a nomination at the
first available opportunity after
consummation of the capacity release
transaction. The change makes capacity
release more competitive with pipeline
services and increases competition
between capacity releasers by enabling
replacement shippers to schedule the
use of capacity obtained through release
transactions quickly rather than having
to wait until the next day.
42. The data accumulated by the
Commission during the Order No. 637
experiment, as well as review of more
recent data, confirm that capacity
release prices reflect competitive
conditions in the industry. On May 30,
2002, the Commission issued a notice of
staff paper presenting data on capacity
release transactions during the
experimental period when the capacity
release ceiling price was waived.55 The
staff paper provided analysis of capacity
release transactions on 34 pipelines
during the 22-month period from March
2000 to December 2001.56
43. In brief, the data gathered during
the 22-month period show that without
the price ceiling, prices exceeded the
maximum rate only during short time
periods and appear to be reflective of
competitive conditions in the industry.
The following table shows the
distribution of above ceiling price
releases among the pipelines studied.
54 Order
No. 637 at 31,301.
May 30, 2002, a staff paper was posted on
the Commission’s web site presenting, and
analyzing data on capacity release transactions
relating to the experimental period when the rate
ceiling on short-term released capacity was waived.
56 Many of these release transactions would have
occurred prior to completion of the pipeline’s Order
No. 637 compliance proceedings and the
implementation of the changes to flexible point
rights, segmentation and scheduling described
above.
55 On
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37066
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
TABLE I.—ABOVE CAP RELEASES BY PIPELINE
[Releases Awarded Between March 26, 2000 and December 31, 2001]
% of total
releases
Release
quantity above
max rate
(MMBtu/day)
% of total
release
quantity
Algonquin .........................................................................................................
ANR Pipeline ...................................................................................................
CIG ...................................................................................................................
Dominion (CNGT) ............................................................................................
Columbia Gas ..................................................................................................
Columbia Gulf ..................................................................................................
East Tennessee ...............................................................................................
El Paso ............................................................................................................
Florida Gas ......................................................................................................
Great Lakes .....................................................................................................
Iroquois ............................................................................................................
Kern River ........................................................................................................
KMI (KNEnergy) ...............................................................................................
Gulf South (Koch) ............................................................................................
Midwestern .......................................................................................................
Mississippi River ..............................................................................................
Mojave Pipeline Co ..........................................................................................
Natural Gas Pipeline Co ..................................................................................
Reliant (Noram) ...............................................................................................
Northern Border ...............................................................................................
Northern Natural ..............................................................................................
Northwest Pipeline ...........................................................................................
Paiute Pipeline .................................................................................................
Panhandle Eastern ..........................................................................................
Southern Natural ..............................................................................................
Tennessee Gas ...............................................................................................
TETCO .............................................................................................................
Texas Gas .......................................................................................................
Trailblazer ........................................................................................................
Transco ............................................................................................................
Transwestern ...................................................................................................
Trunkline ..........................................................................................................
Williams ............................................................................................................
Williston Basin .................................................................................................
1
1
19
21
101
........................
........................
135
25
3
........................
2
3
........................
1
........................
1
16
........................
........................
12
24
........................
1
7
11
122
6
3
183
11
........................
4
........................
0.1
0.1
6.5
1.0
4.4
........................
........................
13.3
1.7
1.3
........................
3.9
1.0
........................
0.6
........................
2.6
3.2
........................
........................
1.6
1.8
........................
0.4
0.3
0.4
3.8
0.5
25.0
3.3
4.5
........................
0.4
........................
18,453
30,000
109,984
65,789
374,727
........................
........................
631,683
43,526
15,000
........................
55,000
1,409
........................
50,000
........................
40,000
270,489
........................
........................
23,273
139,850
........................
1,000
24,101
36,421
645,856
103,237
15,000
1,540,885
64,058
........................
16,500
........................
0.2
0.2
4.4
0.7
2.7
........................
........................
12.5
1.4
0.6
........................
2.5
0.0
........................
2.3
........................
4.7
2.3
........................
........................
0.5
4.1
........................
0.1
0.2
0.2
3.3
1.0
10.0
4.1
6.5
........................
0.3
........................
Total ..........................................................................................................
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
Pipeline
Releases
above max
rate
(number of
transactions)
713
2.2
4,316,241
2.1
44. These data show that during
periods without capacity constraints,
prices remained at or below the
maximum rate. The staff paper does
identify 713 releases above the ceiling
price, representing an average total
capacity release contract volume of 4.3
billion cubic feet (Bcf) per day.
However, the staff paper reflects that
these above-ceiling price releases
represented only a small portion of the
total releases on these pipelines,
comprising approximately two percent
of total transactions on the pipelines
studied for the entire period, and two
percent of gas volumes. Further, above
ceiling releases accounted for no more
than six or seven percent of transactions
during any given month of the period.
As one would expect, the percentages of
releases occurring above the ceiling
increased during peak periods.
However, average release rates were
higher by only one cent per MMBtu per
day or five and one-half percent higher
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
than they would have been with the
price ceiling in place. Of the 34
pipelines in the study, 10 reported no
releases above the ceiling price, and 20
pipelines reported fewer than 25 aboveceiling price releases. The data gathered
during this 22-month period reflects the
Commission’s expectations and affirms
the Commission’s findings in the Order
No. 637 proceeding. As the court stated
in INGAA:
The data represented in the graph [ ] do
support the Commission’s view that the
capacity release market enjoys considerable
competition. The brief spikes in moments of
extreme exigency are completely consistent
with competition, reflecting scarcity rather
than monopoly. * * * [citation omitted] A
surge in the price of candles during a power
outage is no evidence of monopoly in the
candle market.57
45. The Commission has gathered
additional current data and has
replicated the evidence presented in
57 INGAA
PO 00000
at 32.
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Order No. 637. The current data shows
that the conditions that existed at the
time of Order No. 637 and during the
past experimental period continue in
today’s marketplace.
46. For example, Figure 1 illustrates
the fluctuations in the market value of
transportation service, as shown by the
basis differentials between Louisiana
and New York City. This graph
compares the daily difference in gas
prices between Louisiana and New York
City to Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line
Corporation’s maximum interruptible
transportation rate, including fuel
retainage, during the 12 months ending
July 31, 2007. This graph shows that for
most of the year, the value of
transportation service, as indicated by
the basis differentials, is less than the
maximum transportation rate. However,
during brief, peak demand periods, the
value of transportation service is
measurably greater than the maximum
transportation rate. For example, on
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
while the maximum tariff rate plus the
47. Figures 2 and 3 below reflect that
a similar pattern of transportation value
is evident in other areas of the country.
Focusing on fluctuations in the market
value of transportation service as shown
by basis differentials between Louisiana
and Chicago and between the Permian
Basin and the California border,
respectively, these figures show that for
most of the year, the value of
transportation service is less than the
maximum transportation rate of Natural
Gas Pipeline Company of America and
El Paso Natural Gas Company,
58 In Order No. 637, the Commission presented
similar data in figure 6 showing the implicit
transportation value between South Louisiana and
Chicago. Order No. 637 at 31,274.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
cost of fuel was approximately $1.08 per
MMBtu.58
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
respectively. However, similar to figure
1, these figures also reflect that during
brief peak-demand periods the value of
transportation service is measurably
greater than the maximum
transportation rate.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
ER30JN08.020
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
February 5, 2007, the basis differential
between Louisiana and New York City
was in excess of $27.00 per MMBtu,
37067
ER30JN08.022
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
BILLING CODE 6717–01–C
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
ER30JN08.021
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
37068
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
The data in all three of the above
figures reflect similar market conditions
to the data that the Commission relied
upon in lifting the price ceiling for
short-term capacity releases in Order
No. 637, with the market value of
capacity generally below the pipeline’s
maximum rate except for relatively brief
price spikes.59 In affirming the
Commission’s actions, the court in
INGAA found that the data presented by
the Commission constituted a
substantial basis for the conclusion that
a considerable amount of competition
existed in the capacity release market.
Further, the INGAA court concluded
that the price spikes reflected in the
data were consistent with competition
and that such spikes reflected scarcity
rather than monopoly power.60
b. Recourse Rate Protection
48. Moreover, the Commission is not
relying only on a competitive market to
ensure just and reasonable rates. The
pipeline’s maximum rates for short-term
firm and interruptible services serve as
recourse rate protection for negotiated
rate transactions,61 and will provide the
same protection to replacement shippers
by giving them access to a just and
reasonable rate if the releasing shipper
seeks to exercise market power.62 As the
Commission explained in Order No.
637:
The Commission is continuing to protect
against the possibility that, in an oligopolistic
market structure, the pipeline and firm
shipper will have a mutual interest in
withholding capacity to raise the price
because the Commission is continuing cost
based regulation of pipeline transportation
transactions. The pipeline will be required to
sell both short-term and long-term capacity at
just and reasonable rates. In the short-term,
a releasing shipper’s attempt to withhold
capacity in order to raise prices above
59 Order
No. 637 at 31,273–75.
at 31–32.
61 Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC
¶ 61,076, reh’g denied, 75 FERC ¶ 61,024 (1996),
petitions for review denied sub nom., Burlington
Resources Oil & Gas Co. v. FERC, 172 F.3d 918 (DC
Cir. 1998). See also Natural Gas Pipelines
Negotiated Rate Policies and Practices;
Modification of Negotiated Rate Policy, 104 FERC
¶ 61,134 (2003), order on reh’g and clarification,
114 FERC ¶ 61,042, order dismissing reh’g and
denying clarification, 114 FERC ¶ 61,304 (2006). As
the Commission explained in its negotiated rate
policy statement, ‘‘[t]he availability of a recourse
service would prevent pipelines from exercising
market power by assuring that the customer can fall
back to traditional cost-based service if the pipeline
unilaterally demands excessive prices or withholds
service.’’ 74 FERC ¶ 61,076 at 61,240 (1996).
62 The pipeline is obligated to sell capacity at the
just and reasonable rate. Tennessee Gas Pipeline
Co., 91 FERC ¶ 61,053 (2000), reh’g denied, 94
FERC ¶ 61,097 (2001), petitions for review denied
sub nom., Process Gas Consumers Group v. FERC,
292 F.3d 831, 837 (DC Cir. 2002).
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
60 INGAA
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
maximum rates will be undermined because
the pipeline will be required to sell that
capacity as interruptible capacity to a shipper
willing to pay the maximum rate. Shippers
also have the option of purchasing long-term
firm capacity from the pipelines at just and
reasonable rates.63
49. The court in INGAA similarly
recognized the value of the pipeline’s
recourse rate protecting against possible
abuses of market power by releasing
shippers stating that:
[i]f holders of firm capacity do not use or
sell all of their entitlement, the pipelines are
required to sell the idle capacity as
interruptible service to any taker at no more
than the maximum rate—which is still
applicable to the pipelines.64
c. Short-Term Customers Are Not
Captive
50. The releasing shippers’ ability to
exercise market power in the short-term
capacity release market also is limited
because short-term customers are not
captive, even if only connected to one
pipeline. Short-term customers, those
using interruptible or short-term firm
pipeline service or relying on capacity
release transactions, are by the very
nature of the service for which they are
contracting, expressly taking the risk
that they may have to forgo the use of
gas entirely if short-term capacity is too
expensive, or not available, when they
need it.65 Thus, short-term shippers
always have the option simply not to
take service, if the price demanded is
above competitive market levels.
d. Non-Cost Factors
51. Removal of the price ceiling on
short-term capacity release transactions
provides a number of advantages which
‘‘offset whatever harm the occasional
high rate might entail.’’ 66 Most
importantly, removal of the price cap
permits more efficient utilization of
capacity by permitting prices for shortterm capacity releases to rise to market
clearing levels, thereby permitting those
who place the highest value on the
capacity to obtain it. Removal of the
price ceiling also will provide potential
customers with additional opportunities
to acquire capacity. Without the price
ceiling, firm capacity holders will have
a greater incentive to release capacity
during times of scarcity, because they
will be able to obtain the full market
value of the capacity.67 Therefore, a
63 Order
637 at 31,282.
at 32.
65 Order No. 637 at 31,285, 31,336–42.
66 INGAA at 33.
67 For example, an LDC shipper may hold
capacity on one or more pipelines and have access
to storage and peak shaving facilities. Using these
facilities may cost the LDC more to deliver gas than
64 INGAA
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37069
shipper needing gas on a peak day will
have a greater opportunity to obtain the
capacity it needs from a firm capacity
holder, instead of having only the
choices of purchasing a bundled sale or
taking gas out of the pipeline and
paying the pipeline’s scheduling or
overrun penalties.68 Thus, removal of
the price ceiling benefits short-term
shippers because the shipper placing a
high value on the capacity has a greater
assurance of obtaining the capacity it
needs than it does under a price cap
where that shipper may be unable to
obtain any capacity.
52. Second, even if replacement
shippers do end up paying higher prices
for capacity during peak periods than
they did with the regulated rate in
effect, it is appropriate for shippers
using the system only during peak
periods to pay higher prices reflecting
the greater demand on the system.
Short-term shippers currently receive
the benefit of paying reduced capacity
release prices during off-peak periods
but face a cap on the market price
during peak periods. Removal of the
price ceiling on short-term capacity
releases will ensure that those shippers
that receive the benefit of lower market
prices during off-peak periods face the
higher market prices during peak
periods.
53. Third, removing the price ceiling
on short-term capacity releases should
benefit the ‘‘primary intended
beneficiaries of the NGA—the ‘captive’
shippers’’ 69 by removing the regulatory
bias built into the current rate structure.
Those shippers typically have long-term
firm contracts with the pipeline. Longterm shippers pay the same rate for
capacity during both peak and off-peak
periods. During off-peak periods they
can recover only a small portion of their
capacity cost through capacity release,
because the market value for release
capacity is generally quite low due to
the reduced demand for capacity and
the increased availability of released
capacity. But during peak periods, the
price cap limits long-term captive
customers (who cannot make bundled
sales) from receiving the full market
value of their capacity. Long-term
shippers pay for the largest proportion
of the pipeline’s fixed costs through
their annual reservation charges, and
purchasing gas in the upstream markets and using
its transportation capacity to transport that gas to
the city gate. However, the LDC might be willing
to release its transportation capacity and use its
peak shaving device instead if it could receive a
price above the maximum rate for its transportation
capacity so that the price it receives will cover the
costs of the peak shaving device. Order No. 637 at
31,277.
68 Order No. 637 at 31,280; INGAA at 34.
69 INGAA at 33.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37070
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
permitting them to receive more
revenue from capacity release during
peak periods will help them defray
those costs. In short, the captive
customers will ‘‘continue to receive
whatever benefits the rate ceilings
generally provide,’’ while also ‘‘reaping
the benefits of [the] new rule, in the
form of higher payments for their
releases of surplus capacity.’’ 70
54. Finally, by providing more
accurate price signals concerning the
market value of pipeline capacity,
removal of the price ceiling for shortterm capacity releases will promote the
efficient construction of new capacity
by highlighting the location, frequency,
and severity of transportation
constraints. Correct capacity pricing
information will also provide
transparent market values that will
better enable pipelines and their lenders
to calculate the potential profitability
and associated risk of additional
construction designed to alleviate
transportation constraints.
e. Oversight
55. The reporting requirements in
Order No. 637 and the Commission’s
implementation of the Energy Policy
Act of 2005, specifically with respect to
market manipulation, provide the
Commission with enhanced ability to
monitor the market and detect and deter
abuses.
56. Order No. 637 improved the
Commission’s and the industry’s ability
to monitor capacity release transactions
by requiring daily posting of these
transactions on pipeline Web sites.71
This has increased the information
available to buyers while at the same
time making it easier for the
Commission to identify situations in
which shippers are abusing their market
70 Id.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
71 18
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
3. Comments
57. The vast majority of comments
support the removal of the price ceiling
for capacity release transactions. But
some commenters have raised limited
concerns.
a. Lack of Competition in Certain Areas
58. A few commentors have alleged
that certain discrete portions of the
short term capacity release market may
not be competitive at all times. For
example, Arizona Public Service states
that the transportation markets served
by El Paso Natural Gas Company (El
Paso) located east of California are not
currently competitive. It asserts that
during the 2000–2002 California energy
crisis, when the Commission had lifted
the price cap on short term capacity
releases, prices of releases of El Paso
capacity spiked to levels in excess of
$20 per Dth. Honeywell similarly argues
that the Commission has failed to
address the fact that many geographical
areas do not operate as a free market and
that areas in the Northeast, East, and
Southwest portions of the country faced
constrained capacity and difficulties in
building new pipeline facilities.
Honeywell argues that lifting the price
cap on short term capacity release will
only exacerbate prices while not
72 Order No. 637 at 31,283; Order No. 637–A at
31,558.
CFR 284.8 (2007).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
power.72 Further, the Commission will
entertain complaints and respond to
specific allegations of market power on
a case-by-case basis if necessary.
Furthermore, the Commission directs
staff to monitor the capacity release
program and, using all available
information, issue a report on the
general performance of the capacity
release program, within six months after
two years of experience under the new
rules.
Jkt 214001
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
addressing the underlying problem of
these constrained markets. In addition,
some end-users of gas express concerns
about the concentration of capacity
ownership on lateral pipelines and
therefore argue that the Commission
should either not remove the price cap
for laterals or do so on a case-by-case
basis, after a review of market
concentration and a demonstration that
the releasing shipper does not have
market power on the lateral.73
59. While the Commission has not
conducted a detailed market analysis for
each discrete area of the interstate
pipeline grid, the data previously
discussed shows that the short-term
capacity release market is generally
competitive. Indeed, with respect to the
El Paso market, the data in Table 1
shows that during the period March 26,
2000 to December 31, 2001, which
included the California energy crisis
referred to by APS, only 12.5 percent of
the total volume of capacity released on
El Paso was released at prices above the
maximum rate. Moreover, the updated
data in Figure 3 for August 2006
through July 2007 shows that the market
value of transportation service from the
Permian Basin to the California border
was less than El Paso’s maximum
transportation rate, except during brief,
peak-demand periods when the value of
transportation service was somewhat
greater than the maximum
transportation rate. Similar data for
deliveries to East of California markets
on El Paso’s South Mainline reflects the
same overall pattern, as shown in the
following graph.74
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
73 Weyerhaeuser,
NWIGU, and PGC.
data for this chart comes from ICE, an online electronic trading platform. The El Paso South
Mainline area is described on ICE as: El Paso-South
Mainline—buyers’ choice west of Cornudas.
74 The
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
60. Similarly, while Honeywell
suggests that capacity is constrained in
areas in the East and Northeast, the data
in Figure 1 shows that for most of the
year the value of transportation service
from Louisiana to New York City is less
than the maximum transportation rate
on Transco, with only brief spikes above
that level during peak demand periods.
61. These data are consistent with the
proposition that prices will exceed the
maximum rate only during periods of
constraint. Moreover, it is precisely for
these reasons that the Commission is
continuing to insist on the maintenance
of the pipeline’s recourse rate as
protection against the exercise of market
power. Even on laterals or other parts of
the pipeline grid where all firm capacity
may be held by only a few or one firm
shipper, those shippers cannot withhold
their capacity in order to charge a price
above competitive levels. The pipeline’s
cost-based interruptible rate is always
available as an alternative when a
releasing shipper attempts to withhold
its capacity. For example, assume that a
releasing shipper with available
capacity on a little used lateral seeks to
exercise market power by withholding
capacity unless a potential replacement
shipper pays a higher than justified rate.
If market demand for capacity at that
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
rate does not exist,75 the replacement
shipper has the option of turning down
the deal and purchasing the capacity
from the pipeline at the just and
reasonable interruptible rate.
62. NEM remains concerned that in
spite of the Commission’s finding that
the short term capacity release market is
competitive, market power may exist for
some market participants resulting in
historically high natural gas prices
reaching even higher levels. However,
the data reflects the competitive nature
of the short term capacity release market
and the safeguards that the Commission
employs in the instant Final Rule to
mitigate any residual market power. The
Commission accordingly finds that
NEM’s speculative concerns are
unwarranted.76
75 In
other words, the market is not constrained.
also posits that the lifting of the short
term capacity release market price ceiling in states
where LDCs are required to release their capacity
to marketers as part of a state retail unbundling
program will place the marketer in a position where
they would no longer be guaranteed the same
underlying capacity costs as if the capacity had
remained with the utility, and this could increase
the costs the marketers must pass on to their state
retail customers. To the extent that this feature
causes problems in states where capacity release
assignments are a mandatory part of a state retail
unbundling program, the Commission would expect
that the State would consider this in its policies.
76 NEM
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
b. Benefits From Removing the Price
Ceiling
63. Tenaska contests some of the
benefits the Commission has cited for
removing the price ceiling. It argues
there will be no overall increase in
allocative efficiency from removal of the
short term release price cap. It asserts
that capacity that is in excess to the
current capacity holder’s needs already
finds it way to those who value it more
by a variety of means, including
bundled downstream sales, short and
long term capacity releases, and
pipeline sales of short-term firm and
interruptible service. It also argues that
releasing shippers with excess capacity
are more likely to release that capacity
over a longer term, perhaps multiple
years, rather than speculate that it could
profit by making very short-term
releases during peak period price
spikes. It states that releases over
relatively long term with few exceptions
allow the releasing shipper to realize its
full market value without being
constrained by maximum pipeline
rates.77
77 Tenaska explains, ‘‘[c]apacity that basis
markets show to be worth more than the applicable
pipeline maximum rate in the prompt month will
almost always drop in value to a level below that
maximum rate at some future point. Such capacity
can be sold for its full value within the pipeline
maximum rate cap simply by extending the term.’’
Tenaska comments at 4–5.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
ER30JN08.023
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
BILLING CODE 6717–01–C
37071
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
37072
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
64. Rather than undercutting the
removal of the price cap, Tenaska’s
argument that releasing shippers can
now avoid the price ceiling by making
gas sales (in effect bundled sales of gas
and transportation) supports our
determination. Shippers may well find
that releasing transportation alone is far
more efficient than making a bundled
sales transaction, and therefore, removal
of the price ceiling will serve only to
promote efficiency with negligible
effect, if any, on price levels. Similarly,
requiring shippers to execute long-term
contracts in order to effectuate shortterm transactions is inefficient, and
would mask more accurate short-term
price signals. Moreover, as discussed
earlier, releasing and replacement
shippers want to contract based on price
differentials between markets even
when such differentials exceed the
maximum rate, and executing long term
contracts at some approximate capped
rate would not achieve that goal.
65. Tenaska also argues that holders
of long term pipeline contracts, that are
‘‘net long’’ compared to their actual
capacity needs will be the only shippers
to benefit. Market participants that are
‘‘net short’’ hold less capacity than they
need and choose to match some portion
of their demand with short term services
and delivered gas purchases rather than
to rely exclusively on long term pipeline
contracts. Tenaska argues that the effect
of the removal of the short term release
rate cap, if there is any effect on
reallocation of capacity at all, will be a
transfer of value from net short
companies to net long companies and
states that there will be no net market
benefit of the type the Commission must
show to justify the proposed removal of
the cap.
66. Tenaska ignores the fact that ‘‘net
short’’ holders of capacity under its
scenario will benefit from the removal
of the price cap from short term capacity
release because they may be able to gain
access to capacity in a constrained
market that they could not if the price
cap remained. A releasing shipper,
subject to a rate ceiling, may well hold
onto capacity if the maximum rate is
less than its opportunity cost, such as
using an alternative fuel, using
expensive storage, or conservation of
gas.78 Moreover, the fact low load factor
‘‘net long’’ holders of capacity of the
type described by Tenaska can profit
from above-cap short term releases is
one of the benefits of removing the
short-term price cap.
78 Order
No. 637 at 31,554.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
c. Promotion of Construction
67. Honeywell argues that the
Commission has failed to show that
more accurate price signals concerning
the value of pipeline capacity will, in
fact, promote construction of needed
capacity. First, higher prices should
serve as price signals indicating where
capacity shortages exist and where
potentially profitable construction can
take place. If prices are ‘‘exacerbated’’ as
Honeywell argues, replacement shippers
paying such prices have every incentive
to go to the pipeline and support
economically efficient construction to
rectify the shortage. While political and
environmental obstacles are also a factor
in construction, this factor has not
stymied construction. The Commission
has processed a large number of
certificate applications for new
construction of capacity, storage, and
liquefied natural gas terminals in every
region.79 Third, providing incentives for
new construction is not the only benefit
of removing the price ceiling. As
discussed earlier, removal of the price
ceiling will benefit the market even in
the short term by providing for a more
efficient allocation of capacity to those
who value that capacity.
d. Changed Circumstances
68. Tenaska and APS argue that even
if the Commission’s conclusion that all
pipeline capacity release markets are
competitive is supportable at this time,
circumstances could change
dramatically in this industry. As a
result, they assert that the Commission
must include a process for promptly
revisiting its determination that the
market is competitive if there is
evidence that the market is
dysfunctional. Honeywell also states
that the Commission also proposes to
blind itself for almost three years to any
problems in the capacity release market
by directing its staff to issue a report
within six months after gaining two
years of experience under the new rules.
69. As set forth above, we are
maintaining oversight over the market
and can act if market power is being
abused in particular circumstances.
Order No. 637 improved the
Commission’s and the industry’s ability
to monitor capacity release transactions
79 In 2007 alone, approximately 34 major pipeline
projects were authorized by the Commission which
was comprised of approximately 2,782 miles of
pipeline, 850 thousand horsepower of compression
and the capacity to transport some 23,000 million
MMd/t of gas. See the ‘‘2007’’ data at https://
www.ferc.gov/industries/gas/indus-act/pipelines/
approved-projects.asp. See similar data for storage
at https://www.ferc.gov/industries.asp and liquefied
natural gas terminals at https://www.ferc.gov/
industries/lng.asp.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
by requiring daily posting of these
transactions on pipeline Web sites.80
This has increased the information
available to buyers while at the same
time making it easier for the
Commission to identify situations in
which shippers are abusing their market
power.81 Such information allows the
Commission to monitor, with the
assistance of all industry participants,
the overall competitiveness of the
market including discrete portions of
the market that may not be competitive
at all times. Moreover, the Commission
will entertain complaints and respond
to specific allegations of market power
on a case-by-case basis if necessary.
This action will also guard against the
use of market power by any market
participant.
70. Further, Honeywell misreads the
Commission’s directives and intent
when it claims the Commission has
voluntarily blinded itself to market
forces for some three years. While the
Commission directs its staff to monitor
the capacity release program and issue
a report on the general performance of
the capacity release program within six
months after two years of experience
under the new rules, nothing in this
directive precludes staff from alerting
the Commission to any irregularities in
the capacity release market before it
issues its general report.
71. Moreover, while Tenaska refers to
the Commission lifting of the short term
price cap as permanent, and notes that
the INGAA court reviewed a proposal by
the Commission to lift the price ceiling
only on a temporary basis, it is
important to note that, although the
Commission will remove the price
ceiling on short term capacity releases it
will monitor the capacity release market
and review its staff’s report on the
effects of the new rule and the overall
functioning of the capacity release
market.
e. Exemption From Bidding for ShortTerm Releases at the Maximum Rate
72. The NGSA and others request that
the Commission continue to allow
market participants to enter into a prearranged capacity release transaction
without bidding for releases of capacity
with a term of a year or less as long as
those releases are made at the pipeline’s
maximum tariff rate. NGSA asserts that
prearranged releases at the pipeline’s
maximum rate without the competitive
bidding requirement have been proven
to provide significant market benefits
and should not be eliminated, solely
80 18
CFR 284.8 (2007).
No. 637 at 31,283; Order No. 637–A at
81 Order
31,558.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
because the Commission removes the
rate cap on short-term capacity release
transactions.
73. The reason for the prior
exemption from bidding for prearranged capacity release transactions at
the maximum rate was based solely on
the fact that with the rate cap in place,
no one could submit a higher bid and
win the capacity. As discussed earlier,
one of the reasons for removing the
price ceiling for short-term releases is to
ensure that capacity is allocated to the
shipper that values it the most. NGSA
has not provided a sufficient
justification for permitting shippers to
consummate a capacity release at the
maximum rate when another potential
shipper places a greater value on that
capacity.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
B. Removal of Price Ceiling for LongTerm Releases
74. Several commenters to the NOPR
request that the Commission remove the
price ceiling on long-term capacity
releases in addition to eliminating the
price ceiling on short-term capacity
releases. 82 These commenters assert
that the same arguments that support
removal of the price cap for short-term
capacity releases apply equally to lifting
the price cap for long-term capacity
releases. For example, commenters
argue that lifting the price ceiling on
long-term capacity releases would
increase liquidity and competition in
the market for capacity release and
primary pipeline capacity, thereby
promoting the goals of allocative
efficiency. Moreover, commentors assert
that lifting the price cap on long-term
capacity releases will promote the
construction of additional pipeline
capacity by providing more accurate
price signals reflecting the value of such
capacity.
75. Commentors also point out that
the Commission’s concern over
replacement shippers being ‘‘locked in’’
to high price long-term contracts is
misplaced because such releases of
capacity would likely be priced using
basis differentials at different price
index locations.83 Other commentors
such as Duke assert that the
Commission’s concerns are misplaced
because replacement shippers accepting
such multi-year deals are sophisticated
market participants capable of
negotiating fair agreements.
76. Allegheny argues that the
pipelines’ recourse rates will serve as a
check on over-priced long-term capacity
82 See, e.g., Comments of Allegheny Energy
Supply Co. (Allegheny), Duke Energy, Dynegy
Marketing and Trade (Dynegy), and Southwest .
83 See e.g., Comments of Southwest at 10;
Allegheny at 6–7.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
releases because replacement shippers
would have the ability to negotiate for
capacity from a pipeline at the recourse
rate if the releasing shippers were
seeking excessive prices. Allegheny also
points to the Commission’s reporting
requirements, complaints process, and
enhanced civil penalty authority as
additional safeguards against the
exercise of market power.
77. Several commenters support the
retention of the price ceiling on long
term capacity releases and argue that it
protects customers from being locked
into a long term contract without price
cap protection, that the price cap
provides protection against possible
abuse of market power and that removal
of the price cap for long term capacity
releases does not provide the efficiency
gains provided by the removal of the
price ceiling on short term capacity
release.84
78. In this instant Final Rule, the
Commission will not extend the
removal of price ceilings to long term
releases as urged by these commentors.
The data discussed above indicate only
that removal of the price cap for shortterm releases is needed to reflect market
values. The Commission removed the
price ceiling to permit shippers to
quickly align their capacity prices with
the fluctuating short term market for
capacity releases. Such flexibility is not
relevant to long-term releases.
79. Limiting this rulemaking to shortterm transactions is a reasonable
response to the circumstances the
Commission is trying to address, i.e.,
short term price spikes. Only under
these conditions do Commissionapproved maximum rates prevent the
market from rationally allocating scarce
capacity to those shippers who value it
most. Removing the price cap only for
short-term transactions allows a more
efficient market-driven allocation of
capacity during those brief peak
demand periods, and provides more
detailed price signals to the market on
the value of peak capacity, while
retaining valuable consumer protections
provided by the price ceiling for longer
term transactions. The Commission’s
policy emphasis in this rule is on shortterm transactions, because that is where
there is a problem to be solved. No
commenter has made a convincing
argument that price ceilings on longer
term transactions create significant
allocative inefficiencies or market
failures. Accordingly, the Commission
concludes that the current record does
not warrant removal of the price ceiling
on long-term capacity releases.
84 See, e.g., Comments of NJNG at 33, OIPA at 3,
Statoil at 14, Weyerhaeuser at 11.
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37073
80. Moreover, as we said in the
NOPR,85 limiting the release to one year
will not prevent the releasing and
replacement shipper from continuing an
index-based release past one year,
because they could repost the release for
another year, and the price ceiling
would not apply to the release.
However, such reposting provides
additional assurance to the market that
capacity will be allocated to those who
value it the most. Any transaction in
which the parties want to continue the
release past one year would have to be
re-posted for bidding to ensure that the
capacity is allocated to the highest
valued use.86 This bidding process
could provide an opportunity for redetermining the current market value of
the capacity.
C. Removal of Price Ceiling for Pipeline
Short-Term Transactions
81. Pipelines request that the
Commission remove the price ceiling for
short-term primary pipeline capacity
whether firm or interruptible. In sum,
the Interstate Natural Gas Association of
America (INGAA) and the commenting
pipelines argue that if the Commission
lifts the price cap for short-term
capacity releases, it should also lift the
price cap for primary pipeline
capacity.87
1. Removal of the Price Ceiling Is Not
Justified
82. The Commission declines to
remove the ceiling from short-term
pipeline capacity. In the Alternative
Rate Design Policy statement, we offered
the pipelines the flexibility to exceed
the price cap in one of two ways: either
pipelines can make a filing with
appropriate information to establish the
market is competitive or pipelines can
negotiate rates as long as the shipper has
the option of purchasing capacity at the
recourse (maximum) tariff rate.88 These
two approaches assured shippers that
the pipelines were not exercising market
power. The pipelines request for lifting
the maximum rate on short-term
releases would effectively negate the
recourse rate protection we included in
the negotiated rate program.
83. Our action here is designed to
permit releasing shippers some of the
85 NOPR
at P 44–45.
discussed below, however, short term
capacity releases made in context of an AMA need
not be re-posted for bidding at the end of their term.
87 See e.g., Comments of Boardwalk, Spectra
Energy Transmission, LLC and Spectra Energy
Partners, LP (Spectra), and Williston Basin
Interstate Pipeline Co. (Williston Basin).
88 Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines and
Regulation of Negotiated Transportation Services of
Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ¶ 61,076 (1996).
86 As
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37074
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
same flexible pricing authority the
Commission has already granted
pipelines through the negotiated rate
program. But, as discussed earlier, the
Commission is retaining the maximum
rate ceiling on pipeline capacity because
it acts as the recourse rate for both
pipeline transactions as well as release
transactions. Removing the rate ceiling
for pipeline transactions would
therefore remove an important
protection both for pipeline customers
and for replacement shippers on
capacity release transactions.
84. In addition, pipelines are the
principal holders of capacity. As the
court recognized in INGAA:
There seems every reason to suppose that
[releasing shipper] ownership of such
capacity (in any given market) is not so
concentrated as that of the pipelines
themselves—the concentration that prompted
Congress to impose rate regulation in the first
place.
*
*
*
*
*
Here, the distinction between pipelines
and other holders of unused capacity, based
on probable likelihood of wielding market
power, seems to us to pass muster.89
85. Unlike releasing shippers, the
pipeline holders of primary capacity
have a greater ability to exercise market
power by withholding capacity and not
constructing facilities. Because
pipelines are in the best position to
expand their own systems, cost-ofservice rate ceilings help to ensure that
pipelines have appropriate incentives to
construct new facilities when needed.
As the Commission found, ‘‘the only
way a pipeline [can] create scarcity to
force shippers to accept longer term
contracts would be to refuse to build
additional capacity when demand
requires it.’’ 90 As long as cost-of-service
rate ceilings apply, however, ‘‘pipelines
[will] have a greater incentive to build
new capacity to serve all the demand for
their service, than to withhold capacity,
since the only way the pipeline could
increase current revenues and profits
would be to invest in additional
facilities to serve the increased
demand.’’ 91 Similarly, as long as
pipeline short-term services are subject
to a cost of service rate, the pipelines
will not limit their construction of new
capacity to meet demand in order to
create scarcity that increases short-term
prices. Indeed, releases at prices above
89 INGAA
at 35.
of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services, 101 FERC ¶ 61,127, at P 12
(2002), aff’d, American Gas Ass’n v. FERC, 428 F.3d
255 (DC Cir. 2005). See also Tennessee Gas Pipeline
Co., 91 FERC ¶ 61,053 (2000), reh’g denied, 94
FERC ¶ 61,097 (2001), aff’d, 292 F.3d 831 (DC Cir.
2002).
91 Id.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
90 Regulation
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
the maximum rate will indicate that
pipeline capacity is constrained and
demonstrate that constructing
additional capacity could be profitable.
86. Further, pipelines already have
significant pricing discretion. As
discussed above, pipelines can enter
into negotiated rate transactions above
the maximum rate. Pipelines also may
seek market-based rates by making a
filing with the Commission establishing
that they lack market power in the
markets they serve.92 In addition,
pipelines have the ability to propose
seasonal rates for their systems, and
therefore, recover more of their annual
revenue requirement in peak seasons.93
The proposed rule is designed solely to
give releasing shippers some of the same
flexibility enjoyed by the pipelines,
subject to the same recourse rate
protection. But removing the ceiling
price from the release market does not
justify removing all regulatory
protections applicable to the primary
capacity holder.
2. Response to Specific Comments
a. Evidentiary Record
87. INGAA states that the same
evidentiary record relied upon by the
Commission to propose lifting the
ceiling on capacity releases reflects that
the entire market, including short-term
pipeline services, is competitive, and
therefore contends that the Commission
should lift the rate ceilings on the entire
short-term market. Spectra adds that the
evidence cited by the Commission
supports the existence of competition by
all participants in the single market for
short-term capacity, not just
competition in the capacity release
sector of the overall market. INGAA
asserts that if the market is competitive,
the identity of the seller should be
irrelevant.
88. As we have explained above,
while the data indicates that the shortterm secondary market is competitive in
general, we have not made a finding that
every segment of every pipeline is
competitive; we retained the recourse
rate as a protection against the potential
exercise of market power by both
pipelines and releasing shippers in
those cases in which the market may not
be competitive. While the purpose of
capacity release, segmentation, and
flexible point rights is to encourage
competition between the pipeline’s sale
of its own capacity and capacity release,
and those policies have successfully
92 Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines and
Regulation of Negotiated Transportation Services of
Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ¶ 61,076 (1996).
93 See Order No. 637 at 31,574–81.
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
created a robust secondary market as
demonstrated by the data discussed
earlier in this rule, that does not
necessarily mean that every pipeline
faces competition in the sale of its shortterm capacity on all segments of its
system. For example, the Commission’s
selective discounting policy permits
pipelines to restrict a shipper’s discount
to specific points, so that the shipper
must pay the pipeline’s maximum rate
if it releases the capacity to a
replacement shipper who uses different
points where the pipeline faces less
competition.94 This may reduce that
shipper’s incentive to release its
capacity to a replacement shipper who
will use points on a segment with less
competition.95 Retaining the recourse
rate helps protect against the pipeline’s
abuse of market power in the sale of
capacity on any such segments of its
system.
89. Further, the repercussions of
removing price ceilings for pipeline
transactions are more serious than for
released capacity, because the exercise
of market power by pipelines could
reduce the total amount of primary
pipeline capacity available to the
market. Finally, to the extent pipelines
believe their markets are competitive,
they have a full opportunity to make a
filing with the Commission to obtain
market based rates based on a showing
of lack of market power.96
94 Williston Basin Interstate Pipeline Co., 110
FERC ¶ 61,210 at P 22, order on reh’g, 112 FERC
¶ 61, 038 (2005). These orders responded to a
decision by the United States Court of Appeals for
the District of Columbia Circuit in Williston Basin
Interstate Pipeline Co. v. FERC, 358 F.3d 45 (DC Cir.
2004) (Williston), vacating orders in an Order No.
637 compliance proceeding permitting releasing
shippers to retain primary point discounts when
their replacement shippers used different points.
The DC Circuit held that the policy could
undermine the benefits of selective discounting,
stating that ‘‘economic theory tells us price
discrimination, of which selective discounting is a
species, is least practical where arbitrage is
possible—that is, where a low price buyer can resell
to a high price buyer * * * yet this is precisely
what the Commission’s policy would appear not
only to allow but to encourage.’’ 358 F.3d at 50 (cite
omitted).
95 In addition, a particular shipper’s incentive to
release capacity in competition with the pipeline
could be reduced, if its discounted or negotiated
rate agreement contains a provision, as permitted by
Commission policy, providing that the pipeline will
share any revenues the shipper receives from a
capacity release in excess of its discounted or
negotiated rate. See LSP Cottage Grove, L.P. v.
Northern Natural Gas Co., 111 FERC ¶ 61,108 at
P58–59 (2005), and cases cited.
96 Pipelines so far have not been successful in
demonstrating that their major markets are
competitive. See e.g., Gas Transmission Northwest
Corp., 119 FERC ¶ 61,288 (2007); Koch Gateway
Pipeline Co., 85 FERC ¶ 61,013 (1998), order on
reh’g, 89 FERC ¶ 61,046 (1999).
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
b. Infrastructure Incentives
90. INGAA alleges that maintaining
cost-based recourse rates for pipelines is
not required to preserve an incentive for
pipelines to construct needed pipeline
infrastructure. It asserts this runs
counter to the general presumption that
market-based rates send the proper
signals as to whether new pipeline
construction is needed and can be
constructed economically. In their
comments, INGAA and Spectra argue
that pipelines actually compete to build
new capacity, and that there is no
reason to assume that non-pipeline
investment will not fill any void caused
by pipelines withholding capacity.97
91. Neither INGAA nor Spectra have
shown that the entry barriers to
constructing capacity on existing
pipeline rights of way are so low that
there is effective competition. Moreover,
they have the opportunity to present
any such detailed evidence in a
proceeding seeking to show that they do
not have market power, and other
parties would have an opportunity to
challenge such evidence. This is not a
finding we can make on a generic basis
in this proceeding.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
c. Competitive Market Structure
92. INGAA asserts that the
Commission’s concern that pipelines
own more pipeline capacity than their
firm shippers is based on a prerestructuring, pre-open access view of
the industry, and not based on any
empirical study of pipeline market
power. Moreover, INGAA and Spectra
assert that control of the short-term
market is now primarily in the hands of
pipelines’ firm shippers, which have
substantial rights such as capacity
release, flexible point rights and
segmentation rights. These shipper
rights produce a competitive short-term
market that cannot reasonably be
bifurcated based on the identity of the
seller. INGAA and Spectra state that the
Commission should focus its concern
not on formal ownership, but rather on
the entity that controls access to or use
of the capacity.
93. Spectra points out that a check on
prices is not needed to prevent the
exercise of market power because
sufficient safeguards—in the form of
97 Spectra also argues that the Commission should
remove the price caps for pipeline short-term firm
and interruptible capacity, and suggests that to the
extent the Commission retains its concerns
regarding withholding of capacity, the Commission
could retain the price caps for interruptible service.
Spectra further argues that this action would
provide shippers with a recourse alternative that
would be available if the pipeline attempted to
withhold short-term firm capacity or the releasing
customer tried to withhold short-term release
capacity.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
competition between shippers seeking
to release or acquire capacity in the
short-term markets, as well as the
competition between shippers and
pipelines themselves—will protect the
market from abuse. Further, Spectra
asserts that construction of new
capacity, the open access tariff,
reporting and posting requirements, and
the Commission’s oversight and
enforcement authority will also serve as
added safeguards.
94. However, as the Court of Appeals
found, these arguments are comparing
‘‘apples and oranges.’’ 98 First, the
available capacity of the pipeline is on
hand and ready to be sold, whereas the
capacity held by releasing shippers is
not necessarily available, since much of
it may be needed to serve its native
loads:
The petitioning pipelines assert that
pipelines hold only about 7% of pipeline
transportation capacity, while shippers hold
the remaining 93%. This is classic apples
and oranges. The Commission points out that
whereas the uncontracted capacity of a
pipeline is presumptively available for the
short-term market, no such presumption
makes sense for the non-pipeline capacity
holders: they presumably contracted for the
capacity in anticipation of actually using it.99
Second, using the market shares for
already existing capacity does not
reflect the more important relationship
of the price ceiling to construction of
new capacity infrastructure which is far
more critical to ensuring that the
pipeline grid is expanded to meet
demand. Because the pipelines are the
principal parties constructing additional
capacity, it is crucial that their incentive
to build is not diluted by the ability to
earn scarcity rents in the short-term
market.
d. Differences in Flexibility Between
Pipeline Capacity and Released
Capacity
95. INGAA and the pipelines argue
that the pricing flexibility available to
the pipelines does not allow pipelines
to compete with shippers offering shortterm capacity releases without a price
ceiling. They argue that market-based
pricing for pipelines is subject to a
strenuous market-power test that
involves lengthy and costly
administrative proceedings. They argue
that the Commission rarely finds that a
pipeline meets this market-power test,
and therefore it is impractical for
98 INGAA
at 24.
In addition, as previously discussed, there
may be circumstances in which shippers’
discounted or negotiated rate agreements contain
provisions that have the effect of reducing
competition from capacity release on some
segments of the pipeline.
99 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37075
pipelines to engage in competition with
capacity releases.100
96. In regard to negotiated rates, the
pipelines argue that their flexibility is
limited because the maximum rate is
always subject to the shipper’s right to
elect the recourse rate, and
implementation is subject to regulatory
delays. INGAA and Williston also argue
that the negotiated rate program offers
pipelines very little, if any, opportunity
to employ market-based pricing to
efficiently allocate capacity to those
who desire it most.
97. Third, INGAA asserts that
seasonal rates do not provide the
flexibility necessary to address the
pipelines’ competitive disadvantage
under the Commission’s proposal
because seasonal rates result in new
recourse rates, capped at the pipeline’s
annual revenues, not the ability to
charge rates in excess of recourse rates.
Spectra adds that seasonal rates do not
allow pipelines to award the capacity to
the customers who value it most
because there is still a maximum rate. In
addition, Spectra notes that pipelines
are unable to respond to market signals
in the short-term market using seasonal
recourse rates. Williston asserts that
seasonal rates are not a substitute for the
removal of a price ceiling because they
do not necessarily align prices with
what the market will bear.
98. We agree that the flexibility
offered to pipelines and releasing
shippers is not identical, due to the
differences already noted between the
primary and secondary markets. The
recourse rate, for example, may operate
somewhat differently in the two markets
by virtue of the design of these markets;
but as we have found, the retention of
the recourse rate is necessary to provide
an effective check on both markets.
Thus, we have sought to provide both
pipelines and shippers with reasonably
comparable flexibility consistent with
the differences between these entities
and the need to provide protection
against market power.
99. For example, the commentors
assert that the Commission has rarely
granted a pipeline authority to price its
capacity upon market based rates.
INGAA and the pipelines make this
allegation to show that it is
administratively difficult to obtain
market-based rates from the
Commission and that is a difference
from the pricing authority the
100 INGAA at 12 (citing, KN Interstate Gas
Transmission Co., 76 FERC ¶ 61,134 (1996); and
Rendezvous Gas Services, LLC, 112 FERC ¶ 61,141,
at 61,792–94 (2005)). Spectra notes that the
Commission has never approved market based rates
for a major natural gas pipeline. Spectra comments
at 24.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37076
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
Commission grants capacity releases in
this rule. On the other hand, the fact
that the pipelines have not been granted
market based rates based on their factual
showings is strong evidence that the
recourse rate is still needed to protect
shippers against the exercise of market
power.101 This fact also leaves the
Commission reluctant to find that it
should remove the ceiling from primary
short term pipeline capacity.
100. Spectra argues that the
Commission uses a stricter market
power analysis to determine whether to
grant a pipeline market based rates than
it did to conclude that it would remove
the price caps for short term capacity
releases. Spectra asserts that the
Commission, in removing the price
ceiling from short term capacity
releases, did not define the relevant
product market and the relevant
geographic market, nor did it calculate
a Herfindahl-Hirschman Index to
measure market concentration of the
releasing shippers and other competing
sellers in the market. Spectra argues that
the Commission should remove the
price caps on short-term pipeline
capacity on the same basis it used for
removing the caps on short-term
capacity releases.
101. The Commission is not using the
same analysis to remove the price
ceiling from short term capacity releases
as it does to determine whether a
pipeline lacks market power and should
therefore be permitted market based
rates. As we have explained, one of the
principal reasons for removing the price
ceiling on released capacity is the
existence of the pipeline’s service as
recourse in the event market power is
exercised.102 As the court in INGAA
observed:
If holders of firm capacity do not use or
sell all of their entitlement, the pipelines are
required to sell the idle capacity as
interruptible service to any taker at no more
than the maximum rate—which is still
applicable to the pipelines. [footnote
omitted] Even though interruptible service
may not be as desirable as firm service, the
Commission concluded that it would provide
an adequate substitute, whose availability
would place a meaningful check on whatever
anti-competitive tendencies the resellers
might have.103
102. The analysis we have employed
in removing the price ceiling for
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
101 See
e.g., Gas Transmission Northwest Corp.,
119 FERC ¶ 61,288 (2007); Koch Gateway Pipeline
Co., 85 FERC ¶ 61,013 (1998), order on reh’g, 89
FERC ¶ 61,046 (1999).
102 Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 91 FERC ¶ 61,053
(2000), reh’g denied, 94 FERC ¶ 61,097 (2001),
petitions for review denied sub nom., Process Gas
Consumers Group v. FERC, 292 F.3d 831, 837 (DC
Cir. 2002).
103 INGAA at 22.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
released capacity is therefore more
comparable to that used for pipeline
negotiated rates than for the market
power analysis under the Alternative
Rate Design Policy statement. The
continuation of the recourse rate
provides sufficient protection to enable
us to remove the price ceiling for short
term capacity releases without doing a
more detailed market power analysis.104
The Commission finds, however, that
there are sufficient concerns about the
ability of pipelines to exercise market
power in short-term transactions on at
least some segments of their systems,
that a blanket removal of the price cap
on all such pipeline transactions in this
rulemaking proceeding, without
consideration of specific circumstances
on individual pipeline systems, would
be inappropriate.
e. Bifurcation of the Markets
103. The pipelines maintain that
continuing the price ceiling on pipeline
short term services will create a
bifurcated market with higher market
prices in the uncapped release market.
The premise of this argument is that if
shippers that place a lower value on
transportation are able to acquire the
capped pipeline service, the prices in
the uncapped market will be higher
than if all capacity were sold without a
price ceiling. In the NOPR, the
Commission responded to similar
arguments.105 The Commission pointed
out that interruptible service has lower
104 Moreover, the Commission’s use of stricter
standard in reviewing petitions by a pipeline for
alternative pricing authority for its primary
transportation is not a new concept and is based
upon the different risks of abuses of market power.
In Koch Gateway Pipeline Co., 89 FERC ¶ 61,046
(1999), the Commission stated:
As reflected in the market power analysis set
forth in the Policy Statement, the Commission has
taken a conservative and cautious approach
concerning the showing a pipeline must make in
order to justify a finding that it lacks market power
in its primary transportation market, i.e., the
pipeline’s own sale of its transportation capacity. In
fact, many commenters asserted that it would be
unlikely that the pipeline’s primary market would
meet the proposed criteria for market-based rates.
The Commission recognizes that it has taken a more
relaxed and light-handed approach toward marketbased rates in other contexts, including for
example, the pipeline’s sales of storage service and
unbundled sales of the gas commodity. Purchasers
of such other services are more likely to have good
alternatives to purchasing from the pipeline; for
example, barriers to entry in the storage and gas
commodity markets are likely to be less. The
Commission also recognizes that its Short-Term
Transportation NOPR proposed a different
approach for justifying removal of the price cap on
short term (less than one year) transportation
services in both the pipeline’s primary
transportation market and the secondary, capacity
release market. That proposal included the
establishment of mandatory capacity auctions to
control market power. Id. at 61,129 (footnote
omitted).
105 NOPR at P 51.
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
priority than firm service so that even if
a shipper placing a relatively low value
on the capacity has a higher position on
the pipeline’s queue for price-controlled
interruptible transportation, it is not
guaranteed that it can acquire that
capacity, leading to the supposed higher
market clearing price. A firm shipper
could always release its unused firm
capacity to a replacement shipper who
places a higher value on that capacity,
thereby displacing the lower-value
interruptible shipper.
104. With respect to short-term firm
service, the Commission stated that
higher market clearing prices would not
occur as long as arbitrage exists. Any
shipper with a higher queue position
that acquires the pipeline capacity at the
lower capped rate would have an
incentive to resell that capacity to
another shipper who places a higher
value on the capacity, thus ensuring that
the market clearing price will reflect all
relevant demand.
105. INGAA asserts that the
Commission’s observation that pipeline
short-term capacity is interruptible and
inferior to firm released capacity is a
partial answer to its argument that a
bifurcated market will produce higher
prices in the regulated portion of the
market than would otherwise be the
case. But INGAA and Spectra assert that
short-term pipeline capacity is not
always interruptible—unsubscribed
pipeline capacity can be sold on a firm
basis during periods of peak demand,
and would, if treated on a par with
released capacity, compete on a head to
head basis. INGAA and Spectra argue
that if the rate for that short-term firm
pipeline capacity is capped, the pricing
inefficiencies will occur because the
arbitrage opportunities relied upon by
the Commission in the above-quoted
text often entail high costs, making
reliance on such opportunities
inefficient. For example, Spectra cited
articles for the proposition that arbitrage
opportunities ‘‘often entail high costs,
making the reliance on them also
inefficient.’’ 106
106. The only arbitrage costs at issue
in this case are the costs of releasing
that capacity, which is precisely the
same cost releasing shippers must incur
and we have sought to reduce the costs
106 Spectra comments at 12, citing, Stephen J.
Choi and A.C. Pritchard, Behavioral Economics and
the SEC, 56 Stan. L. Rev. 1, n. 11 (2003) (discussing
that ‘‘arbitrage is costly, which may limit its
effect’’). See also Lynn A. Stout, The Mechanics of
Market Inefficiency: An Introduction to the New
Finance, 28 J. Corp. L. 635, 655 (2003) (observing
that ‘‘arbitrage is costly and imperfect’’) and Andrei
Shleifer & Robert W. Vishny, The Limits of
Arbitrage, 52 J. Fin. 35 (1997) (explaining why the
capital costs required to engage in arbitrage
opportunities can hamper market efficiency).
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
of capacity release over the years. In
particular, the Commission’s action in
Order No. 637, where the Commission
instituted a number of policy revisions
that were designed to enhance
competition and improve efficiency
across the pipeline grid should reduce
arbitrage costs. There the Commission
required pipelines to permit releasing
shippers to use flexible point rights in
order to compete effectively on release
transactions with other shippers and to
fully segment their pipeline capacity
which permits the releasing shipper to
retain the portion of the pipeline
capacity it needs while releasing the
unneeded portion.107 This combination
of flexible point rights and segmentation
increases the alternatives available to
shippers looking for capacity. Moreover,
the Commission also required that
pipelines provide shippers with
scheduling equal to that provided by the
pipeline, so that replacement shippers
can submit a nomination at the first
available opportunity after
consummation of the capacity release
transaction. This action also makes the
two types of capacity more
interchangeable and should reduce
arbitrage costs.
107. On the other hand, we have to
recognize that arbitrage can never be
perfect. If it were, no interruptible
transportation would be sold on fully
subscribed pipelines. Moreover, as
previously discussed, in order to
preserve at least some of the benefits of
selective discounting, the Commission
permits pipelines to include provisions
in discounted rate agreements which
may reduce a shipper’s incentive to
engage in arbitrage in certain
circumstances. It is also important to
recognize that the pipelines’ argument
for removing the price ceiling for
pipeline interruptible and short-term
firm capacity is predicated on arbitrage.
Their essential argument is that as long
as long-term prices are regulated, shortterm price ceilings can be removed
because shippers can purchase firm
capacity in the long-term market and
arbitrage that capacity by releasing it in
the short-term market. If such arbitrage
is costly or ineffective, as the pipelines
argue here, or if a pipeline uses selective
discounting to discourage arbitrage on
some parts of its system, the pipelines
retain market power over their sales of
short-term capacity. Thus, even if
arbitrage is not fully effective, that fact
does not require removal of the price
ceiling because impediments to
107 Order
No. 637 at 31,300.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
arbitrage may enhance pipeline market
power.108
108. In balancing the risks of creating
a somewhat bifurcated market against
the possibility of the exercise of market
power by the pipelines in the short-term
market, we have determined to err on
the side of enhanced protection against
market power. In INGAA, the court
recognized the importance of the same
trade-off between the possible
bifurcation of the market and the need
to continue to regulate pipeline shortterm capacity. It recognized that while
price distortions might occur if arbitrage
is not effective,109 the recourse rate
applied to the pipelines provided
protection with respect to both pipeline
and released capacity:
If holders of firm capacity do not use or
sell all of their entitlement, the pipelines are
required to sell the idle capacity as
interruptible service to any taker at no more
than the maximum rate—which is still
applicable to the pipelines.110
The Court concluded, and we agree that,
the essential differences between
pipelines and releasing shippers
justified their differential treatment:
Here, the distinction between pipelines
and other holders of unused capacity, based
on probable likelihood of wielding market
power, seems to us to pass muster.111
IV. Asset Management Arrangements
109. In this Final Rule, the
Commission is revising its capacity
release policies to give releasing
shippers greater flexibility to negotiate
and implement AMAs. AMAs are a
relatively recent development in the
capacity release market, and are
beneficial to numerous market
participants and to the market in
general. However, the Commission’s
existing regulations and policies
concerning capacity release interfere
with the ability of releasing shippers to
implement the most efficient AMAs.
Accordingly, as discussed below, the
Commission is adopting its NOPR
proposals to grant an exemption from
108 Further, even if maintenance of the price
ceiling on short-term firm capacity serves to
bifurcate the market, we are concerned that lifting
the price ceiling on short term firm capacity would
create a perverse incentive for pipelines to forgo the
sale of firm capacity for periods of more than a year
in order to reap the uncapped rates that would be
available in the short term.
109 ‘‘The basic proposition asserted by the
pipelines (and, as we say, recognized by the
Commission) is that where (1) a portion of the
supply of a good or service is subject to price
controls, and (2) demand exceeds (the pricecontrolled) supply at the fixed price, the marketclearing price in the uncontrolled segment will be
normally higher than if no price controls were
imposed on any of the supply.’’ INGAA at 33.
110 Id.
111 Id at 36.
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37077
the prohibition against tying and an
exemption from bidding for AMAs. The
Commission is also revising the
definition of AMAs proposed in the
NOPR so as to relax the requirements
concerning an asset manager’s
obligation to deliver gas to the releasing
shipper and to allow supply side AMAs.
In addition, the Final Rule clarifies that
uncapped AMA capacity releases of
one-year or less may be rolled over
without competitive bidding, and that
profit sharing arrangements included in
an AMA will not violate any applicable
price cap. The Commission also
exempts certain AMAs from the buy/sell
prohibition.
A. Background
110. In general, AMAs are contractual
relationships where a party agrees to
manage gas supply and delivery
arrangements, including transportation
and storage capacity, for another party.
Typically a shipper holding firm
transportation and/or storage capacity
on a pipeline or multiple pipelines
temporarily releases all or a portion of
that capacity along with associated gas
production and gas purchase
agreements to an asset manager. The
asset manager uses that capacity to serve
the gas supply requirements of the
releasing shipper, and, when the
capacity is not needed for that purpose,
uses the capacity to make releases or
bundled sales to third parties.
111. While AMAs may be fashioned
in a myriad of ways, there are several
common components of these
arrangements. First, the releasing
shipper generally enters into a prearranged capacity release to an asset
manager ostensibly at the maximum rate
in order to avoid the bidding
requirement. Second, the releasing
shipper makes payments to the asset
manager for the gas supply service
performed by the asset manager for the
releasing shipper. These payments may
include the releasing shipper paying the
asset manager: (1) The full cost of the
released capacity (e.g., maximum rate)
on the theory that the asset manager is
using the released capacity to transport
the releasing shipper’s gas supplies, (2)
a management fee for transportationrelated tasks (e.g. nominations,
scheduling, storage injections, etc.)
associated with the asset manager’s
obligation to provide gas supplies to the
releasing shipper, and (3) the asset
manager’s cost of purchasing gas
supplies for the releasing shipper.
Third, the asset manager generally
shares with the releasing shipper the
value it is able to obtain from the
releasing shipper’s capacity and supply
contracts when those assets are not
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37078
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
needed to supply the releasing shipper’s
gas needs. The asset manager obtains
such value either by re-releasing the
capacity or by using it to make bundled
sales to third parties. The asset manager
may share that value by: (1) Paying a
fixed ‘‘optimization’’ fee to the releasing
shipper, (2) sharing profits pursuant to
an agreed-upon formula, or (3) making
its gas sales to the releasing shipper at
a price below market levels.
112. In many instances the asset
manager is chosen through a request for
proposal (RFP) process. The RFP
describes the details and terms and
conditions of the proposed deal and
seeks bids from service providers
willing to provide the requested
services. The methodology for choosing
a winning bidder under an RFP often
reflects many different factors,
including price, creditworthiness,
experience, reliability, and flexibility,
and it is clear that price is not always
the determining factor. Some RFP
procedures are state mandated, and
thus, in those situations, the LDC must
get approval from the state for the final
agreement.
113. As the Commission described in
the NOPR, there are several ways in
which the Commission’s current
capacity release regulations may
interfere with the ability of shippers to
negotiate and implement AMAs. The
first relates to the Commission’s
prohibition against the ‘‘tying’’ of
release capacity to any condition. The
Commission established this prohibition
in Order No. 636–A, using the following
language:
[t]he Commission reiterates that all terms
and conditions for capacity release must be
posted and non-discriminatory and must
relate solely to the details of acquiring
transportation on the interstate pipelines.
Release of capacity cannot be tied to any
other conditions. Moreover, the Commission
will not tolerate deals undertaken to avoid
the notice requirements of the regulations.
Order No. 636–A at 30,559.112
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
A critical component of many AMAs is
that the releasing shipper be able to
112 The Commission stated in Order No. 636–A
that releasing shippers may include in their offers
to release capacity reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms and conditions to
accommodate individual release situations,
including provisions for evaluating bids. All such
terms and conditions applicable to the release must
be posted on the pipeline’s electronic bulletin board
and must be objectively stated, applicable to all
potential bidders, and non-discriminatory. For
example, the terms and conditions could not favor
one set of buyers, such as end users of an LDC, or
grant price preferences or credits to certain buyers.
The pipeline’s tariff also must require that all terms
and conditions included in offers to release
capacity be objectively stated, applicable to all
potential bidders, and non-discriminatory. Order
No. 636–A at 30,557.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
require the replacement shipper (asset
manager) to satisfy the supply needs of
the releasing shipper and take
assignment of the releasing shipper’s gas
supply agreements as a condition of
obtaining the released capacity.
However, such requirements could be
considered prohibited tying conditions
that go beyond ‘‘the details of acquiring
transportation on the interstate
pipelines,’’ because they relate to the
purchase and sale of the gas
commodity.113
114. AMAs also have implications for
the rate cap and bidding regulations.
Section 284.8 of the Commission’s
regulations requires capacity release
transactions to be posted for competitive
bidding, unless the transactions are at
the maximum rate or are for 31 days or
less.114 Section 284.8 also allows the
releasing shipper to enter into a ‘‘prearranged’’ release with a designated
replacement shipper before any posting
for bidding.115 Prearranged releases are
subject to the same bidding
requirements as other releases; however,
the prearranged replacement shipper
will receive the capacity if it matches
the highest bid submitted by any other
bidder.116
115. As noted, in an AMA, the
releasing shipper typically enters into a
prearranged deal to release all of its
pipeline capacity at the maximum rate
to the marketer. It is reasonable to
surmise that the main reason for the
maximum release rate is so the release
will qualify for the exemption from
bidding of all maximum rate
prearranged capacity releases. By
avoiding the requirement to post the
release for bidding, the releasing
shipper can ensure that the capacity
will go to the asset manager whom the
releasing shipper has determined will
provide the most effective asset
management services.
116. As described above, however, the
releasing shipper may agree to rebate
some or all of the demand charge to the
marketer so that the marketer’s actual
cost of obtaining the capacity is
something less than the maximum rate.
The Commission has held that such
rebates render the release to be at less
than the maximum rate, thereby
113 Since Order No. 636–A, the Commission has
granted several waivers of the prohibition against
tying, Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 113 FERC
¶ 61,106 (2005); Northwest Pipeline Corp. and Duke
Energy Trading and Marketing, 109 FERC ¶ 61,044
(2004), but only where an entity sought the waiver
to exit the natural gas transportation business. See
Louis Dreyfus Energy Services, L.P., 114 FERC
¶ 61,246, at 61,780 (2006), denying a waiver
request.
114 18 CFR 284.8(h).
115 18 CFR 284.8(b).
116 18 CFR 284.8(e).
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
requiring that the prearranged release be
posted for bidding.117
117. Moreover, as described above,
some AMAs may require the asset
manager (replacement shipper) to pay
fees to the releasing shipper. The
Commission has ruled that if the
prearranged release is at the maximum
rate, such additional payments violate
the maximum rate ceiling on capacity
releases.118
B. Discussion
118. In this rule, the Commission is
revising its capacity release regulations
and policies in order to facilitate the use
of AMAs. Based on the industry-wide
support for AMAs as shown in the
comments, the Commission finds that
AMAs are in the public interest because
they are beneficial to numerous market
participants and to the market in
general. Thus, the Commission is
modifying the prohibition on tying, the
section 284.8 regulations concerning
bidding, and making additional policy
changes requested by the commenters
discussed below in order to eliminate
obstacles to the utilization and
implementation of AMAs.
119. AMAs are a relatively recent
development in the natural gas market,
which the Commission did not
anticipate when it adopted the capacity
release program in Order No. 636. The
purpose of that program was to permit
shippers to ‘‘reallocate unneeded firm
capacity’’ to those who do need it.119
The bidding requirements of section
284.8 and the prohibition against tying
the release to extraneous conditions
were all part of the Commission’s
fundamental goal of ensuring that such
unneeded capacity would be reallocated
to the person who values it the most.
The Commission found that such
‘‘capacity reallocation will promote
117 In Louis Dreyfus Energy Services, L.P, 114
FERC ¶ 61,246 (2006), the Commission stated that:
[t]he Commission has held that any consideration
paid by the releasing shipper to a prearranged
replacement shipper must be taken into account in
determining whether the prearranged release is at
the maximum rate. For instance, where the
replacement shipper agrees to pay the pipeline the
maximum rate for the released capacity, but the
releasing shipper agrees to make a payment to the
replacement shipper, the release must be treated as
a release at less than the maximum rate to which
the posting and bidding requirements of sections
284.8(c) through (e) apply. Id. at P 15, citing, Pacific
Gas Transmission Co. and Southern California
Edison Co., 82 FERC ¶ 61,227 (1998).
118 See Consumers Energy Co., 82 FERC ¶ 61,284,
order approving settlement, 84 FERC ¶ 61,240
(1998). See also Order No. 636–A at 30,561, where
the Commission stated that capacity cannot be
‘‘resold at a rate including the pipeline marketing
fee. The marketing fee is not part of the cost of
transportation being released and the replacement
shipper should not pay more than the maximum
transportation rate for the capacity it is acquiring.’’
119 Order No. 636 at 30,418.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
efficient load management by the
pipeline and its customers and,
therefore, efficient use of pipeline
capacity on a firm basis throughout the
year.’’ 120
120. The Commission thus developed
its capacity release policies and
regulations based on the assumption
that shippers would handle their own
gas purchase and transportation
arrangements and release their capacity
only when they were not using the
capacity to serve their own needs. For
example, the Commission envisioned
that LDCs with long-term contracts for
firm transportation service up to the
peak needs of their retail customers
would, during off-peak periods, release
that portion of capacity not needed to
serve the lower off-peak demand of its
retail customers but otherwise would
retain the capacity to serve their own
needs.
121. However, this basic assumption
underlying the capacity release program
does not hold true in the context of
AMAs. As the Commission stated in the
NOPR, a distinguishing factor between
standard capacity releases and AMAs is
that in the AMA context, the releasing
shipper is not releasing unneeded
capacity, but capacity that it needs to
serve its own supply function. Releasing
shippers in the AMA context are
releasing capacity for the primary
purpose of transferring the capacity to
entities that they perceive have greater
skill and expertise both in purchasing
low cost gas supplies, and in
maximizing the value of the capacity
when it is not needed to meet the
releasing shipper’s gas supply needs. In
short, AMAs entail the releasing shipper
transferring its capacity to a third party
expert who will perform the functions
the Commission expected releasing
shippers would do for themselves—
purchase their own gas supplies and
release capacity or make bundled sales
when the releasing shipper does not
need the capacity to satisfy its own
needs. The goal of the changes adopted
by the Commission herein is to make
the capacity release program more
efficient by bringing it in line with these
developments in today’s secondary gas
markets.
122. As virtually all the commenters
on the NOPR agree, AMAs provide
significant benefits to a variety of
participants in the natural gas and
electric marketplaces and to the
secondary natural gas market itself. One
of the most important aspects of AMAs
is that they provide broad benefits to the
marketplace in general. By permitting
capacity holders to use third party
121 See e.g., Comments of the EPSA, Comments of
the EEI, Comments of FPL and Comments of the
120 Id.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
experts to manage their gas supply
arrangements and their pipeline
capacity, AMAs provide for lower gas
supply costs and more efficient use of
the pipeline grid. Asset managers have
resources and market knowledge not
necessarily available to natural gas
capacity holders, such as trading
platforms, credit portfolios, hedge fund
and risk management experience, cost
containment and counterparty credit
and contracting expertise, which allow
asset managers to better maximize the
value of the releasing party’s assets and
manage the associated risk. AMAs bring
diversity to the mix of capacity holders
and customers that are served through
the capacity release program, thus
enhancing liquidity and diversity for
natural gas products and services.
AMAs result in an overall increase in
the use of interstate pipeline capacity,
as well as facilitating the use of capacity
by different types of customers in
addition to LDCs. AMAs benefit the
natural gas market by creating
efficiencies as a result of more load
responsive gas supply, and an increased
utilization of transportation capacity.
123. AMAs are an important
mechanism used by LDCs to enhance
their participation in the secondary
market and allow LDCs to increase the
utilization of facilities and lower gas
costs. They provide the needed
flexibility to customize arrangements to
meet unique customer needs. AMAs
allow LDCs to use an entity with more
expertise to manage their gas supply
and thus relieve LDCs of administrative
burdens. The ability of LDCs to use
AMAs as a means of relieving the
burdens of administering their capacity
or supply needs on a daily basis also
works to the benefit of the entire market
because that burden may at times result
in LDCs not releasing unused capacity.
124. AMAs also provide LDCs and
their customers an increased ability to
offset their upstream transportation
costs. The profit sharing arrangements
in AMAs often allow an LDC to reduce
reservation costs that it normally passes
on to its customers. They foster market
efficiency by allowing the releasing
shipper to reduce its costs to the extent
that its capacity is used to facilitate a
third party sale that also benefits that
third party.
125. LDCs are not the only entities
that benefit from AMAs. As evidenced
by certain comments on the NOPR,
many other large gas purchasers,
including electric generators and
industrial users, may desire to enter into
such arrangements.121 AMAs increase
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37079
the ability of wholesale electric
generators to provide customer benefits
through superior management of fuel
supply risk, allow generators to focus
their attention on the electric market,
and eliminate administrative burdens
relating to multiple suppliers,
overheads, capital requirements and the
risks associated with marketing excess
gas and pipeline imbalances.
126. Finally, AMAs bring benefits to
consumers, mostly through reductions
in consumer costs. AMAs provide in
general for lower gas supply costs,
resulting in ultimate savings for end use
customers. The overall market benefits
described above also inure to
consumers. These benefits have been
recognized by state commissions and
the National Regulatory Research
Institute.122 In light of these substantial
benefits provided by AMAs, the
Commission is modifying its capacity
release regulations and policies in the
specific respects discussed below.
1. Tying
127. First, the Commission adopts its
proposal to exempt AMAs from the
prohibition against tying in order to
permit a releasing shipper in a prearranged release to require that the
replacement shipper (1) agree to supply
the releasing shipper’s gas requirements
and (2) take assignment of the releasing
shipper’s gas supply contracts, as well
as released transportation capacity on
one or more pipelines 123 and storage
capacity with the gas currently in
storage. This exemption will allow firm
shippers to pre-arrange releases of
capacity to an asset manager
(replacement shipper) along with
upstream assets and gas purchase
agreements in a bundled transaction
where the capacity being released will
NWIGU. See also Comments of NJNG to the
Commission’s January 3, 2007 request for comments
(‘‘in addition to LDCs, there are many other types
of large natural gas purchasers, such as electric
generation facilities and large gas process industrial
users, who face the same challenges with managing
and optimizing their natural gas portfolios. These
customers, whose core business lies outside the
natural gas industry—are also likely consumers of
third party portfolio management services.’’) at 9,
n.9.
122 See e.g., Comments of BGEM to the January 3,
2007 request for comments at 8–9, citing to the
Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission’s order in
Case No. 42, 973, approved April 25, 2006. See also
Orders of the Massachusetts Department of
Telecommunications and Energy, attached to the
Marketer Petitioners comments on the January 3,
2007 request for comments, which describe and
approve certain asset management arrangements.
123 Commission policy already permits a releasing
shipper to require a replacement shipper to take a
release of aggregated capacity contracts on one or
more pipelines, at least in some circumstances. See
Order No. 636–A at 30,558 and n.144.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37080
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
be used to meet that party’s gas supply
requirements.124
128. As discussed above, AMAs
provide recognizable benefits to market
participants and the marketplace overall
in terms of more load-responsive use of
gas supply, greater liquidity, increased
utilization of transportation capacity
and the overall efficiencies these
arrangements bring to the marketplace.
However, AMAs require that the
releasing shipper be able to release both
its capacity and its natural gas supply
arrangements in a single package. The
very purpose of the transaction would
be frustrated if the releasing shipper
could not combine the supply and
capacity components of the deal. This
tying is meant to ensure that the
released capacity will continue to be
used to support the releasing shipper’s
acquisition of needed gas supplies.
Based on the fact that AMAs provide
benefits to the market, and that tying of
capacity and supply is necessary to
implement beneficial AMAs, it is
reasonable to allow the tying conditions
discussed above in the AMA context in
order to foster and facilitate the use and
implementation of such arrangements.
129. All the commenters support this
change in Commission policy, except
Williston. Williston argues that
approval of the proposed changes to
exempt AMAs from the prohibition on
tying (as well as the bidding
requirements discussed in the next
section) would encourage
discrimination and preferential
treatment toward asset managers by
allowing participants in the secondary
capacity release market to engage in
activities prohibited to pipelines.125
According to Williston, allowing
releasing shippers to tie releases to a
requirement that the replacement
shipper provide asset management
services, and exempting such releases
from bidding, will give releasing
shippers a strong competitive edge over
the pipelines for the sale of similar
types of services. Williston asserts the
pipelines’ reduced sale of similar types
of services will result in increased firm
transportation rates charged by
pipelines. Williston also claims that
exempting AMAs from tying will nullify
the goal of awarding capacity to the
shipper that values it most and that
removing the bidding requirement will
inhibit transparency.126
124 The exemption is limited to releases to an
asset manager to implement an AMA, and does not
apply to re-releases to third parties during the term
of the AMA.
125 Comments of Williston Basin at 12–14.
126 The Commission explains in the next section
how the benefits AMAs outweigh any
disadvantages in exempting such releases from
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
130. Williston has failed to show that
exempting capacity releases to
implement AMAs from the prohibition
against tying and bidding will subject
pipelines to unfair competition.
Pipelines’ core business is providing
unbundled transportation services. By
contrast, a major component of asset
management service is the purchase and
sale of gas as a commodity. Williston
does not assert that it has any interest
in either providing or purchasing asset
management services. Therefore,
Williston has no need or reason to tie
the sale of its transportation services to
the provision of asset management
services. Many shippers, by contrast,
have indicated a desire to purchase (or
provide) asset management services,
and as discussed above, the Commission
has found that such services provide
substantial benefits to the natural gas
and electric markets as a whole.
Williston has not identified any tying
requirement that it would desire to
impose on the sale of its unsubscribed
capacity that would provide comparable
benefits to the market as a whole.
131. The Commission recognizes that,
to the extent asset managers are more
skilled at releasing and managing
capacity in competition with the
pipelines’ interruptible services,
pipelines may face increased
competition from capacity release as a
result of this rule. The Commission,
however, has always intended that
capacity releases would compete with
the pipelines’ short-term firm and
interruptible transportation services.127
Accordingly, the fact that this rule may
result in greater competition for
pipelines’ interruptible services is not a
compelling reason for the Commission
to decline to facilitate AMAs as set forth
in this Final Rule.
2. Bidding
132. Second, the Commission adopts
its proposal to exempt pre-arranged
releases to implement AMAs from the
bidding requirements of section 284.8 of
its regulations. In light of its experience
with capacity releases and the
comments discussed above, the
Commission concludes that, in the
bidding and how the Final Rule will continue to
satisfy the goals of disclosure and transparency.
127 See Order No. 636–A at 30,553 and 30,556
(stating ‘‘the Commission views the competition
between interruptible transportation and capacity
releasing as part of a healthy secondary market’’
and finding ‘‘pipeline capacity (firm and
interruptible) must compete with released
capacity’’); see also UDC v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105,
1149 (DC Cir. 1996) (recognizing that capacity
release is intended to develop an active secondary
market with holders of unutilized firm capacity
rights reselling those rights in competition with
capacity offered directly by the pipeline).
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
AMA context, the bidding requirement
creates an unwarranted obstacle to the
efficient management of pipeline
capacity and supply assets.
133. All capacity releases made to
implement AMAs are pre-arranged
because it is important that a releasing
shipper be able to use the asset manager
of its choice to effectuate the
components of the agreement. Unlike a
normal capacity release where the
releasing shipper is often shedding
excess capacity and has no intention of
an ongoing relationship with the
replacement shipper, in the AMA
context the identity of the replacement
shipper is often critical because it will
manage the releasing shipper’s portfolio
for some time into the future. During the
process of choosing an asset manager
(often an RFP process), the releasing
shipper considers a number of factors,
including experience in managing
capacity and gas sales, experience with
a particular pipeline or area of the
country, flexibility, creditworthiness
and price. Because the asset manager
will manage the releasing shipper’s gas
supply operations on an ongoing basis,
it is critical that the releasing shipper be
able to release the capacity to its chosen
asset manager. Requiring releases made
in order to implement an AMA to be
posted for bidding would thus interfere
with the negotiation of beneficial
AMAs, by potentially preventing the
releasing shipper from releasing the
capacity to its chosen asset manager.
Moreover, AMAs at their core entail a
bundling of commodity sales with
capacity release. As a result, it is
difficult to have meaningful bidding on
the released capacity as a stand-alone
component of the arrangement, because
the values of the commodity and
capacity components of the arrangement
are not easily separated. The
Commission concludes that the benefits
of facilitating AMAs outweigh any
disadvantages in exempting such
releases from bidding.
134. The exemption from bidding
adopted by this rule will apply to all
releases to asset managers, made for the
purpose of implementing an AMA,
regardless of the term of the AMA and
whether the release is subject to the
price ceiling. As discussed above, in
this rule the Commission is removing
the price ceiling for all short-term
capacity release transactions of one year
or less, but is continuing the price
ceiling for capacity release transactions
of more than one year. In the NOPR, the
Commission stated that, if the parties
wanted to continue an uncapped shortterm capacity release beyond one year,
the release ‘‘would have to be re-posted
for bidding to ensure the capacity is
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
allocated to the highest valued use.’’ 128
Some commenters 129 request that the
Commission clarify that the reposting
and bidding requirements for extending
uncapped, short-term capacity releases
beyond one year do not apply in the
context of short-term AMAs. They assert
that the proposed exemption from
bidding for capacity releases to asset
managers should apply in all
circumstances, including the
circumstance of an expiring short-term
release related to an AMA. In essence,
they inquire whether the reposting and
bidding requirements for extensions of
short-term capacity releases would
trump the general exemption from
bidding requirements proposed by the
Commission for AMAs.
135. The Commission clarifies that
the exemption from bidding for AMAs
adopted in this rule applies to all
releases to an asset manager, including
those made for the purpose of extending
a short-term AMA.130 The rationale for
exempting releases to an asset manager
from bidding applies equally to releases
made for the purpose of extending a
short-term AMA as to any other release
to an asset manager. In all such releases,
the identity of the asset manager is
critical to the releasing shipper, because
the releasing shipper will be relying on
the asset manager to obtain its gas
supplies. Therefore, as with any other
release to an asset manager, requiring
releases made for the purpose of
extending a short-term AMA to be
posted for bidding could interfere with
the negotiation of beneficial AMAs by
potentially preventing such releases to
be made to the releasing shipper’s
chosen asset manager.
136. While the Commission is
exempting releases made to implement
AMAs from the capacity release bidding
requirements, those releases will remain
subject to existing posting and reporting
requirements, including the section
284.13(c)(2)(viii) requirement to post the
name of any asset manager. In addition,
as discussed below, the Commission is
adding a requirement to post the asset
128 NOPR
at P 44.
e.g., comments of Southwest and BGEM.
130 Section 284.8(h)(1), as adopted by this rule,
provides a blanket exemption from posting and
bidding for all releases to an asset manager:
A release of capacity by a firm shipper to a
replacement shipper for any period of 31 days or
less, a release of capacity for more than one year
at the maximum tariff rate, or a release to an asset
manager as defined in (h)(3) of this section need not
comply with the notification and bidding
requirements of paragraphs (c) through (e) of this
section. (emphasis added).
The section 284.8(h)(2) prohibition on extending
exempt releases without posting and bidding
expressly applies only to the first category of
releases included in the section 284.8(h)(1)
exemption: Releases for a period of 31 days or less.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
129 See
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
manager’s delivery obligation to the
releasing shipper. Therefore, the
Commission’s goals of disclosure and
transparency will still be met.
Williston’s argument that the exemption
from bidding for AMAs will impair
transparency and allow deals to be
consummated without Commission or
market participant knowledge thus
fails.131
137. The exemption from bidding
adopted by this rule does not extend to
releases made outside the AMA context.
There has been no showing that nonAMA prearranged releases provide
benefits of the type we have found
justify exempting AMA releases from
bidding. Moreover, in the typical nonAMA pre-arranged release, price is the
primary factor, and therefore the
releasing shipper should generally be
indifferent as to the identity of the
replacement shipper so long as it
receives the highest possible price.
Accordingly, non-maximum rate
capacity releases of more than 31 days,
made outside the AMA context, will
still need to be posted for bidding in
order to ensure that the capacity is
allocated to the highest valued use.
3. Definition of AMAs
a. NOPR Proposal
138. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed to define AMAs that would
qualify for the tying and bidding
exemptions, as follows:
Any pre-arranged release that contains a
condition that the releasing shipper may, on
any day, call upon the replacement shipper
to deliver to the releasing shipper a volume
of gas equal to the daily contract demand of
the released transportation capacity. If the
capacity release is a release of storage
capacity, the asset manager’s delivery
obligation need only equal the daily contract
demand under the release for storage
withdrawals (emphasis added).
139. The Commission developed this
definition in order to address two
concerns relating to its facilitation of
AMAs. It wanted to limit the
exemptions from tying and bidding to
bona fide AMAs, that is, arrangements
that place a significant delivery
obligation on the replacement shipper
so as to distinguish AMAs eligible for
the exemptions from standard capacity
releases. The Commission also sought to
avoid a definition that was too narrow
131 Williston Basin is also incorrect in suggesting
that the Commission requires pipelines to sell their
available capacity in a bidding auction. See
Northern Natural Gas Co., 110 FERC ¶ 61,361, at P
10 (2005) (‘‘[T]he Commission has not required
pipelines to sell capacity solely through open
seasons. Rather, so long as the pipeline posts all
available firm capacity, it may sell that capacity on
a first-come, first-served basis’’).
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37081
and would effectively limit efficient and
innovative AMAs. The Commission
focused on what it understood to be the
fundamental purpose of AMAs, namely
that the asset manager would use the
released capacity to deliver gas supplies
to the releasing shipper. Thus, it
included the requirement that the
replacement shipper contractually
commit itself to deliver to the releasing
shipper, on any day, gas supplies equal
to the daily contract demand of the
released capacity. The Commission
reasoned this would achieve the goal of
exempting only bona fide AMA
transactions from bidding and the
prohibition against tying.
140. The Commission also believed
that the proposed definition was
sufficiently flexible to allow releasing
shippers to use AMAs to obtain only a
portion of its required gas supplies or to
enter into multiple AMAs with different
asset managers. In addition, the
Commission noted that the proposed
definition does not require that the asset
manager make all its deliveries to the
releasing shipper over the released
capacity, nor did it limit the types of
entities that can use AMAs and take
advantage of the exemptions. The
Commission recognized that electric
generators and industrial end-users may
make use of AMAs, and thus the
exemption is not limited to LDCs
utilizing AMAs.
b. Comments
141. Numerous commenters 132
requested that the Commission revise or
clarify the ‘‘on any day’’ and/or the
‘‘equal to’’ phrases highlighted in the
definition above. They claim that ‘‘on
any day’’ may be interpreted as
requiring the asset manager to stand
ready to deliver the contract quantity on
‘‘every day’’ in order for the
arrangement to be considered an AMA.
Commenters assert that such a
requirement would severely inhibit the
asset manager’s flexibility and its ability
to maximize the value of the capacity.
Many commenters also seek to replace
‘‘equal to’’ the daily contract demand of
the released capacity with ‘‘up to.’’
Again, commenters cite a lack of
flexibility and devaluation of the
released capacity because it would
inhibit the asset manager from rereleasing the capacity. Commenters note
that the beneficial aspects of AMAs are
hindered if the asset manager must hold
in reserve the entire portfolio of its
132 Those commenters include the AGA, BGEM,
BP, Canadian Association of Petroleum Producers
(CAPP), FPL Hess, the Marketer Petitioners,
National Grid, NJNG, NGSA, Nicor Enerchange
(Nicor), NJR, Piedmont, PPM, PSNC, SCE&G, SEMI,
Sequent, Statoil and WDG.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37082
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
assets even on days when the releasing
shipper does not need the capacity for
its supply needs.
142. Commenters suggest several
general language changes to remedy
these perceived problems. AGA
recommends that the Commission
clarify the definition by adding ‘‘but not
necessarily every day’’ after the phrase
‘‘on any day.’’ It also suggests changing
‘‘equal to’’ to ‘‘up to’’ as noted above.133
BGEM agrees with this latter change, as
do FPL, National Grid, PPM, and PSNC.
Others take a broader view, suggesting
that the delivery obligation should be
left to the parties to negotiate. BP, for
example, advocates permitting the
parties to determine by mutual
agreement when the releasing shipper
may call upon the replacement shipper
to deliver to it a volume of gas equal to
the daily contract demand.134 Numerous
parties agree with the concept that the
details of the delivery obligation should
be left to the parties and spelled out in
the contract. NGSA comments that
‘‘may, on any day, call upon’’ should be
revised to ‘‘may, as agreed by the
parties, require. * * *’’ 135 Nicor would
add the phrase ‘‘pursuant to the terms
of its contract’’ after ‘‘any day’’. It would
also clarify that the replacement shipper
should be required to deliver gas to a
‘‘location’’ specified in the
agreement.136 Piedmont suggests that
parties be permitted to negotiate call
rights ‘‘as necessary and appropriate for
the contracting parties.’’ 137 SCANA
suggests that because the releasing
shipper is in the best position to know
the appropriate level of delivery
obligation it will require, the definition
should be revised to clarify that the
delivery requirement is limited to
specified days set forth in the
agreement.138 The WDG suggests that
parties should be given the flexibility to
‘‘tailor’’ capacity recall rights in AMA
transactions to the releasing shipper’s
market and supply needs.139
143. NJNG also recommends that the
definition of AMA be clarified such that
a releasing shipper’s recall rights up to
the maximum daily quantity of the
released capacity is limited to use by the
releasing shipper for its ‘‘own load’’
requirements—either its utility retail
service obligation or its own system
generation or consumption needs.
133 AGA provides a revised definition on page 21
of its comments.
134 See BP comments at 2, 5–8.
135 NGSA comments at 10.
136 Nicor comments at 2–3.
137 Piedmont comments at 6.
138 Scana comments at 4–7.
139 WDG comments at 4–5.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
c. Modified Definition
144. In light of the comments
received, the Commission has
reconsidered its definition of AMAs and
in this rule is modifying the definition
to strike a balance between facilitating
flexible and innovative AMAs and
drawing a clear line between AMAs and
standard capacity releases.140 The
specific modifications to the definition
which the Commission is making for
this purpose are shown in bold below:
Any pre-arranged release that contains a
condition that the releasing shipper may, on
any day during a minimum period of five
months out of each twelve-month period of
the release, call upon the replacement
shipper to deliver to the releasing shipper a
volume of gas up to one-hundred percent of
the daily contract demand of the released
transportation capacity. If the capacity
release is for a period of less than one year,
the asset manager’s delivery obligation
described in the previous sentence must
apply for the lesser of five months or the term
of the release. If the capacity release is a
release of storage capacity, the asset
manager’s delivery obligation need only be
one-hundred percent of the daily contract
demand under the release for storage
withdrawals.141
145. The Commission finds that this
definition of AMA will further its goal
of delineating AMAs from standard
capacity releases. First, it continues to
differentiate bona fide AMAs from
standard capacity releases by placing a
significant delivery obligation,
applicable during at least five months
out of each 12 month period of the
release, on the asset manager, while
alleviating the concerns of those
commenters that assert the NOPR
definition was too restrictive. The
Commission has replaced ‘‘equal’’ in the
definition with ‘‘up to’’ in order to
clarify that the asset manager does not
have to actually make deliveries equal
to the daily contract demand on every
day the delivery obligation is in effect.
However, by using the phrase ‘‘up to’’
in the adopted definition, the
Commission doest not intend to allow
the parties to negotiate a potential
delivery obligation of less than one
hundred percent of the daily contract
demand for the required time period,
even though that amount may not
actually be delivered to the releasing
140 As discussed in detail below, the Commission
is also revising the AMA definition to allow for
supply AMAs and to extend to retail state
unbundling programs the same blanket exemption
from bidding granted for AMAs.
141 The annual five month minimum would apply
to AMAs with terms of one year or longer. The
delivery obligation for any AMA between five
months and a year would be for five months of the
release. The delivery obligation would apply to the
entire term for any AMA of less than five months.
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
shipper every day. Before entering into
an AMA an asset manager should be
able to make reasonable judgments
about the releasing shipper’s
requirements based upon the releasing
shipper’s gas usage in earlier years, and
thus make reliable estimations as to
when it can use the capacity for
bundled sales or re-releases. Thus,
under the definition adopted in this
rule, the releasing shipper will have the
right to call upon the asset manager to
deliver the full contract volume on
every day of the five month minimum,
though it need not actually do so. This
delivery obligation for the asset manager
will adequately distinguish AMAs from
standard capacity releases as well as
ensure that AMAs eligible for the
exemptions from tying and bidding will
fulfill the primary purpose of using the
releasing shipper’s capacity to supply
its gas needs during peak periods.
146. The definition also furthers the
goal of defining AMAs in such a way
that they will be flexible enough to
allow diverse parties to enter into AMAs
and for those parties to be able to
maximize the value of pipeline capacity
within the context of an AMA. The
definition only requires a delivery
obligation on behalf of the replacement
shipper for a portion of each twelve
month period, thus giving the asset
manager additional assurance it can
utilize the capacity during non peak
periods. The definition adopted in this
rule also allows for releasing shippers to
only release a portion of their capacity,
places no limitations on the asset
manager that would require it to use the
released capacity to make its deliveries
to the releasing shipper, and does not
limit the type of party that can enter
into an AMA.
147. The Commission considered the
comments that the extent of the asset
manager’s delivery obligation should be
left to the parties to negotiate
themselves but ultimately determined
that approach would not further the
primary goal of AMAs that they be used
to serve the releasing shipper’s supply
needs. Absent a specific delivery
obligation in the definition, there would
be no assurances that capacity releases
meant to implement an AMA would
actually contain a substantial delivery
obligation that would differentiate it
from a standard capacity release. Parties
would be able to enter into
arrangements that may require an asset
manager to deliver supply to the
releasing shipper on only one day of the
year for instance. Such arrangements
would technically qualify as AMAs but
would not serve the Commission’s goal
to ensure that AMAs be used to serve
the releasing shipper’s needs.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
Accordingly, the Commission does not
deem it appropriate to grant the benefits
of the exemptions from tying and
bidding to such arrangements.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
4. Supply AMAs
148. In the NOPR the Commission
sought comments on whether it should
expand the definition of AMAs and if
so, how supply side AMAs should be
distinguished from other capacity
releases. The Commission in this Final
Rule is revising its regulations and the
proposed definition of AMAs to allow
for supply side AMAs. Pursuant to the
revised definition for AMAs discussed
below, a supply AMA will be
distinguishable from a standard capacity
release, and thus eligible for the tying
and bidding exemptions, only if it
includes a condition that requires the
replacement shipper to purchase a
volume from the releasing shipper up to
the maximum daily contract demand of
the released capacity.
149. In general, gas supply AMAs are
arrangements where a production area
capacity holder releases capacity to an
asset manager that commits to purchase
(receive) the releasing shipper’s gas and
use the capacity to transport and market
that gas. The asset manager nets back to
the producer a fixed percentage of the
price that the asset manager is able to
obtain for resale of the gas on a
delivered basis. Numerous producer and
marketer commenters filed in favor of
AMAs for gas sellers.142 No commenter
opposed expanding the AMA definition
to include gas supply AMAs.
150. Based on the comments received,
the Commission finds that the benefits
of AMAs as identified in the NOPR
apply with equal weight to producers
that want to optimize the value of their
capacity and minimize costs. The
Commission understands from producer
commenters that producers often
acquire firm pipeline capacity for flow
assurance, that is, to ensure that there
will be sufficient capacity to transport
the gas they produce to relevant
markets.143 Because of the fluctuation in
flows related to new wells in particular,
producers often purchase capacity in
excess of their immediate needs to
ensure that there is sufficient capacity
for their gas to flow once the production
volumes ramp up. The Commission’s
approval of supply AMAs will allow a
producer to release all of its capacity to
an asset manager who could maximize
the value of that capacity during the
142 See e.g., comments of NGSA, BGEM, BP,
Dominion Marketers, FPL, Marketer Petitioners,
Mewbourne Oil, NEM, Nicor, NJR, Statoil, Ultra,
Walter Oil and Gas, and the Wyoming Pipeline
Authority.
143 See e.g., comments of BP.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
start-up period when producers may not
need it, resulting in increased and
efficient use of capacity.
151. The Commission also finds that
the rationale supporting AMAs for end
users equally supports supply AMAs.
Supply AMAs will help to alleviate a
producer’s burden of administering
capacity on a day to day basis, will
maximize the value of pipeline capacity,
and will further diversify the mix of
capacity holders and customers served
through capacity releases. Similar to
delivery AMAs, supply AMAs involve
an ongoing relationship between the
releasing shipper and the asset manager
that differentiates the deals from normal
capacity releases.144 Further, supply
AMA capacity will be used for its
original purpose, that is, to transport the
producer’s gas to the market place. The
Commission finds reasonable comments
that the purchase obligation in a supply
side AMA is a mirror image of the
delivery obligation required by the
Commission for the downstream AMA’s
facilitated in the NOPR.145
152. As discussed above, in the
Commission’s view the most important
aspect of a supply AMA is the
requirement that the asset manager
commit to purchasing the releasing
shipper’s gas as a part of the agreement.
While several commenters suggest
definitional language for gas supply
AMAs that would require the
replacement shipper to ‘‘receive’’ the
releasing shipper’s gas,146 the
Commission finds that the condition
must be to ‘‘purchase’’ the gas in order
to avoid running afoul of the shipper
must have title rule.147 This condition
144 See
e.g., comments of NGSA at 14.
of NGSA at 13, comments of Ultra
145 Comment
at 8.
146 For example, Statoil states that the
Commission should extend the exemption to
include supply-side AMAs by expanding its
proposed section 284.8(h) as follows:
(h)(3) A release to an asset manager exempt from
bidding requirements under paragraph (h)(1) of this
section is any prearranged capacity release that
contains a condition that the releasing shipper may,
on any day, call upon the replacement shipper to
(i) deliver to the releasing shipper a volume of gas
equal to the daily contract demand of the released
transportation capacity or the daily contract
demand for storage withdrawals or (ii) receive from
the releasing shipper a volume of gas equal to the
daily contract demand of the released
transportation capacity or the daily contract
demand for storage withdrawals. Statoil comments
at 12–13.
147 As described in the comments, a typical
supply AMA could involve a requirement that the
replacement shipper accept delivery of the releasing
shipper’s gas, and use the capacity released to ship
and market that gas. Under that scenario, where the
replacement shipper would accept the releasing
shipper’s gas and transport that gas on the released
capacity to the releasing shippers’ customers, the
arrangement would violate the Commission’s
requirement that the shipper hold title to the gas.
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37083
would also help ensure that such
arrangements are bona fide AMAs
because it imposes a significant
purchase obligation on the asset
manager.
153. Based on the determination to
allow supply AMAs, the Commission
will further modify the proposed
definition of capacity releases to asset
managers to accommodate supply
AMAs. Thus, the full definition of the
capacity releases that will be eligible for
the tying and bidding exemptions
adopted by this rule is as follows:
Any pre-arranged release that contains a
condition that the releasing shipper may, on
any day during a minimum period of five
months out of each twelve-month period of
the release, call upon the replacement
shipper to (i) deliver to the releasing shipper
a volume of gas up to one-hundred percent
of the daily contract demand of the released
transportation capacity or (ii) purchase a
volume of gas up to the daily contract
demand of the released transportation
capacity. If the capacity release is for a period
of less than one year, the asset manager’s
delivery or purchase obligation described in
the previous sentence must apply for the
lesser of five months or the term of the
release. If the capacity release is a release of
storage capacity, the asset manager’s delivery
or purchase obligation need only be onehundred percent of the daily contract
demand under the release for storage
withdrawals or injections, as applicable.
5. AMA Profit Sharing Arrangements
154. AMAs generally include
provisions for the asset manager to share
with the releasing shipper the value it
is able to obtain from the releasing
shipper’s capacity and other assigned
assets when those assets are not used to
serve the releasing shipper. The
manager may share that value by: (1)
Paying a fixed ‘‘optimization’’ fee to the
releasing shipper; (2) sharing with the
releasing shipper the asset manager’s
profits from the use of the released
capacity and other assigned assets 148
pursuant to an agreed-upon formula; (3)
making gas sales to the releasing shipper
at a below-market commodity price; or
(4) in some other way mutually agreed
to by the contracting parties.149
The shipper in that situation would be the
replacement shipper, and it would be transporting
gas that was owned by the releasing shipper. Thus,
in order for there to be a valid supply AMA, the
replacement shipper must purchase and take title
to the gas that it will ship for the releasing shipper.
148 These uses could include re-releases of the
capacity or bundled sales to third parties.
149 The AMA may also require the releasing
shipper to make payments to the manager for the
services performed by the manager for the releasing
shipper under the AMA. These payments may
include the releasing shipper paying the manager:
(1) A management fee for transportation related
tasks (e.g. nominations, scheduling, storage
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
Continued
30JNR2
37084
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
155. As discussed above, while this
rule removes the price ceiling for all
short-term capacity release transactions
of one year or less, the Commission is
continuing the price ceiling for capacity
release transactions of more than one
year. Numerous commenters, including
marketers, LDCs, and producers are
concerned that AMA profit sharing
arrangements, such as those described
above, may be considered to violate the
price ceiling for long-term capacity
releases. Accordingly, they contend that
the Commission should either (1)
exempt long-term capacity releases to
asset managers from the price ceiling or
(2) determine that the maximum rate
does not apply to the asset manager’s
payments to the releasing shipper under
such profit sharing arrangements.
156. AGA, FPL, Integrys,150 the
Marketer Petitioners, NGSA, PGC,
NWIGU, Southwest, and others request
that the Commission clarify that the
various payments made by or to an asset
manager under an AMA will not be
attributed or imputed to the
transportation component of an AMA,
and that payments by the parties to one
another will not be viewed as causing
the maximum rate ceiling to be
exceeded for any releases made
pursuant to an AMA. Alternatively, they
request that the Commission clarify that
the price ceiling is removed for all
capacity releases associated with an
AMA, regardless of their term.
157. These commenters explain that
applying the price ceiling to profit
sharing arrangements in long-term
releases to an asset manager could
significantly hinder parties’ ability to
successfully structure an acceptable
AMA. They assert that limiting the
compensation the releasing shipper can
collect from the asset manager under
long-term releases would prevent the
releasing shipper from sharing in the
full market value the asset manager is
able to obtain from the capacity,
contrary to the basic purpose of an
AMA. This could discourage parties
from entering into AMAs with terms of
more than a year. These commenters
further state that the parties frequently
desire to enter into AMAs with terms of
two or three years, because longer-term
AMAs provide the parties with a greater
ability to plan their business operations
injections) associated with the manager’s obligation
to provide gas supplies to the releasing shipper, and
(2) the manager’s cost of purchasing gas supplies for
the releasing shipper.
150 The Integrys Gas Group (Integrys) consists of
the Michigan Gas Utilities Corporation, Minnesota
Energy Resources Corporation, North Shore Gas
Company, The Peoples Gas Light and Coke
Company, and Wisconsin Public Service
Corporation.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
for a longer period of time and are
administratively more efficient.
158. In response to these comments,
the Commission is modifying section
284.8(b) of its regulations to clarify that
the price ceiling does not apply to any
consideration provided by an asset
manager to the releasing shipper as part
of an AMA. However, apart from this
clarification, capacity releases of more
than one year to an asset manager will,
like any other long-term capacity
release, remain subject to the price
ceiling. This modification of the
Commission’s regulations will provide
the parties to an AMA the flexibility to
negotiate mutually acceptable
arrangements under which the asset
manager shares with the releasing
shipper the value it obtains from the
released capacity, without running afoul
of the capacity release price ceiling.
However, the price ceiling will continue
to apply to the rates the asset manager
pays to the pipeline for the released
capacity.151
159. The Commission finds that this
change in its regulations is consistent
with the overall goal of this rulemaking
of facilitating beneficial AMAs. In the
AMA context, unlike in other capacity
release situations, the releasing shipper
is not releasing unneeded capacity, but
capacity that is needed to serve its own
supply function and will be so used
during the term of the release. Releasing
shippers enter into AMAs ‘‘for the
primary purpose of transferring the[ir]
capacity to entities they perceive have
greater skill and expertise both in
purchasing low cost gas supplies and in
maximizing the value of the capacity
when it is not needed to meet the
releasing shipper’s gas supply needs. In
short, AMAs entail the releasing shipper
transferring its capacity to another
entity that will perform the functions
the Commission expected releasing
151 As pointed out in the NOPR, in Consumers
Energy Co., 82 FERC ¶ 61,284, order approving
settlement, 84 FERC ¶ 61,240 (1998), the
Commission investigated certain joint marketing
agreements whereby replacement shippers agreed
either to share with the releasing shipper revenues
obtained by the replacement shippers on the sales
of the gas transported by means of the released
capacity or to pay the releasing shipper prices based
on the amount of gas bought and sold. The
Commission found in this situation that Consumers
had collected money in excess of the pipeline’s
maximum rate, thereby violating the capacity
release price ceiling. Recently, the Commission
similarly held in Louis Dreyfus Energy Services,
L.P., 114 FERC ¶ 61,246, at 61,779 (2006), that if
a pre-arranged release is at the maximum rate,
additional payments by the replacement shipper to
the releasing shipper are deemed to render the
release price above the maximum rate. As a result
of the modification to section 284.8(b) adopted in
this rule, these precedents will not apply in the
context of capacity releases to asset managers.
However, these precedents will continue to apply
to all other capacity releases.
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
shippers would do for themselves—
purchase their own gas supplies and
release capacity or make bundled sales
when the releasing shipper does not
need the capacity to satisfy it owns
needs.’’ 152
160. Thus, a fundamental purpose of
an AMA is for the asset manager to
extract as much value from the released
capacity and assigned assets as possible
and to share that value with the
releasing shipper, who has contracted
with the asset manager precisely
because of the asset manager’s expertise
in this area. The asset manager generally
obtains revenues related to the released
capacity from two basic revenue
sources. First, the asset manager may
earn money through the re-release of the
releasing shipper’s capacity for a higher
value. For example, the asset manager
could enter into short-term re-releases of
the capacity that are not subject to the
price cap. Second, the asset manager
could garner funds through utilizing the
released capacity to make bundled sales
to third parties. In either situation, the
releasing shipper could have attempted
to garner these revenues by itself, but
instead it utilized the asset manager’s
skills through the use of an AMA to
increase the value of its capacity.153
161. Given that the purpose of an
AMA is to allow a releasing shipper to
maximize the value of its capacity by
obtaining the services of an asset
manager with greater expertise at
accomplishing that goal, it makes little
sense to apply the price ceiling on longterm capacity releases in a manner
which limits the amount of that value
which the asset manager can share with
the releasing shipper. As discussed
above, permitting the asset manager to
maximize the value of released capacity
and share that value with the releasing
shipper provides numerous benefits,
including reducing the releasing
shipper’s costs of reserving pipeline
capacity, and these benefits ultimately
serve to reduce consumer costs.
Moreover, as some commenters point
out, applying the long-term capacity
release price ceiling to AMA profit
sharing arrangements would likely
152 NOPR
at P 66.
are a number of other potential methods
for an asset manager to gain additional revenues
from a releasing shipper’s transportation, storage,
gas supply, and hedging ‘‘assets’’. An asset manager
may use the full range of acquired ‘‘assets’’ to enter
into a variety of financial, commodity,
transportation, or storage-related arrangements
which allows the asset manager to generate more
revenues from these ‘‘assets,’’ when they are not
needed to serve the releasing shipper’s direct needs,
than the releasing shipper would have generated on
its own. We do not mean to suggest here any limit
to the range of legally-allowed transactions that an
asset manager may pursue, but merely provide
illustrative examples.
153 There
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
discourage parties from negotiating
AMAs with terms of more than a year
in order to avoid the price ceiling.
However, longer-term AMAs may
provide the parties significant
advantages, for example, by enabling the
parties to obtain greater certainty
concerning their gas supply and sale
arrangements for a longer period of time
and by minimizing the administrative
costs of negotiating multiple AMA
arrangements over a relatively short
period of time.
162. Thus, the Commission concludes
that profit sharing agreements between
the releasing shipper and the
replacement shipper in the context of an
AMA, where the releasing shipper could
have earned the monies itself, should
not violate the price ceiling just because
the releasing shipper utilized the skills
of an asset manager. Modifying our
regulations to exempt all such profit
sharing arrangements from the price
ceiling will permit the parties flexibility
to craft AMAs in a manner that they
perceive as capturing the true value of
the release and related assignments of
other assets, consistent with our goal of
facilitating the use of AMAs.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
6. Exemption From Buy/Sell Prohibition
163. Some commenters state that they
wish to enter into AMAs whereby they
would release their capacity to an asset
manager, but would continue to
negotiate their own gas purchase
contracts. Because such gas supply
contracts would be competitively
negotiated arrangements containing
confidential pricing information, these
commenters do not want to assign such
contracts to the asset manager.154
Instead, they want to sell the gas they
purchase from their supplier to their
asset manager and then direct the asset
manager to transport the gas to their city
gate and resell the gas to them. These
commenters ask that the Commission
exempt such arrangements from the
Commission prohibition on buy/sell
arrangements.
164. The Commission prohibited buy/
sell arrangements in Order No. 636 and
companion orders in El Paso Natural
Gas Company.155 Order No. 636 stated
that ‘‘[u]nder those arrangements, an
LDC will purchase gas in the production
area from an end-user or a merchant
designated by an end-user. The LDC
will ship the gas on its own firm
capacity and sell the gas to the end-user
at the retail delivery point.’’ 156 The
154 See
e.g., NWIGU comments at 7, PGC
comments at 6, Weyerhaeuser comments at 3–11.
155 59 FERC ¶ 61,031, reh’g denied, 60 FERC ¶
61,117 (1992).
156 Order No. 636 at 30,416. In Order No. 636–B,
61 FERC ¶ 61,272, at 61,997 (1992), the
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
Commission explained that it had
adopted a nationally uniform capacity
release program in order to provide
greater assurance that transfers of
capacity from one shipper to another
were transparent and not unduly
discriminatory. The Commission found
that permitting buy/sell arrangements
would frustrate this goal, because such
arrangements ‘‘would provide a major
loophole, potentially inviting
substantial circumvention of the
capacity release mechanism.’’ 157
165. The Commission grants an
exemption from the buy/sell prohibition
for AMAs that qualify for the
exemptions from bidding and tying, but
only for volumes of gas delivered to the
releasing shipper. In this proceeding,
the Commission is modifying its
regulations and policies in order to
facilitate the development of efficient
and beneficial AMAs. Consistent with
this objective, the Commission will
permit shippers to hire an asset manager
solely for the purpose of managing their
interstate pipeline capacity, while they
continue to purchase their gas supplies
from a different marketer under
contracts which they do not assign to
the asset manager.
166. As the commenters explain, the
marketer having the best terms and
price for asset management services is
not always the marketer who is able to
supply the gas commodity at the lowest
cost. Moreover, such marketers may be
in direct competition with each other,
both in the asset management field and
in the commodity supply area. Such
competition helps the end-user obtain
the lowest possible delivered cost for its
gas supplies. The commenters state,
however, that in such circumstances,
the releasing shipper may prefer not to
assign its gas purchase contracts to the
marketer providing asset management
services for their pipeline capacity
because this would reveal competitively
sensitive information concerning the
commodity prices offered by the other
marketer. Rather, the releasing shipper
could avoid this result by entering into
what is in essence a buy/sell
transaction, in which the releasing
shipper would purchase the gas
commodity from someone other than its
asset manager and sell that gas to the
asset manager.158 The asset manager
would then use the released capacity to
transport the gas to the shipper and
Commission clarified that the buy/sell prohibition
applies to all firm capacity holders, not just LDCs.
See also, In re BP Energy Co., 121 FERC ¶ 61,088,
at P 14 (2007).
157 El Paso, 59 FERC at 61,080.
158 The sale to the asset manager is necessary to
avoid a violation of the shipper-must-have title
requirement.
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37085
resell the gas to the shipper at the
delivery point.
167. The Commission finds that
exempting such transactions from the
buy/sell prohibition is appropriate, in
light of the above-described benefits of
AMAs in which the asset manager only
manages the releasing shipper’s pipeline
capacity. This exemption will not
undercut the Commission’s goal in
adopting the prohibition on buy/sell
arrangements of preventing
circumvention of the capacity release
program. As we have previously
explained, capacity releases to an asset
manager differ from other releases,
because the releasing shipper is not
releasing unneeded capacity, but
capacity that will continue to be used to
serve its own supply function during
the term of the release. The purpose of
the buy/sell transactions at issue here is
to permit the releasing shipper to
negotiate its own gas purchase
arrangements with a third party, while
having its asset manager transport the
gas over the released capacity to the
releasing shipper. Thus, the asset
manager’s purchase from the releasing
shipper and resale to that shipper
enables the released capacity to be used
to meet the releasing shipper’s own gas
requirements and is a condition of the
capacity release. This is unlike the buy/
sell transactions prohibited by Order
No. 636, where the purchases,
transportation, and re-sales were for the
purpose of meeting the gas requirements
of a third party, and there was no
capacity release to any participant in the
transactions. While, here, the asset
manager would be buying gas from, and
reselling it to, the releasing shipper, the
capacity release to the asset manager
would be done in accordance with the
Commission’s capacity release
regulations and as such, would be
transparent to the market. The parties
would need to comply with all the
notice and posting provisions currently
in place. Further, the Commission has
found that AMAs are beneficial to the
secondary gas markets. By providing a
limited exemption from the buy/sell
prohibition for AMAs, the Commission
is further facilitating the flexibility of
AMAs and promoting enhanced
competition in the capacity release
market.
168. The Commission also clarifies, as
requested by several commenters, that
an AMA does not necessarily need to
involve an assignment of gas supply
contracts.159 Those commenters suggest
159 Commenters supportive of this general view
include the AGA, BGEM, Direct Energy, NWIGU,
Nstar, PPM, PGC, Sequent and Weyerhaeuser.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37086
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
descriptions and risk allocations.161
NJNG likewise seeks clarification that
the tying exemption for AMAs applies
to all aspects of an AMA, including
financial risk management products and
services, nominations and scheduling
services, asset optimization fees and
profit sharing arrangements and other
products and services reasonably related
to an AMA.
171. The Commission clarifies that its
definition of AMAs is not meant to
preclude the parties from negotiating
the terms and conditions of other
agreements necessary to implement
AMAs, provided the elements of the
AMA definition are satisfied. It is the
Commission’s intention in this rule to
facilitate innovative and efficient
AMAs. The Commission recognizes that
in order to successfully implement an
AMA, the parties will need to negotiate
and agree upon certain other practical
elements of the transaction aside from
the release terms and delivery aspects of
the deal. Those items may include
communication protocols, risk
management arrangements, nominations
and scheduling services, asset
optimization fees and profit sharing
arrangements and other products and
services reasonably related to an AMA.
It would be counterproductive to the
Commission’s goal of facilitating AMAs
to disallow parties to tie these other
necessary aspects of AMAs to the deal.
Thus, the Commission clarifies that if
the arrangement meets the essential
elements of the definition of AMAs,
then the tying exemption applies to all
other agreements necessary to
implement the AMA. The Commission
also clarifies that payments made by or
to an asset manager under an AMA that
are separate and apart from the cost of
the released capacity do not violate the
prohibition against tying.
7. Other AMA Terms and Conditions
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
that while an AMA may involve an
assignment of gas supply agreements, an
AMA should not be so limited because
the asset manager may have different
supply sources from which to draw. For
example, the releasing shipper may
enter into a supply agreement directly
with the asset manager, or the asset
manager itself may be responsible for
acquiring supply for delivery to the
releasing shipper. Some commenters
seek clarification that an end use
customer need not assign actual gas
supply contracts under which it takes
service to an asset manager but that it
may avail itself of ‘‘any lawful
mechanism for transferring title to gas
supply.’’ 160
169. The Commission notes that the
definition for AMAs approved in this
rule does not include a requirement that
the releasing shipper assign gas supply
contracts. As discussed above, the
releasing shipper may want to negotiate
its own gas supply contracts.
Alternatively, the releasing shipper may
not currently have any of its gas supply
contracts to assign, but is hiring an asset
manager in part for the purpose of
having the asset manager negotiate and
enter into gas supply contracts for the
purpose of supplying the releasing
shippers’ gas supply needs. Consistent
with the Commission’s desire to give the
parties the flexibility to negotiate the
most efficient AMA arrangements to fit
their needs, the definition of AMArelated releases adopted in this rule
only requires that the replacement
shipper enter into a contractual
commitment to make the requisite
delivery of gas supplies to the releasing
shipper. The mechanism by which the
replacement shipper will obtain those
supplies is left to the parties to
negotiate.
8. Posting and Reporting Requirements
172. In the NOPR, the Commission
stated that, while it proposed to exempt
capacity releases implementing AMAs
from bidding, such releases would
remain subject to all existing posting
and reporting requirements.
Accordingly, the Commission stated,
pipelines would still be obligated to
provide notice of the release pursuant to
18 CFR section 284.8(d). In addition, the
details of the release transaction would
have to be posted on the pipeline’s
Internet web site under 18 CFR section
284.13(b)(1)(viii), which requires the
posting of ‘‘special terms and conditions
applicable to a capacity release
transaction.’’ The Commission also
stated that sections 284.13(c)(2)(viii)
170. Several commenters request that
the Commission clarify that parties are
free to negotiate all relevant terms and
conditions of an AMA, and the
Commission does not intend to preclude
parties from including in their AMA
agreements terms and conditions
relating to matters beyond the asset
manager’s delivery obligation to the
releasing shipper. For example, Sequent
comments that the definition of AMA
should not preclude parties from
negotiating terms and conditions in
addition to capacity release and
delivery/receipt requirements, such as
form of service and other related
agreements, compensation, operating
and communication protocols, asset
160 Weyerhaeuser
VerDate Aug<31>2005
comments at 2–5.
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
161 Sequent
PO 00000
comments at 8–9.
Frm 00030
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
and (ix) require that the pipeline’s index
of customers include the name of any
agent or asset manager managing a
shipper’s transportation service and
whether that agent or asset manager is
an affiliate of the releasing shipper.
173. Several parties filed comments
regarding the posting and reporting
requirements for AMAs.162 While most
support the Commission’s goals of
transparency and disclosure, they seek
clarification as to what exactly must be
posted. Essentially these comments
request clarification that commercially
sensitive details of an AMA, such as the
structure, assets available for use by the
asset manager, and the compensation to
be paid, do not need to be posted as
‘‘special terms and conditions’’ of the
release pursuant to section
284.13(b)(1)(viii). They assert that only
the fact that the release is an AMA
needs to be disclosed. FPL requests that
the Commission specifically define the
facts that must be reported for there to
be a valid AMA. Hess makes a similar
request, and emphasizes that releasing
shippers should not be required to post
an RFP or any other details of the AMA
because they are proprietary,
confidential and commercially
sensitive. Hess also requests the
Commission confirm that it is not
expanding the details that it expects to
be disclosed as special terms and
conditions. Hess and Integrys assert that
posting and reporting on AMAs should
be limited to the fact that the release is
part of an AMA and describing the
terms and conditions of the release
associated with the AMA.163 NGSA also
requests clarification that the posting of
a capacity release in the context of an
AMA should require only the
information normally posted for a
typical release of capacity (receipt and
delivery points, term), along with a
statement that acknowledges that it is
part of an AMA.
174. In response to these comments,
the Commission clarifies in this rule the
posting and reporting requirements that
will be applicable to release transactions
implementing AMAs. By stating in the
NOPR that existing section
284.13(b)(1)(viii) requires that any
‘‘special terms and conditions’’ of such
releases must be posted, the
Commission did not intend to require
that commercially sensitive details of an
AMA be disclosed, particularly
information concerning the gas
commodity aspects of the AMA.164 The
162 See e.g., Comments of AGA; Comments of
FPL, Comments of Hess; Comments of Integrys, and
NGSA comments.
163 Integrys comments at 6–7.
164 The Commission retains the right, however, to
require a releasing shipper to make all relevant
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
Commission recognizes that in order to
promote competition certain details of
the AMA are commercially sensitive
and thus should remain confidential.
175. However, the Commission finds
that any posting under section 284.13(b)
that relates to a release to implement an
AMA should include (1) the fact that the
release is to an asset manager and (2) the
delivery or purchase obligation of the
AMA, in addition to the information
required to be posted for all capacity
releases. As discussed in detail above,
the requirement that the asset manager
deliver or purchase gas to fulfill the
releasing shipper’s supply or marketing
obligations is the cornerstone for
differentiating AMAs from standard
capacity releases. In order to ensure that
capacity releases posited as AMAs
eligible for the exemptions from tying
and bidding are bona fide AMAs, the
Commission must have a means to
monitor this critical component of the
arrangement. Other information
specifically related to the AMA,
however, such as the pricing of any
sales of gas commodity and any profit
sharing arrangements between the
releasing and replacement shipper need
not be posted pursuant to section
284.13(b). Consistent with this
discussion, the Commission is revising
section 284.13(b)(1) of its regulations to
add a new subsection (x) specifying the
information concerning an AMA that
must be included in the posting of any
capacity release meant to implement an
AMA. The required posting concerning
the delivery or purchase obligation that
qualifies the release as an AMA under
the definition discussed above should
specify the volumetric level of the
replacement shipper’s delivery or
purchase obligation and the time
periods during which that obligation is
in effect.
176. INGAA and other pipeline
commenters state that as pipelines
already have a substantial role in
administering the Commission’s
capacity release program, pipelines
should not be overburdened by the
proposed changes nor should they be
responsible for policing asset managers’
compliance therewith. They assert that
pipelines’ obligations should be limited
to posting offers submitted by releasing
shippers using the terms and conditions
provided to the pipeline.165
177. The Commission hereby clarifies
in this rule that pipelines are
responsible for posting offers submitted
agreements and supporting documents available to
the Commission for review if questions arise as to
whether a purported AMA satisfies the
Commission’s regulations.
165 INGAA comments at 21; Spectra comments at
29.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
by releasing shippers that are meant to
implement AMAs using the terms and
conditions provided by the releasing
shipper to the pipeline. It is incumbent
upon the releasing shipper to include
the details discussed above to qualify
the release as an AMA. The Commission
further clarifies that the pipeline has no
obligation to act on any information
other than is provided to it by its
customers. The pipeline must of course,
comply with all applicable elements of
section 284.13 of the Commission’s
regulations.
9. Part 157
Capacity
178. Several commentors 166 urge the
Commission to permit Part 157
individually certificated transportation
and storage agreements to be used in the
AMA context.167 The Commission’s Part
284 regulations, including the
provisions for flexible receipt points
and capacity release, do not apply to
Part 157 services. This is because
pipelines perform Part 157 services
pursuant to an individual certificate
rather than a Part 284 blanket certificate
for open access transportation. Under
Part 157, a pipeline negotiates a service
with a particular shipper, including the
terms and conditions of service. Such an
agreement generally would only provide
for service between specified receipt
and delivery points. Subsequently, the
pipeline would apply to the
Commission under NGA section 7 for a
certificate to perform this individual
service.
179. NJNG states that the Commission
should permit a capacity holder desiring
to enter into an AMA ‘‘to release Part
157, as well as Part 284, capacity to the
asset manager.’’ However, it qualifies its
request to explain that while it believes
that a release of Part 157 capacity
should be permitted in this context, it
does not request all the flexibility of
Part 284 capacity. NJNG states that a
limited expansion of flexibility afforded
to Part 157 transactions will facilitate
the asset manager’s ability to optimize
the customer’s portfolio of
transactions.168 NGNJ also suggests that
inclusion of Part 157 service in AMAs
could be achieved ‘‘either by making
Part 157 services releasable for this
limited purpose, or it could be
effectuated by affording the asset
166 See e.g., comments of AGA, National Grid,
NJNG, Nstar, and PPM.
167 Individually-certificated service agreements
are transportation and storage services that have
been certificated pursuant to Part 157 of the
Commission’s regulations and under the authority
of Section 7(c) of the NGA. See 18 CFR 157 Subpart
A (2007).
168 NJNG comments at 3.
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37087
manager a waiver of the Shipper Must
Have Title requirement * * *.’’ 169
180. National Grid also requests that
the Commission clarify that ‘‘as part of
an AMA, a shipper can include all of its
pipeline contracts, including
individually certificated Part 157
contracts and upstream sales agreements
without violating any otherwise
applicable Commission rules or policies
* * *.’’ 170 AGA recommends that the
Commission allow Part 157 capacity to
be included in the portfolio of assets
that a releasing shipper may assign to an
asset manager, but does not advocate
that Part 157 capacity be permitted to be
released or assigned on a stand-alone
basis.171 PPM and Nstar request that the
Commission permit customers to
include Part 157 service as part of an
AMA. They argue that inclusion of Part
157 capacity in AMAs would further
advance the Commission’s goal of
facilitating AMAs and warrants an
exception from the rules that otherwise
prohibit shippers from releasing their
Part 157 capacity, while exclusion of
Part 157 capacity, would serve as an
obstacle to the maximization of efficient
capacity.
181. On February 15, 2008, Spectra
filed a reply to these comments. Spectra
supports the ability of customers to have
asset managers act as their agents in
managing Part 157 service agreements,
so long as the agreements themselves
are not released or otherwise assigned to
the asset manager and the customer and
asset manager follow all other
Commission policies and regulations
related to Part 157 service. Spectra
opposes requests that the Commission
allow Part 157 service to be released or,
in any way, be treated in the same
manner as Part 284 services and states
that such suggestions are inconsistent
with Commission policy and are outside
the scope of the NOPR.
182. On March 3, 2008, Nstar filed a
response to Spectra and clarifies that
commentors requesting this treatment
for Part 157 capacity are not arguing for
flexibility equal to that the Commission
provides shippers under Part 284
service. Rather, they simply urge the
Commission to clarify that Part 157
rights may be among the assets
conveyed under an AMA, and that they
seek no additional Part 284 service
flexibilities. Nstar argues that the
Commission should not require
shippers to convert Part 157 service to
Part 284 service as a condition of
subjecting such capacity to an AMA.
Nstar argues that such conversion
169 Id.
170 National
171 AGA
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
Grid comments at 5.
comments at 22.
30JNR2
37088
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
would be costly and the added
flexibilities would not warrant the cost
of conversion as they are unnecessary.
183. The Commission did not propose
in the NOPR to require pipelines to
allow shippers to transfer their Part 157
service agreements to an AMA, because
the essence of an AMA, as defined by
Commission, is a pre-arranged capacity
release, pursuant to the Part 284
regulations, from the holder of the
capacity to the asset manager. The
Commission’s policies regarding the
release of Part 157 capacity are well set:
In Order No. 636–A, the Commission
determined that holders of individually
certificated transportation under section 7(c)
of the Natural Gas Act and Part 157 of the
Commission’s regulations (Part 157
shippers), i.e. not Part 284 shippers, are not
eligible to release capacity under section
284.243 since they are not governed by Part
284 or affected by the provisions of Order No.
636 that amended the Part 284 regulations.172
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
184. In its Order No. 636 proceeding,
the Commission recognized that
shippers under Part 157 service would
not have the same rights and flexibility
as Part 284 shippers such as flexible
receipt and delivery points and the right
to release their capacity to another
shipper. However, the Commission
stated that shippers with Part 157
service could convert their Part 157
service to Part 284 service if they
wanted to release capacity or use
flexible receipt and delivery points.173
Further, in Order No. 636–B, the
Commission recognized that while its
open access program under Part 284
granted shippers benefits not enjoyed by
Part 157 shippers, it also imposed
obligations upon Part 284 shippers that
were not imposed on Part 157 shippers,
such as requiring non-discriminatory
access for all shippers under Part 284
while Part 157 arrangements may
include unique terms and conditions.174
The Commission also pointed out that,
because the Part 284 capacity releasing
program permits releases at discounted
rates but Part 157 capacity cannot be
discounted, Part 157 shippers cannot
simply be included in the Part 284
capacity release program.175
172 Order No. 636–B, 61 FERC ¶ 61,272 at 61,992
(1992), citing, Order No. 636–A at 30,569.
173 Order No. 636–A at 30,569. Moreover, in
Order No. 636–B, the Commission stated:
Although the Commission is denying the requests
for rehearing, the Commission reemphasizes that it
finds conversions from individually certificated
transportation to open access transportation to be in
the public interest. The Commission anticipates
that pipelines and their customers will be able to
reach agreement on proposals for implementing
such conversions and encourages them to do so. Id.
at 61,994. (footnote omitted)
174 Order No. 636–B at 61,992.
175 Order No. 636–B at 61,993.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
185. For the reasons stated above, the
Commission is not persuaded to revise
its longstanding policy of not permitting
Part 157 shippers to participate in the
capacity release program without
converting their services to service
under Part 284 blanket authority.
Further, to the extent that Nstar argues
that the commentors do not seek
capacity release rights such as those
enjoyed by Part 284 shippers but, rather
the ability to assign a Part 157
individually certificated service
agreement to its asset manager, such a
request entails a change of the contract
between the pipeline and the shipper.
That is because such a modification
would replace the existing shipper
under a contract individually
certificated by the Commission with
another shipper. If the contract does not
include a provision permitting such an
assignment, the Commission could only
require the pipeline to permit the
assignment by acting under NGA
section 5. The Commission finds that
such modifications to individually
certificated agreements should be
addressed on a case by case basis, rather
than in this rulemaking proceeding.
V. Tying of Storage Capacity and
Inventory
186. In its decision in Texas Eastern
Transmission, LP,176 the Commission
found that a proposed tariff provision
stating that ‘‘[i]f the Releasing Customer
proposes or requires a transfer of all or
a portion of its Storage Inventory in
conjunction with its release of storage
capacity rights, it shall so specify in its
offer to release capacity’’ constituted a
broad authorization for shippers on
Texas Eastern’s system to tie their
release of storage capacity to an
extraneous condition (i.e. the taking of
gas inventory) in all situations. The
Commission held that this proposed
tariff provision violated the
Commission’s current prohibition
against tying a release of its capacity to
any extraneous conditions. The
Commission thus required Texas
Eastern to delete the proposed language.
187. Subsequent to the Texas Eastern
decision, the Commission in the NOPR
requested comment on whether it
should clarify its prohibition concerning
tying agreements outside of the AMA
context to allow a releasing shipper to
176 Texas Eastern Transmission LP, 120 FERC
¶ 61,199, order on compliance filing, 121 FERC
¶ 61,026 (2007), reh’g denied without prejudice, 122
FERC 61,014 (2008) (Texas Eastern). The
Commission stated in its rehearing order that the
issues raised in the requests for clarification and/
or rehearing in the Texas Eastern case were general
policy issues that would be more appropriately
addressed in this rulemaking proceeding.
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
include conditions in a storage release
concerning the sale and/or repurchase
of gas in storage inventory.177 All
commenters that addressed this issue
supported removing the tying
prohibition for storage services to allow
a shipper that releases storage capacity
to condition a release of storage capacity
on the sale and/or repurchase of gas in
storage inventory. They want to be able
to require that a replacement shipper
take title to any gas that remains in the
storage at the time the release takes
effect and/or to require the releasing
shipper to return the storage capacity to
the releasing shipper at the end of the
release with a specified amount of gas
in storage.178 Commenters supporting
this change argue that there is nothing
extraneous about a releasing shipper
addressing gas in storage at the time it
releases storage capacity, and thus the
requisite ‘‘tying’’ should be permitted.
188. Commenters note that tying
storage capacity with storage inventory
will allow the releasing shipper greater
ease in releasing capacity and will
enable transactions to be consummated
more readily.179 Further, because
releasing shippers may want to release
storage capacity in the summer when
they do not need it, they need to get the
capacity back with gas in storage or
there will not be enough time to re-fill
it for the winter season.
189. Commenters also assert that the
nature of the relationship between
storage capacity and storage inventory
calls out for a waiver of the tying rule.
They add that the ability of releasing
shippers to ‘‘tie’’ storage capacity with
storage inventory such that releasing
shippers would be permitted to require
that replacement shippers take
inventory as a condition of release, even
outside the AMA context, will provide
benefits to the marketplace similar to
those provided by AMA.180 Finally, the
NYPSC asserts that the AMA exemption
from tying prohibition should be
extended to releases of storage capacity
performed pursuant to state retail access
programs.
190. Based on the substantial support
expressed in the comments, the
Commission is clarifying in this rule its
prohibition on tying to allow a releasing
shipper to include conditions in a
release concerning the sale and/or
repurchase of gas in storage inventory
even outside the AMA context.
Specifically, this exception to the tying
177 NOPR
at P 82.
e.g. Comments of the AGA, Duke Energy,
Florida Cities, INGAA, the NGSA, Piedmont,
National Grid, NYSEG and RG&E.
179 See e.g. Comments of Piedmont at 7.
180 Comments of Marketer Petitioners at 15–16.
178 See
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
rule is meant to allow a shipper that
releases storage capacity to require the
replacement shipper to (1) take title to
any gas in the released storage capacity
at the time the release takes effect and/
or (2) return the storage capacity to the
releasing shipper at the end of the
release with a specified amount of gas
in storage. The Commission is
persuaded in the storage context, storage
capacity is inextricably attached to the
gas in storage. By allowing releasing
shippers to condition the release of
storage capacity on sale and or
repurchase of gas in storage inventory
and on there being a certain amount of
gas left in storage at the end of the
release, the Commission will enhance
the efficient use of storage capacity
while at the same time ensuring that the
releasing shipper will have gas in
storage for the winter. The Commission
also agrees that allowing the tying of
storage capacity to storage inventory
will provide benefits to the market by
enabling more active release of storage
capacity into the wholesale market.
VI. Liquefied Natural Gas
191. Statoil seeks clarification that
akin to the exemption for AMAs that
would allow the tying of released
capacity to gas sales agreements, it
would be permissible to link throughput
agreements and/or sales of gas at the
outlet of an NGA Section 3 liquefied
natural gas (LNG) terminal with a
prearranged capacity release on an
interstate pipeline connected to the
terminal. Statoil comments that LNG
importers often hold firm capacity on
interstate pipelines adjacent to the
terminals to ensure that re-gasified LNG
can exit the terminal efficiently and be
transported to the markets on the
interstate pipeline grid. Noting that
while the contracts governing the use of
NGA section 3 capacity are not subject
to the Commission’s open access or
capacity release policies, and that the
terms of agreements for the sale of LNG
are not governed by the Commission,
the NGA section 7 pipelines that
connect the terminals to the interstate
grid are subject to those regulations.
Accordingly, Statoil suggests that the
Commission should recognize and
permit the natural link between an LNG
terminal throughput agreement and an
agreement to release downstream
pipeline capacity and clarify that such
a tie is permissible. Shell LNG filed in
support of Statoil’s comments.181
192. The Commission declines to
grant the requested clarification in this
generic rulemaking proceeding. In this
181 Chevron also filed late supporting comments
on May 27, 2008.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
rule, the Commission is providing an
exemption from bidding and the
prohibition on tying in order to permit
gas sellers to use supply AMAs. Statoil
and other LNG importers holding firm
capacity on interstate pipelines
connected to an LNG terminal can use
a supply AMA. The comments of Statoil
and other LNG importers do not provide
adequate detail on the types of
transactions for which they seek a tying
exemption to explain why a further
exemption beyond that provided for
supply AMAs is required for LNG
facilities. Likewise, it is unclear from
the comments how far downstream they
seek to have the exemption apply. For
example, while some terminals may
have direct connection to a dedicated
lateral line, others interconnect directly
with a major interstate natural gas
pipeline. Nor do we have a sufficient
record at this time to evaluate the
possible benefits of such an exemption
or the effect on open access competition
that such an exemption might have.
193. While the Commission declines
to grant the clarification in this general
rulemaking proceeding, the Commission
is open to considering this issue on a
case-by-case basis if presented to it in a
fully justified proposal.
VII. State Mandated Retail Unbundling
194. Section 284.8(h)(1) of the
Commission’s current capacity release
regulations exempts prearranged
releases of more than 31 days from
bidding only if they are at the
‘‘maximum tariff rate applicable to the
release.’’ States with retail open access
gas programs (in which customers can
buy gas from marketers rather than
LDCs) have relied on this ‘‘safe harbor’’
exemption from bidding in structuring
their programs. Specifically, a key
component of most such programs is a
provision for the LDC to make periodic
releases, at the maximum rate, of its
interstate pipeline capacity to the
marketers participating in the program.
The marketers then use the released
capacity to transport the gas supplies
that they sell to their retail customers.
The exemption from bidding ensures
that the LDC’s capacity is transferred
only to the marketers participating in
the state retail unbundling program and
is not obtained by non-participating
third parties.
195. However, the Commission’s
removal of the price ceiling for releases
of one year or less in this rule eliminates
the bidding exemption for releases with
terms of between 31 days and one year.
That is because there will no longer be
a maximum tariff rate applicable to such
releases. As a result, absent some
additional modification of the
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37089
regulations concerning bidding, LDCs
will have to post for bidding all releases
of between 31 days and one year that are
made as part of a state retail unbundling
program. This would mean that the
marketers participating in the program
could only obtain the capacity if they
matched any third party bid for the
capacity.
196. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed to address this issue in a
manner generally consistent with its
actions in Order No. 637, when a similar
issue arose with respect to the
experimental lifting of the price ceiling
for short-term capacity releases. In
Order Nos. 637–A and 637–B,182 the
Commission denied the request by LDCs
for a blanket exemption from bidding of
all capacity releases made as part of a
state retail unbundling program. The
Commission explained that, with the
price ceiling removed, posting and
bidding was necessary to protect against
undue discrimination and ensure that
the capacity is properly allocated to the
shipper placing the greatest value on the
capacity. The Commission nevertheless
provided that, if an LDC considered an
exemption from bidding essential to
further a state retail unbundling
program, the LDC could request a
waiver of the bidding regulation to
allow the LDC to consummate prearranged capacity release deals at the
maximum rate, subject to certain
conditions.183
197. In the NOPR, the Commission
similarly proposed to permit LDCs to
request a waiver of the bidding
regulation to allow them to consummate
short-term pre-arranged capacity release
deals necessary to implement retail
access at the maximum rate without
bidding. The Commission stated that
this limited waiver of the bidding
requirement would enable retail access
programs to continue to operate with
the same exemption from bidding which
they now have. While the Commission
did not propose a blanket exemption
from bidding for releases made by LDCs
under state retail choice programs
comparable to the blanket exemption for
AMAs, the Commission requested
182 Order No. 637–A at 31,569; Order No. 637–B,
92 FERC at 61,163.
183 On appeal of Order No. 637, the court in
INGAA affirmed the Commission’s refusal to grant
a blanket waiver of the bidding requirement for
releases made as part of a state retail unbundling
program, finding that the Commission’s concern
about discrimination was reasonable. However, the
court remanded the issue of the reasonableness of
the Commission’s condition that an LDC seeking a
waiver must agree to subject all its releases to the
maximum rate. The Commission did not address
this issue in its order on remand, because the price
ceiling had been re-imposed by the time of the
remand order, thus rendering the issue moot.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
37090
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
comment on whether such releases
should be treated as similar to releases
made as part of an AMA and thus
accorded the same full exemption from
bidding. The Commission recognized
that there are similarities between
releases made pursuant to a state retail
unbundling program and those made as
part of an AMA, but requested comment
on whether a blanket exemption for
state programs would entail greater
potential for undue discrimination.
198. The vast majority of comments
that addressed this issue supported
treating capacity releases under state
retail choice programs the same way as
AMAs, advocating that those capacity
releases be afforded the same blanket
exemptions from capacity release
bidding requirements as those granted
to releases to implement AMAs.184
Commenters assert that releases made
by LDCs for state unbundling programs
closely resemble AMAs in that the
capacity is committed to be used for its
original purpose, to serve the LDC’s
customers. Commenters also note that
the reasons given by the Commission in
the NOPR for the bidding and tying
exemptions for AMAs apply with equal
force to releases to implement state
approved retail access programs. Others
argue that the Commission’s case-bycase exemption analysis creates a
greater potential for discrimination than
a blanket exemption would. As pointed
out by the NYPSC, requiring LDCs
seeking to participate in state approved
unbundling programs will inject a level
of uncertainty into the process as well
as impose additional expensive burdens
on those LDCs. AGA urges the
Commission to permit LDCs to make
exempt releases at the price the LDC
paid for the capacity as opposed to the
applicable maximum tariff rate.185 FPL
Energy provides the Commission with
an alternative suggestion that would
continue to allow a general exemption
from bidding for prearranged releases
where the replacement shipper agrees to
pay the maximum tariff rate.186
199. The Commission finds that
capacity releases by LDCs to implement
state approved retail access programs
should be granted the same blanket
exemptions from the prohibition against
tying and the bidding requirements as
capacity releases made in the AMA
context. As the Commission stated in
Georgia Public Service Commission,187
‘‘state retail unbundling is consistent
with the Commission’s overall goals in
Order No. 636 of improving the
competitive structure of the natural gas
industry by promoting access to the
interstate pipeline transportation grid
and the wellhead market so that willing
buyers and sellers can meet in a
competitive, national market to transact
the most efficient deals possible.
Therefore the Commission does not
wish to discourage state retail
unbundling programs that give retail
end-users a greater choice of suppliers
from whom to purchase their gas.’’ State
retail unbundling programs provide
benefits similar to AMAs.
200. Accordingly, this rule clarifies
that the prohibition against tying does
not apply to releases by an LDC to a
marketer that agrees to sell gas to the
LDC’s retail customers under a state
approved retail access program. The
final rule also amends section 284.8(h)
in order to provide for such an
exemption from bidding. The exemption
from bidding will apply regardless of
the rate at which the LDC makes its
releases to the marketers participating in
the state retail unbundling program. In
order to qualify for the exemption, the
capacity release must be used by the
replacement shipper to provide the gas
supply requirement of retail consumers
pursuant to a retail access program
approved by the state agency with
jurisdiction over the LDC that provides
delivery service to such retail
consumers. The exemption does not
apply to re-releases made by marketers
participating in the retail access
program.
201. In light of our granting this
blanket bidding exemption, the
Commission is also modifying section
284.13(b)(1) of its regulations to add a
requirement that the pipeline’s posting
of a capacity release must state whether
the release is to a marketer participating
in an eligible state retail access program.
184 Those commenters include the AGA,
Boardwalk, BP, Commerce Energy, Direct Energy,
Duke Energy, FPL, Hess, IGS, NJNG, NStar, NYSEG,
RG&E, Ohio OGMG, PG&E, PSCNY, PUCO, SEMI,
Sequent and WDG.
185 AGA comments at 7.
186 FPL Energy comments at 23.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
VIII. Implementation Schedule
202. The regulatory changes in this
rule will become effective as of the
effective date of this rule, at which time
parties may act in accordance with the
revised regulations adopted by this rule.
Pipelines must file within 180 days of
the effective date of this rule to remove
any inconsistent tariff provisions and
can incorporate this filing into any other
tariff filing made by the pipeline within
the 180 day period.
IX. Information Collection Statement
203. The Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) regulations require that
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
OMB approve certain reporting,
recordkeeping, and public disclosure
(collections of information) imposed by
an agency.188 Accordingly, pursuant to
OMB regulations, the Commission is
providing notice of its proposed
information collections to OMB for
review under section 3507(d) of the
Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995.189
204. The Commission identifies the
information provided under Part 284.13
as contained in FERC–549B. As
mentioned above, natural gas pipelines
must also amend their tariffs to remove
inconsistent language and to incorporate
the provisions from this rule into
another tariff filing as covered under
FERC–545 and file with the
Commission.
205. The Commission did not receive
specific comments concerning its
burden estimates and uses the same
estimates here in the Final Rule, as
modified to reflect the addition of what
must be included in the posting of any
capacity release to implement an asset
management agreement or a release
made as part of a state retail access
program and to make the require tariff
filings. The burden estimates for
complying with additional filing
requirements of this rule pursuant to the
procedures in proposed new sections
284.13(b)(1) are set forth below. For the
most part, the burden on respondents to
comply with the existing reporting
requirements in section 284.13 of the
Commission’s regulations will not be
changed by this proposed rule. In 1992
in Order No. 636 the Commission
established a capacity release
mechanism under which shippers could
release firm transportation and storage
capacity on either a short or long term
basis to other shippers wanting to obtain
capacity. This Final Rule modifies
policies and regulations concerning
capacity releases by shippers on
interstate pipelines in order to enhance
the efficiency and effectiveness of the
secondary capacity release market. The
Commission is responding to industry’s
request for greater flexibility in the
capacity release market and to reflect
changes and developments in the
marketplace. On average, we expect the
burden of making the corresponding
changes under this Final Rule to be 35
hours. This estimate is based on the
modification of Web sites to account for
the posting of the delivery and/or
purchase obligation and whether a
release is to a marketer serving as an
asset manager or a shipper who is
187 110
FERC ¶ 61,048 at P 20 (2005).
CFR 1320.11 (2007).
189 44 U.S.C. 3507(d) (2000).
188 5
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
participating in a state unbundling
37091
program, as well as to make the required
tariff changes.
Number of
respondents
Data collection
Number of
responses per
respondent
Hours per
response
Total annual
hours
102
102
1
1
10
25
1,020
2,550
Totals ........................................................................................................
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
FERC–549B .....................................................................................................
FERC–545 .......................................................................................................
102
1
25
3,570
Total Annual Hours for Collection:
3570 hours.
206. Information Collection Costs:
The Commission sought comments on
the cost to comply with these
requirements. No comments were
received. The Commission has projected
the average annualized cost for all
respondents to be $$145,350. This takes
into account IT technical support 5
hours @ $125 an hour, legal review 3
hours @ $250 an hour and
administrative support 22 hours @ $25
an hour.
207. Title: Capacity Information
(FERC–549B), Gas Pipeline Rates: Rate
Change (Non-Formal) (FERC–545).
208. Action: Proposed Information
Collection.
209. OMB Control Nos.: 1902–0169,
1902–0154.
210. The applicant shall not be
penalized for failure to respond to these
collections of information unless the
collections of information display valid
OMB control numbers.
211. Respondents: Business or other
for profit.
212. Frequency of Responses: On
occasion.
213. Necessity of Information: This
Final Rule will permit market based
pricing for short-term capacity releases
and facilitate AMAs by relaxing the
Commission’s prohibition on tying and
its bidding requirements for certain
capacity releases. Elimination of the
price ceiling for short-term capacity
releases will provide more accurate
price signals concerning the market
value of pipeline capacity. Further,
implementation of AMAs will make the
capacity release program more efficient
as releasing shippers can transfer their
capacity to entities with greater
expertise both in purchasing low cost
gas supplies, and in maximizing the
value of the capacity when it is not
needed to meet the releasing shipper’s
gas supply needs. Such arrangements
free up the time, expense and expertise
involved with managing gas supply
arrangements and serve as a means of
relieving the burdens of administering
their capacity or supply needs.
214. Interested persons may obtain
information on the reporting
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
requirements by contacting the
following: Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426 (Attention:
Michael Miller, Office of the Executive
Director, 202–502–8415, fax: 202–273–
0873, e-mail: michael.miller@ferc.gov).
215. For submitting comments
concerning the collection of information
and the associated burden estimate(s)
including suggestions for reducing this
burden, please send your comments to
the contact listed above and to the
Office of Management and Budget,
Room 10202 NEOB, 725 17th Street,
NW., Washington, DC 20503 (Attention:
Desk Officer for the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 202–395–7345,
fax: 202–395–7285).
X. Environmental Analysis
216. The Commission is required to
prepare an Environmental Assessment
or an Environmental Impact Statement
for any action that may have a
significant adverse effect on the human
environment.190 The Commission has
categorically excluded certain actions
from these requirements as not having a
significant effect on the human
environment.191 The actions proposed
to be taken here fall within categorical
exclusions in the Commission’s
regulations for rules that are corrective,
clarifying or procedural, for information
gathering, analysis, and dissemination,
and for sales, exchange, and
transportation of natural gas that
requires no construction of facilities.192
Therefore an environmental review is
unnecessary and has not been prepared
in this rulemaking.
XI. Regulatory Flexibility Act
217. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 (RFA) 193 generally requires a
190 Order No. 486, Regulations Implementing the
National Environmental Policy Act, 52 FR 47,897
(Dec. 17, 1987), FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations
Preambles 1986–1990 ¶ 30,783 (1987).
191 18 CFR 380.4 (2007).
192 See 18 CFR 380.4(a)(2)(ii), 380.4(a)(5) and
380.4(a)(27)(2007).
193 5 U.S.C. 601–612, citing to Section 3 of the
Small Business Act, 15 U.S.C. 623 (2000). Section
3 defines a ‘‘small business concern’’ as a business
which is independently owned and operated and
which is not dominant in its field of operation.
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
description and analysis of the impact
the proposed rule will have on small
entities or a certification that the
proposed rule will not have significant
economic impact on a substantial
number of small entities. The
amendments to our regulations would
apply only to natural gas companies,
most of which are not small businesses.
Under the industry standards used for
purposes of the RFA, a natural gas
pipeline company qualifies as a ‘‘small
entity’’ if it has annual revenues of $6.5
million or less. As we stated in both the
NOPR and in this Final Rule, removal
of the price ceiling will enable releasing
shippers to offer competitively-priced
alternatives to the pipelines’ negotiated
rate offerings. Further, removal of the
ceiling also permits more efficient
utilization of capacity by permitting
prices to rise to market clearing levels,
allowing those entities that place the
highest value on the capacity to obtain
it.
218. The RFA directs agencies to
consider at a minimum four regulatory
alternatives in drafting a rulemaking to
lessen the impact on small entities:
Tiering or establishment of different
compliance or reporting requirements
for small entities; classification,
consolidation, clarification or
simplification of compliance and
reporting requirements; performance
rather than design standards; and
exemptions. In this Final Rule, the
Commission has revised its regulations
to lift the ceiling price from the release
market and provided a different
compliance regime for shippers making
short-term capacity release transactions.
This gives releasing shippers some of
the same flexibility that is currently
enjoyed by jurisdictional pipelines. In
addition, the Commission will exempt
capacity releases made as part of AMAs
from the prohibition of tying and from
the bidding requirements of section
284.8. AMAs provide significant
benefits to many participants in the
natural gas and electric marketplaces
particularly by allowing greater
flexibility for entities to customize
arrangements to meet unique customer
needs. Sellers of natural gas by using the
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
37092
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
benefits of AMAs create a greater
diversity of potential suppliers and
participants in the secondary markets.
AMAs benefits also include better
management of risks to the fuel supply
which in turn allows generators to focus
on the electric market and not to be
consumed with administrative burdens
relating to multiplier suppliers,
overheads and capital requirements for
and the risks associated with marketing
excess gas. In addition, capacity releases
made under state-approved retail access
programs are also exempt from the
prohibition on tying and bidding
requirements of section 284.8 A small
entity that participates in the market
will no longer be constrained by a
ceiling price for its unused capacity.
219. Accordingly, pursuant to section
605(b) of the RFA, the Commission
certifies that the Final Rule would not
have a significant economic impact on
a substantial number of small entities.
XII. Document Availability
220. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through
FERC’s Home Page (https://www.ferc.gov)
and in FERC’s Public Reference Room
during normal business hours (8:30 a.m.
to 5 p.m. Eastern time) at 888 First
Street, NE., Room 2A, Washington, DC
20426.
221. From FERC’s Home Page on the
Internet, this information is available on
eLibrary. The full text of this document
is available on eLibrary in PDF and
Microsoft Word format for viewing,
printing, and/or downloading. To access
this document in eLibrary, type the
docket number excluding the last three
digits of this document in the docket
number field.
222. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the FERC’s Web site during
normal business hours from FERC
Online Support at 202–502–6652 (toll
free at 1–866–208–3676) or e-mail at
ferconlinesupport@ferc.gov, or the
Public Reference Room at (202) 502–
8371, TTY (202) 502–8659. E-mail the
Public Reference Room at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
XIII. Effective Date and Congressional
Notification
223. These regulations are effective
July 30, 2008. The Commission has
determined, with the concurrence of the
Administrator of the Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs of
OMB, that this rule is not a ‘‘major rule’’
as defined in section 351 of the Small
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
Business Regulatory Enforcement
Fairness Act of 1996.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 284
Continental shelf, Natural gas, and
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements.
By the Commission. Commissioner Moeller
dissenting in part with a separate statement
attached.
Kimberly D. Bose,
Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission amends part 284, Chapter I,
Title 18, Code of Federal Regulations, as
follows:
I
PART 284—CERTAIN SALES AND
TRANSPORTATION OF NATURAL GAS
UNDER THE NATURAL GAS POLICY
ACT OF 1978 AND RELATED
AUTHORITIES
1. The authority citation for part 284
continues to read as follows:
I
Authority: 15 U.S.C. 717–717w, 3301–
3432; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352; 43 U.S.C. 1331–
1356.
2. Amend § 284.8 as follows:
a. In paragraph (e), remove the words
‘‘(not over the maximum rate)’’.
I b. Remove paragraph (i).
I c. Add two sentences to the end of
paragraph (b) and revise paragraph (h)
to read as follows:
I
I
§ 284.8 Release of firm capacity on
interstate pipelines.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) * * * The rate charged the
replacement shipper for a release of
capacity for more than one year may not
exceed the applicable maximum rate.
Payments or other consideration
exchanged between the releasing and
replacement shippers in a release to an
asset manager as defined in (h)(3) of this
section are not subject to the maximum
rate. No rate limitation applies to the
release of capacity for a period of one
year or less.
*
*
*
*
*
(h)(1) A release of capacity by a firm
shipper to a replacement shipper for any
period of 31 days or less, a release of
capacity for more than one year at the
maximum tariff rate, a release to an
asset manager as defined in (h)(3) of this
section, or a release to a marketer
participating in a state-regulated retail
access program as defined in (h)(4) of
this section need not comply with the
notification and bidding requirements of
paragraphs (c) through (e) of this
section. Notice of a firm release under
this paragraph must be provided on the
pipeline’s electronic bulletin board as
soon as possible, but not later than the
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
first nomination, after the release
transaction commences.
(2) When a release of capacity for 31
days or less is exempt from bidding
requirements under paragraph (h)(1) of
this section, a firm shipper may not rollover, extend, or in any way continue the
release without complying with the
requirements of paragraphs (c) through
(e) of this section, and may not rerelease to the same replacement shipper
under this paragraph at less than the
maximum tariff rate until 28 days after
the first release period has ended.
(3) A release to an asset manager
exempt from bidding requirements
under paragraph (h)(1) of this section is
any pre-arranged release that contains a
condition that the releasing shipper
may, on any day during a minimum
period of five months out of each
twelve-month period of the release, call
upon the replacement shipper to (i)
deliver to the releasing shipper a
volume of gas up to one-hundred
percent of the daily contract demand of
the released transportation capacity or
(ii) purchase a volume of gas up to the
daily contract demand of the released
transportation capacity. If the capacity
release is for a period less than one year,
the asset manager’s delivery or purchase
obligation described in the previous
sentence must apply for the lesser of
five months or the term of the release.
If the capacity release is a release of
storage capacity, the asset manager’s
delivery or purchase obligation need
only be one-hundred percent of the
daily contract demand under the release
for storage withdrawals or injections, as
applicable.
(4) A release to a marketer
participating in a state-regulated retail
access program exempt from bidding
requirements under paragraph (h)(1) of
this section is any prearranged capacity
release that will be utilized by the
replacement shipper to provide the gas
supply requirement of retail consumers
pursuant to a retail access program
approved by the state agency with
jurisdiction over the local distribution
company that provides delivery service
to such retail consumers.
3. In § 284.13 add paragraphs (b)(1)(x)
and (b)(1)(xi) to read as follows:
I
§ 284.13 Reporting requirements for
interstate pipelines.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) * * *
(1) * * *
(x) Whether a capacity release is a
release to an asset manager as defined
in § 284.8(h)(3) and the asset manager’s
obligation to deliver gas to, or purchase
gas from, the releasing shipper.
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules and Regulations
(xi) Whether a capacity release is a
release to a marketer participating in a
state-regulated retail access program as
defined in § 284.8(h)(4).
Note: The following text will not appear in
the Code of Federal Regulations.
United States of America Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission
Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity
Release Market; Docket No. RM08–1–000
Issued June 19, 2008.
sroberts on PROD1PC70 with RULES
MOELLER, Commissioner dissenting,
in part:
Several commenters with interests in
the importation of liquefied natural gas
(LNG) seek clarification that a
prohibited tying arrangement would not
occur if an LNG importer combines an
LNG throughput agreement (or the sale
of regasified LNG at the outlet of the
terminal) with a prearranged release of
pipeline transportation capacity on the
terminal’s directly connected pipeline.
In the alternative, the parties seek a
limited exception from the
Commission’s tying prohibition.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:28 Jun 27, 2008
Jkt 214001
Today’s final rule declines to grant
either the requested clarification or the
limited tying exception, but instead
provides for adjudication on a case-bycase basis. I cannot support this
determination.
While LNG imports admittedly have
characteristics that are similar to both
natural gas production and storage, LNG
imports have important differences that
merit a somewhat different policy. LNG
cargo owners and terminal operators
may have less flexibility as they enter
into negotiations and supply
arrangements in the global market on
the high seas, and the Commission
should provide the regulatory certainty
to permit the linkage of such agreements
without fear of running afoul of the
tying prohibition. Providing such an
assurance could benefit the public
interest by encouraging increased LNG
supply deliveries and the efficiencies
associated with linking the terminal
capacity and pipeline capacity (since
the commodity would flow
uninterrupted from the terminal to its
directly connected pipeline—although
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
37093
separately contracted arrangements on
other pipeline(s) may be necessary to
deliver the gas to its final destination.)
However, separating these arrangements
risk stranding capacity at the import
terminal or may even result in LNG
suppliers serving more flexible markets
that do not have such regulatory
obstacles. Moreover, due to the limited
nature of the exception being sought, I
would not expect that either domestic
producers or interstate shippers would
be placed at a competitive disadvantage.
The need for LNG imports will
undoubtedly increase in the coming
years and the Commission should take
steps to provide regulatory certainty to
ensure that LNG tankers can reach our
domestic markets without unnecessary
risk. Accordingly, I believe that this
narrow exception is appropriate in light
of the unique position of LNG terminals
in the interstate pipeline system.
Philip D. Moeller,
Commissioner.
[FR Doc. E8–14444 Filed 6–27–08; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
E:\FR\FM\30JNR2.SGM
30JNR2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 73, Number 126 (Monday, June 30, 2008)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 37058-37093]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E8-14444]
[[Page 37057]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Part III
Department of Energy
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
18 CFR Part 284
Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release Market; Final Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 126 / Monday, June 30, 2008 / Rules
and Regulations
[[Page 37058]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 284
[Docket No. RM08-1-000; Order No. 712]
Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release Market
Issued June 19, 2008.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this Final Rule the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
revises its regulations governing interstate natural gas pipelines to
reflect changes in the market for short-term transportation services on
pipelines and to improve the efficiency of the Commission's capacity
release program. The Commission permits market based pricing for short-
term capacity releases and facilitates asset management arrangements by
relaxing the Commission's prohibition on tying and on its bidding
requirements for certain capacity releases. The Commission further
clarifies that its prohibition on tying does not apply to conditions
associated with gas inventory held in storage for releases of firm
storage capacity. Finally, the Commission waives its prohibition on
tying and bidding requirements for capacity releases made as part of
state-approved retail open access programs.
DATES: This rule will become effective July 30, 2008.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
William Murrell, Office of Energy Market Regulation, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
William.Murrell@ferc.gov, (202) 502-8703.
Robert McLean, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
Robert.McLean@ferc.gov. (202) 502-8156.
David Maranville, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington DC 20426,
David.Maranville@ferc.gov, (202) 502-6351.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Order No. 712
Final Rule
Table of Contents
Paragraph
Numbers
I. Background.............................................. 2.
A. The Capacity Release Program........................ 2.
B. The NOPR............................................ 15.
C. Comments............................................ 19.
II. Overview of the Final Rule............................. 24.
III. Price Cap Issues...................................... 30.
A. Removal of Maximum Rate Ceiling for Short-Term 30.
Capacity Releases.....................................
1. Maximum Rate Ceiling Interferes With Efficient 32.
Transactions......................................
2. Assurance of Just and Reasonable Rates.......... 38.
a. Market Conditions Ensure Just and Reasonable 39.
Rates.........................................
b. Recourse Rate Protection.................... 48.
c. Short-Term Customers Are Not Captive........ 50.
d. Non-Cost Factors............................ 51.
e. Oversight................................... 55.
3. Comments........................................ 57.
a. Lack of Competition in Certain Areas........ 58.
b. Benefits From Removing the Price Ceiling.... 63.
c. Promotion of Construction................... 67.
d. Changed Circumstances....................... 68.
e. Exemption From Bidding for Short-Term 72.
Releases at the Maximum Rate..................
B. Removal of Price Ceiling for Long-Term Releases..... 74.
C. Removal of Price Ceiling for Pipeline Short-Term 81.
Transactions..........................................
1. Removal of the Price Ceiling Is Not Justified... 82.
2. Response to Specific Comments................... 87.
a. Evidentiary Record.......................... 87.
b. Infrastructure Incentives................... 90.
c. Competitive Market Structure................ 92.
d. Differences in Flexibility Between Pipeline 95.
Capacity and Released Capacity................
e. Bifurcation of the Markets.................. 103.
IV. Asset Management Arrangements.......................... 109.
A. Background.......................................... 110.
B. Discussion.......................................... 118.
1. Tying........................................... 127.
2. Bidding......................................... 132.
3. Definition of AMAs.............................. 138.
a. NOPR Proposal............................... 138.
b. Comments.................................... 141.
c. Modified Definition......................... 144.
4. Supply AMAs..................................... 148.
5. AMA Profit Sharing Arrangements................. 154.
6. Exemption From Buy/Sell Prohibition............. 163.
7. Other AMA Terms and Conditions.................. 170.
8. Posting and Reporting Requirements.............. 172.
9. Part 157 Capacity............................... 178.
V. Tying of Storage Capacity and Inventory................. 186.
VI. Liquefied Natural Gas.................................. 191.
[[Page 37059]]
VII. State Mandated Retail Unbundling...................... 194.
VIII. Implementation Schedule.............................. 202.
IX. Information Collection Statement....................... 203.
X. Environmental Analysis.................................. 216.
XI. Regulatory Flexibility Act............................. 217.
XII. Document Availability................................. 220.
XIII. Effective Date and Congressional Notification........ 223.
Before Commissioners: Joseph T. Kelliher, Chairman; Suedeen G. Kelly,
Marc Spitzer, Philip D. Moeller, and Jon Wellinghoff.
Order No. 712
Final Rule
Issued June 19, 2008.
1. In this Final Rule, the Commission revises its Part 284
regulations concerning the release of firm capacity by shippers on
interstate natural gas pipelines. First, as proposed in its Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking,\1\ the Commission will remove, on a permanent
basis, the rate ceiling on capacity release transactions of one year or
less. Second, the Commission will modify its regulations to facilitate
the use of asset management arrangements (AMAs), under which a capacity
holder releases some or all of its pipeline capacity to an asset
manager who agrees to either purchase from, or supply the gas needs of,
the capacity holder. Specifically, the Commission will exempt capacity
releases made as part of AMAs from the prohibition on tying and from
the bidding requirements of section 284.8. Third, the Commission
clarifies that its prohibition on tying does not apply to conditions
associated with gas inventory held in storage for releases of firm
storage capacity. Fourth, the Commission will modify its regulations to
facilitate retail open access programs by exempting capacity releases
made under state-approved retail access programs from the prohibition
on tying and from the bidding requirements of section 284.8. This Final
Rule is designed to enhance competition in the secondary capacity
release market and to increase shipper gas supply options. This rule
will become effective 30 days after publication in the Federal
Register.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release Market, 72 FR
65,916, FERC Stats. and Regs. ] 32,625 (November 26, 2007) 121 FERC
] 61,170 (2007) (NOPR).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
I. Background
A. The Capacity Release Program
2. The Commission adopted its capacity release program as part of
the restructuring of natural gas pipelines required by Order No.
636.\2\ In Order No. 636, the Commission sought to foster two primary
goals. The first goal was to ensure that all shippers have meaningful
access to the pipeline transportation grid so that willing buyers and
sellers can meet in a competitive, national market to transact the most
efficient deals possible. The second goal was to ensure consumers have
``access to an adequate supply of gas at a reasonable price.'' \3\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ Pipeline Service Obligations and Revisions to Regulations
Governing Self-Implementing Transportation; and Regulation of
Natural Gas Pipelines After Partial Wellhead Decontrol, Order No.
636, 57 FR 13,267 (April 16, 1992), FERC Stats. and Regs.,
Regulations Preambles January 1991-June 1996 ] 30,939 (April 8,
1992), order on reh'g, Order No. 636-A., 57 FR 36,128 (August 12,
1992), FERC Stats. and Regs., Regulations Preambles January 1991-
June 1996 ] 30,950 (August 3, 1992), order on reh'g, Order No. 636-
B, 57 FR 57,911 (Dec. 8, 1992), 61 FERC ] 61,272 (1992), notice of
denial of reh'g, 62 FERC ] 61,007 (1993); aff'd in part, vacated and
remanded in part, United Dist. Companies v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105 (DC
Cir. 1996), order on remand, Order No. 636-C, 78 FERC ] 61,186
(1997).
\3\ Order No. 636 at 30,393 (citations omitted).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. To accomplish these goals, the Commission sought to maximize the
availability of unbundled firm transportation service to all
participants in the gas commodity market. The linchpin of Order No. 636
was the requirement that pipelines unbundle their transportation and
storage services from their sales service, so that gas purchasers could
obtain the same high quality firm transportation service whether they
purchased from the pipeline or another gas seller. In order to create a
transparent program for the reallocation of interstate pipeline
capacity to complement the unbundled, open access environment created
by Order No. 636, the Commission also adopted a comprehensive capacity
release program to increase the availability of unbundled firm
transportation capacity by permitting firm shippers to release their
capacity to others when they were not using it.\4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ In brief, under the Commission's current capacity release
program, a firm shipper (releasing shipper) sells its capacity by
returning its capacity to the pipeline for reassignment to the buyer
(replacement shipper). The pipeline contracts with, and receives
payment from, the replacement shipper and then issues a credit to
the releasing shipper. The replacement shipper may pay less than the
pipeline's maximum tariff rate, but not more. 18 CFR 284.8(e)
(2007). The results of all releases are posted by the pipeline on
its Internet web site and made available through standardized,
downloadable files.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. The Commission reasoned that the capacity release program would
promote efficient load management by the pipeline and its customers and
would, therefore, result in the efficient use of firm pipeline capacity
throughout the year. It further concluded that, ``because more buyers
will be able to reach more sellers through firm transportation
capacity, capacity reallocation comports with the goal of improving
nondiscriminatory, open access transportation to maximize the benefits
of the decontrol of natural gas at the wellhead and in the field.'' \5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ Order No. 636 at 30,418.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. In Order No. 636, the Commission expressed concerns regarding
its ability to ensure that firm shippers would reallocate their
capacity in a non-discriminatory manner to those who placed the highest
value on the capacity up to the maximum rate. The Commission noted that
prior to Order No. 636, it authorized some pipelines to permit their
shippers to ``broker'' their capacity to others. Under such capacity
brokering, firm shippers were permitted to assign their capacity
directly to a replacement shipper, without any requirement that the
brokering shipper post the availability of its capacity or allocate it
to the highest bidder.\6\ However, in Order No. 636, the Commission
found ``there [were] too many potential assignors of capacity and too
many different programs for the Commission to oversee capacity
brokering.'' \7\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ See Algonquin Gas Transmission Corp., 59 FERC ] 61,032
(1992).
\7\ Order No. 636 at 30,416.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 37060]]
6. The Commission sought to ensure that the efficiencies of the
secondary market were not frustrated by unduly discriminatory access to
the market.\8\ Therefore, the Commission replaced capacity brokering
with the capacity release program designed to provide greater assurance
that transfers of capacity from one shipper to another were transparent
and not unduly discriminatory. This assurance took the form of several
conditions that the Commission placed on the transfer of capacity under
its new program.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ Order No. 636-A at 30,554.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
7. First, the Commission prohibited private transfers of capacity
between shippers and, instead, required that all release transactions
be conducted through the pipeline. Therefore, when a releasing shipper
releases its capacity, the replacement shipper must enter into a
contract directly with the pipeline, and the pipeline must post
information regarding the contract, including any special
conditions.\9\ In order to enforce theprohibition on private transfers
of capacity, the Commission required that a shipper must have title to
any gas that it ships on the pipeline.\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ Order No. 636 emphasized:
The main difference between capacity brokering as it now exists
and the new capacity release program is that under capacity
brokering, the brokering customer could enter into and execute its
own deals without involving the pipeline. Under capacity releasing,
all offers must be put on the pipeline's electronic bulletin board
and contracting is done directly with the pipeline. Order No. 636 at
30,420 (emphasis in original).
\10\ As the Commission subsequently explained in Order No. 637,
``the capacity release rules were designed with [the shipper-must-
have-title] policy as their foundation,'' because, without this
requirement, ``capacity holders could simply transport gas over the
pipeline for another entity.'' Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services and Regulation of Interstate Natural Gas
Transportation Services, Order No. 637, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,091
at 31,300, clarified, Order No. 637-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,099,
reh'g denied, Order No. 637-B, 92 FERC ] 61,062 (2000), aff'd in
part and remanded in part sub nom. Interstate Natural Gas Ass'n of
America v. FERC, 285 F.3d 18 (DC Cir. 2002), order on remand, 101
FERC ] 61,127 (2002), order on reh'g, 106 FERC ] 61,088 (2004),
aff'd sub nom. American Gas Ass'n v. FERC, 428 F.3d 255 (DC Cir.
2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
8. Second, the Commission determined that the record of the
proceeding that led to Order No. 636 did not reflect that the market
for released capacity was competitive. The Commission reasoned that the
extent of competition in the secondary market may not be sufficient to
ensure that the rates for released capacity will be just and
reasonable. Therefore, the Commission imposed a ceiling on the rate
that the releasing shipper could charge for the released capacity.\11\
This ceiling was derived from the Commission-approved monthly maximum
tariff rates, necessary for the pipeline to recover its annual cost-of-
service revenue requirement.\12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ Order No. 636-A at 30,560.
\12\ Order No. 637 at 31,270-71.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
9. Third, the Commission required that capacity offered for release
at less than the maximum rate must be posted for bidding, and the
pipeline must allocate the capacity ``to the person offering the
highest rate (not over the maximum rate).'' \13\ The Commission
permitted the releasing shipper to choose a pre-arranged replacement
shipper who can retain the capacity by matching the highest bid rate.
The bidding requirement, however, does not apply to releases of 31 days
or less or to any release at the maximum rate. But all releases,
whether or not subject to bidding, must be posted.\14\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ 18 CFR 284.8(e) (2007) provides in pertinent part that
``[t]he pipeline must allocate released capacity to the person
offering the highest rate (not over the maximum rate) and offering
to meet any other terms or conditions of the release.''
\14\ 18 CFR 284.8(h)(1) provides that a release of capacity for
less than 31 days, or for any term at the maximum rate, need not
comply with certain notification and bidding requirements, but that
such release may not exceed the maximum rate. Notice of the release
``must be provided on the pipeline's electronic bulletin board as
soon as possible, but not later than forty-eight hours, after the
release transaction commences.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
10. Finally, the Commission prohibited tying the release of
capacity to any extraneous conditions so that the releasing shippers
could not attempt to add additional terms or conditions to the release
of capacity. The Commission articulated the prohibition against the
tying of capacity in Order No. 636-A, where it stated:
The Commission reiterates that all terms and conditions for
capacity release must be posted and non-discriminatory and must
relate solely to the details of acquiring transportation on the
interstate pipelines. Release of capacity cannot be tied to any
other conditions. Moreover, the Commission will not tolerate deals
undertaken to avoid the notice requirements of the regulations.
Order No. 636-A at 30,559 (emphasis in the original).
11. Subsequent to the Commission's adoption of its capacity release
program in Order No. 636, the Commission conducted two experimental
programs to provide more flexibility in the capacity release market. In
1996, the Commission sought to establish an experimental program
inviting individual shipper and pipeline applications to remove price
ceilings related to capacity release.\15\ The Commission recognized
that significant benefits could be realized through removal of the
price ceiling in a competitive secondary market. Removal of the ceiling
permits more efficient capacity utilization by permitting prices to
rise to market clearing levels and by permitting those who place the
highest value on the capacity to obtain it.\16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ Secondary Market Transactions on Interstate Natural Gas
Pipelines, Proposed Experimental Pilot Program to Relax the Price
Cap for Secondary Market Transactions, 61 FR 41,401 (Aug. 8, 1996),
76 FERC ] 61,120, order on reh'g, 77 FERC ] 61,183 (1996).
\16\ 77 FERC ] 61,183 at 61,699 (1996).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. In 2000, in Order No. 637, the Commission conducted a broader
experiment in which the Commission removed the rate ceiling for short-
term (less than one year) capacity release transactions for a two-year
period ending September 30, 2002. In contrast to the experiment that it
conducted in 1996, in the Order No. 637 experiment the Commission
granted blanket authorization in order to permit all firm shippers on
all open access pipelines to participate. The Commission stated that it
undertook this experiment to improve shipper options and market
efficiency during peak periods. The Commission reasoned that during
peak periods, the maximum rate cap on capacity release transactions
inhibits the creation of an effective transportation market by
preventing capacity from going to those that value it the most and
therefore the elimination of this rate ceiling would eliminate this
inefficiency and enhance shipper options in the short-term
marketplace.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ Order No. 637 at 31,263. The Commission also explained why
it was lifting the price cap on an experimental basis, instead of
permanently, stating:
While the removal of the price cap is justified based on the
record in this rulemaking, the Commission recognizes that this is a
significant regulatory change that should be subject to ongoing
review by the Commission and the industry. No matter how good the
data suggesting that a regulatory change should be made, there is no
substitute for reviewing the actual results of a regulatory action.
The two year waiver will provide an opportunity for such a review
after sufficient information is obtained to validly assess the
results. Due to the variation between years in winter temperatures,
the waiver will provide the Commission and the industry with two
winter's worth of data with which to examine the effects of this
policy change and determine whether changes or modifications may be
needed prior to the expiration of the waiver. Order No. 637 at
31,279-80.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
13. Upon an examination of pricing data on basis differentials
between points,\18\ the Commission found that the price ceiling on
capacity release transactions limited the capacity options of short-
term shippers because firm capacity holders were able to avoid
[[Page 37061]]
price ceilings on released capacity by substituting bundled sales
transactions at market prices (where the market place value of
transportation is an implicit component of the delivered price). As a
consequence, the Commission determined that the price ceilings did not
limit the prices paid by shippers in the short-term market as much as
the ceilings limit transportation options for shippers. In short, the
Commission found that the rate ceiling worked against the interests of
short-term shippers, because with the rate ceilings in place, a shipper
looking for short-term capacity on a peak day who was willing to offer
a higher price in order to obtain it, could not legally do so; this
reduced its options for procuring short-term transportation at the
times that it needed it most.\19\ Throughout this experiment, the
Commission retained the rate ceiling for firm and interruptible
capacity available from the pipeline as well as for long-term capacity
release transactions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Among other things, the data showed that the value of
pipeline capacity, as shown by basis differentials, was generally
less than the pipelines' maximum interruptible transportation rates,
except during the coldest days of the year, and capacity release
prices also averaged somewhat less than pipelines' maximum
interruptible rates.
\19\ Order No. 637 at 31,280-81.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
14. On April 5, 2002, the United States Court of Appeals for the
District of Columbia Circuit, in Interstate Natural Gas Association of
America v. FERC,\20\ upheld the Commission's experimental price ceiling
program for short-term capacity release transactions as set forth in
Order No. 637.\21\ The court found that the Commission's ``light
handed'' approach to the regulation of capacity release prices was,
given the safeguards that the Commission had imposed, consistent with
the criteria set forth in Farmers Union Cent. Exch. v. FERC.\22\ The
court found that the Commission made a substantial record for the
proposition that market rates would not materially exceed the ``zone of
reasonableness'' required by Farmers Union. The court also found that
the Commission's inference of competition in the capacity release
market was well founded, that the price spikes shown in the
Commission's data were consistent with competition and reflected
scarcity of supply rather than monopoly power, and that outside of such
price spikes, the rates were well below the estimated regulated
price.\23\ The Commission's experiment in lifting the price ceiling for
short term capacity releases ended on September 20, 2002.\24\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ 285 F.3d 18 (DC Cir. 2002) (INGAA).
\21\ Specifically, the court found that: ``[g]iven the
substantial showing that in this context competition has every
reasonable prospect of preventing seriously monopolistic pricing,
together with the non-cost advantages cited by the Commission and
the experimental nature of this particular ``light handed''
regulation, we find the Commission's decision neither a violation of
the NGA, nor arbitrary or capricious.'' INGAA at 35.
\22\ 734 F.2d 1486 (DC Cir. 1984) (Farmers Union) (finding that
a move from heavy-handed to light-handed regulation can be justified
by a showing that under current circumstances, the goals and
purposes of the Natural Gas Act (NGA) will be accomplished through
substantially less regulatory oversight.
\23\ Id. at 33.
\24\ Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas Transportation
Services and Regulation of Interstate Natural Gas Transportation
Services, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles July 1996-
December 2000, ] 31,091 (Feb. 9, 2000), order on rehearing, Order
No. 637-A, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles July 1996-
December 2000, ] 31,099 (May 19, 2000), order on rehearing, Order
No. 637-B, 92 FERC ] 61,062 (July 26, 2000), aff'd in part and
remanded in part, Interstate Natural Gas Association of America v.
FERC, 285 F.3d 18 (DC Cir. Apr. 5, 2002).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. The NOPR
15. On January 3, 2007, the Commission, in response to petitions
from various gas industry participants concerning issues related to
capacity releases,\25\ issued a request for comments on the operation
of the capacity release program and whether changes in any of its
capacity release policies would improve the efficiency of the natural
gas market.\26\ The Commission also included in its request for
comments a series of questions asking whether the Commission should
lift the price ceiling, remove its capacity release bidding
requirements, modify its prohibition on tying arrangements, and/or
remove the shipper-must-have-title requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\25\ In August 2006, Pacific Gas and Electric Co. (PG&E) and
Southwest Gas Corp. (Southwest) filed a petition requesting the
Commission to amend sections 284.8(e) and (h)(1) of its regulations
to remove the maximum rate cap on capacity releases. Subsequently,
in October 2006, a group of large natural gas marketers (Marketer
Petitioners) requested clarification of the operation of the
Commission's capacity release rules in the context of asset (or
portfolio) management services.
\26\ Pacific Gas & Electric Co., 118 FERC ] 61,005 (2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
16. After review of the petitions, comments, responses to its
questions, and available data, the Commission issued a Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR), proposing two major changes to its capacity
release regulations and policies. First, the Commission proposed to
lift the price ceiling for short-term capacity release transactions of
one year or less. The Commission determined that the traditional cost-
of-service price ceilings in pipeline tariffs, which are based on
annual costs recovered over twelve equal monthly payments, are not well
suited to the short-term capacity release market, because they do not
reflect short-term variations in the market value of the capacity.
Therefore, removing the price ceiling for short-term capacity releases
would permit more efficient utilization of capacity by allowing prices
to rise to market clearing levels, thereby permitting those who place
the highest value on the capacity to obtain it. The Commission
determined that the data obtained by the Commission both during the
Order No. 637 experiment and more recently indicated that short-term
release prices reflect market value of the capacity as revealed by
basis differentials, rather than the exercise of market power.
Moreover, the Commission reasoned that shippers purchasing capacity
would be adequately protected because the pipeline's firm and
interruptible services will provide just and reasonable recourse rates
limiting the ability of releasing shippers to exercise market power.
Finally, the Commission stated that reporting requirements in Order No.
637 and the Commission's implementation of the Energy Policy Act of
2005, specifically with respect to market manipulation, give the
Commission an enhanced ability to monitor the market and detect and
deter abuses. The Commission did not propose to remove the price
ceiling on either long-term capacity releases or the pipelines' sale of
their own primary capacity.
17. Second, the Commission proposed to revise its capacity release
policies to give releasing shippers greater flexibility to negotiate
and implement AMAs, based on the Commission's findings that AMAs
provide significant benefits to participants in the natural gas and
electric marketplaces.\27\ Recognizing that the linking of
transportation capacity with gas supply arrangements would violate the
Commission's prohibition against ``tying'' released capacity to any
extraneous conditions, the Commission proposed to exempt pre-arranged
capacity release transactions that met certain criteria \28\ from the
prohibition against tying.\29\ This proposal would permit a releasing
shipper in a pre-arranged release to require that the replacement
shipper agree to supply the releasing shipper's gas requirements and
take assignment of the releasing shipper's gas supply contracts, as
well as released transportation capacity on one or more pipelines and
storage capacity with the gas currently in storage.\30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ NOPR at P 67-74.
\28\ The Commission's definition of AMA as proposed in the NOPR
is discussed in detail below.
\29\ NOPR at P 75-82.
\30\ In addition, the releasing shipper could require that, upon
expiration of the AMA, the replacement shipper must return storage
capacity included in the release with an appropriate level of
inventory, e.g., to promise to replenish storage inventories to a
mutually agreed upon level.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 37062]]
18. The Commission's second proposal to facilitate AMAs was to
exempt pre-arranged releases to implement AMAs from competitive
bidding.\31\ The Commission stated that, because the asset manager will
manage the releasing shipper's gas supply operations on an ongoing
basis, it is critical that the releasing shipper be able to release the
capacity to its chosen asset manager. Requiring releases made in order
to implement an AMA to be posted for bidding would thus interfere with
the negotiation of beneficial AMAs by potentially preventing the
releasing shipper from releasing the capacity to its chosen asset
manager. The Commission concluded that in the AMA context the bidding
requirement creates an unwarranted obstacle to the efficient management
of pipeline capacity and supply assets. The Commission emphasized that
AMAs would remain subject to all existing posting and reporting
requirements.\32\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ See NOPR at P 83-90. Section 284.8 of the Commission's
regulations require capacity release transactions to be posted for
competitive bidding unless the transactions are at the maximum
tariff rate or are for a term of 31 days or less.
\32\ While the NOPR originally required that any comments were
due January 10, 2008, a number of entities filed for an extension of
that deadline until February 8, 2008. On January 14, the Commission
granted an extension of time for filing comments until January 25,
2008.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
C. Comments
19. Over 60 entities from all segments of the natural gas industry
filed comments on the NOPR. The vast majority of those who filed
comments regarding the Commission's proposal to permanently remove the
price cap for short-term capacity releases of one year or less support
the proposal, generally agreeing with the Commission's reasoning in
support of removing the cap. Many of the local distribution companies
(LDC), marketers, producers, and end-users who support lifting the
price cap on short-term capacity releases also support retaining the
price cap on long-term capacity releases \33\ and/or primary pipeline
capacity.\34\ These parties generally view retention of these price
caps as providing valuable safeguards in preventing the exercise of
market power in the uncapped short-term capacity release market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ Those commenters include Direct Energy Services, LLC
(Direct Energy), New Jersey Natural Gas Company (NJNG), Oklahoma
Independent Petroleum Association (OIPA), Reliant Energy Inc.
(Reliant), Statoil Natural Gas, LLC (Statoil), and Weyerhaeuser
Company (Weyerhaeuser).
\34\ Such commenters include Edison Electric Institute (EEI),
NJNG, NJR Energy Services Company (NJR), Nstar Gas Company (Nstar),
OIPA, Piedmont Natural Gas Company, Inc. (Piedmont), Statoil,
Weyerhaeuser, and the Wisconsin Distributor Group (WDG). American
Gas Association (AGA), American Public Gas Association (APGA), and
Independent Petroleum Producers of America (IPAA) oppose lifting the
price cap for primary capacity, arguing that doing so would undercut
a major premise for lifting the price cap in the short-term
secondary market, namely, that the availability of recourse rates
from the pipeline will constrain the exercise of market power in the
secondary market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
20. Two commenters oppose the Commission's proposal to lift the
price cap for the short-term capacity release market, arguing that the
Commission has not supported its proposed rule and that the proposed
rule would fail a cost-benefit test.\35\ Other commenters express
concern over the potential for capacity owners to exercise market power
under the proposed rule.\36\ For example, some end-users of gas express
concerns about the concentration of capacity ownership on lateral
pipelines and therefore argue that the Commission should either not
remove the price cap for laterals or do so on a case-by-case basis.\37\
Other parties generally urge the Commission to carefully monitor
markets to ensure that they are functioning properly. Some suggest a
final test period before permanently removing the cap, periodic
reassessments of the uncapped market, or a process to revisit the
determination if the market becomes dysfunctional.\38\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\35\ Tenaska Marketing Ventures (Tenaska) and National Energy
Marketers Association (NEM).
\36\ See Comments of NEM.
\37\ Weyerhaeuser, Northwest Industrial Gas Users (NWIGU), and
Process Gas Consumers (PGC).
\38\ Direct Energy, OIPA, Honeywell International, Inc.
(Honeywell), Arizona Public Service Company (APS) (arguing that the
market currently served by El Paso Natural Gas Pipeline east of
California is not competitive). Commerce Energy Group, Inc.
(Commerce Energy) suggests including a contingency for replacing the
price cap in ``exceptional capacity situations.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
21. In general, commenters also overwhelmingly supported the
Commission's efforts to facilitate the development of AMAs.\39\ Those
commenters agree with the Commission's assessment that AMAs provide
value and benefits to market participants and to natural gas markets
overall. Virtually all who commented support the steps proposed by the
Commission to facilitate AMAs, though many of those that support the
Commission's proposal regarding AMAs request that the Commission modify
or clarify the proposal in various ways in order to permit broader use
of AMAs and greater flexibility in the terms of permitted AMAs. They
request, for example, that the Commission permit uncapped AMA releases
of a year or less to be rolled over without bidding, clarify that
profit sharing arrangements in an AMA do not violate any applicable
price cap, relax the requirements concerning the replacement shipper's
obligation to deliver gas to the releasing shipper, exempt AMAs from
the Commission's prohibition against buy/sell arrangements, and allow
supply side AMAs. Williston Basin commented that exempting AMAs from
the tying prohibition and bidding requirements would encourage
discrimination against pipelines and provide preferential treatment to
asset managers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\39\ See e.g., Comments of the AGA at 1-2, Comments of APGA at
2-4; Comments of Atmos Energy Corporation (Atmos) at 2-4, Comments
of BG Energy Merchants (BGEM) at 1-2, Comments of BP Energy Company
(BP) at 2, Comments of Direct Energy at 3-4, Comments of Duke Energy
Corporation (Duke Energy) at 3, Comments of the EEI at 6, Comments
of the Electric Power Supply Association (EPSA) at 2, Comments of
Florida Cities at 2, Comments of the Interstate Natural Gas
Association of America (INGAA) at 6, Comments of Marketer
Petitioners at 2, Comments of National Grid Delivery Companies
(National Grid) at 2, Comments of NJNG at 1, Comments of the Natural
Gas Supply Association (NGSA) at 3, Comments of NJR at 1, Comments
of NWIGU at 6, Comments of Nstar at 1-2, Comments of the Ohio Gas
Marketers Group (OGMG) at 1, Comments of Piedmont at 1, Comments of
PPM Energy, Inc., (PPM) at 1-3, Comments of PGC at 5, Comments of
the Public Utilities Commission of Ohio (PUCO) at 5-7, Comments of
Puget Sound Energy, Inc. (Puget Sound) at 8-9, Comments of Sequent
Energy Management, L.P. (Sequent) at 5-6, Comments of the Financial
Institutions Energy Group (FEIG) at 6-7, Comments of Turlock
Irrigation District (Turlock) at 5, Comments of Ultra Petroleum
Corporation (Ultra) at 4, Comments of the WDG at 3, and Comments of
the Wyoming Pipeline Authority at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. The Commission also received favorable comments on whether it
should clarify its prohibition against tying agreements to allow a
releasing shipper to include conditions in a storage release concerning
the sale and/or repurchase of gas in storage inventory outside the AMA
context. All comments that addressed this issue supported removing this
prohibition for storage services. They assert that a shipper releasing
storage capacity should be permitted to require the replacement shipper
to take assignment of any gas that remains in the released storage
capacity at the time the release takes effect; and/or to return the
storage capacity to releasing shipper at end of the release with a
specified amount of gas in storage.\40\ Commenters note that tying
storage capacity with storage inventory will enable transactions to be
consummated more readily and that the nature of the relationship
between storage capacity and storage inventory calls out for a waiver
of the tying rule. Others add that the ability of releasing shippers to
``tie'' storage capacity with storage inventory such that releasing
[[Page 37063]]
shippers would be permitted to require that replacement shippers take
inventory as a condition of release, even in circumstances outside the
AMA context, will provide benefits to the marketplace similar to those
provided by AMAs.\41\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\40\ Public Service Commission of New York (PSCNY) comments at
20-21.
\41\ Comments of Marketer Petitioners.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
23. The Commission also received numerous comments on its inquiry
whether pre-arranged capacity release deals necessary to implement
retail access programs should be treated as similar to releases made as
part of an AMA, and thus accorded the same exemptions. The majority of
comments on this issue advocated affording capacity releases under
state retail choice programs the same blanket exemptions from the tying
prohibition \42\ and bidding requirements as those granted to asset
managers.\43\ AGA, for example, recommends that the Commission add an
exemption from the bidding requirements for any prearranged, recallable
capacity release from an LDC to a natural gas marketer in accordance
with the terms of a retail choice program approved by a State
commission. AGA also asks that the Commission clarify that LDC releases
to retail choice marketers would be entitled to the same partial
exemption from the tying prohibition as would be releases under AMAs.
The SPSCNY would extend the AMA exemption from the tying prohibition to
releases of storage capacity conducted according to state retail access
programs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\42\ Those commenters include AGA, Commerce Energy, Duke Energy,
Hess Corporation (Hess), Interstate Gas Supply (IGS), NJNG, New York
State Electric and Gas Corporation (NYSEG), Rochester Gas & Electric
Corporation (RG&E), OGMG, the Public Service Commission of North
Carolina (PSNC), South Carolina Electric and Gas Company (SCE&G),
SCANA Energy Marketing (SEMI), PSCNY, and Sequent.
\43\ Those commenters include the AGA, Boardwalk Pipeline
Partners (Boardwalk), BP, Commerce Energy, Direct Energy, Duke
Energy, FPL Energy, LLC (FPL Energy), Hess, IGS, NJNG, NYSEG, RG&E,
Nstar, OGMG, Peoples Gas System, a Division of Tampa Electric
Company (Peoples), PG&E, PSCNY, PUCO, SEMI, Sequent, and the WDG.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Overview of the Final Rule
24. In this Final Rule, the Commission is modifying its policies
and regulations concerning the release of capacity by firm shippers on
interstate pipelines in order to enhance the efficiency and
effectiveness of the secondary capacity release market. The
Commission's capacity release program has created a successful
secondary market for capacity.\44\ As a result, natural gas markets in
general, and the secondary release market in particular, have undergone
significant development and change in the sixteen years since Order No.
636 and the inception of the capacity release program. As this market
has developed, shippers and potential shippers have sought greater
flexibility in the use of capacity. They seek to better integrate
capacity with the underlying gas transactions, and are looking for more
flexible methods of pricing capacity to better reflect the value of
that capacity as revealed by the market price of gas at different
trading points. They also seek to implement AMAs, in which capacity
holders release their capacity to asset managers (generally marketers)
that have greater expertise in maximizing the value of pipeline
capacity and negotiating beneficial transactions in the gas commodity
markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\44\ As the Commission observed in 2005, the ``capacity release
program together with the Commission's policies on segmentation, and
flexible point rights, has been successful in creating a robust
secondary market where pipelines must compete on price.'' Policy for
Selective Discounting by Natural Gas Pipelines, 111 FERC ] 61,309,
at P 39-41, order on reh'g, 113 FERC ] 61,173 (2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. In this Final Rule the Commission is taking actions to respond
to the industry's request for greater flexibility in the capacity
release market and to revise its policies and regulations to reflect
the changes and developments in the marketplace. The first major
revision is the removal of the price ceiling on short term capacity
releases. The permanent elimination of the price ceiling for short term
releases will enable shippers to offer competitively-priced
alternatives to pipelines' negotiated rate offerings and will permit
short-term capacity release prices to rise to market clearing levels,
thereby allocating capacity to those that value it the most. It will
also provide more accurate price signals concerning the market value of
pipeline capacity.
26. The Commission is also revising its regulations and policies to
accommodate and facilitate AMAs, a relatively recent development in the
industry. AMAs provide significant benefits to many participants in the
natural gas and electric marketplaces and to the secondary marketplace
itself. They maximize the utilization and value of capacity by creating
a mechanism for capacity holders to use third party experts to both (1)
manage their gas supply arrangements and (2) use that capacity to make
gas sales or re-releases of the capacity to others when the capacity is
not needed to serve the releasing shipper. AMAs result in ultimate
savings for end-use customers by providing for lower gas supply costs
and more efficient use of the pipeline grid.\45\ The Commission's goal
in facilitating AMAs in this rule is to make the capacity release
program more efficient by bringing it into line with the realities of
today's secondary gas marketplace.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ See Comments of BGEM at 2, Comments of BP at 5, Comments of
Nstar at 8, Comments of Piedmont at 4-5, Comments of PUCO at 7,
Comments of WDG at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
27. To that end, the Commission in this rule is adopting its NOPR
proposal to exempt capacity releases made to implement AMAs from the
prohibition on tying and the bidding requirements of section 284.8. The
Commission is also making several revisions to the definition of AMAs
as proposed in the NOPR. The Final Rule modifies the definition of AMAs
proposed in the NOPR to relax the delivery obligation of the
replacement shipper to the releasing shipper and to permit supply side
AMAs. The Final Rule also clarifies that short term AMAs may be rolled
over without bidding. Further, the Final Rule clarifies that the price
ceiling does not apply to any consideration provided by an asset
manager to the releasing shipper as part of an AMA. These steps,
requested by many industry commenters that support the Commission's
efforts in the NOPR to facilitate AMA's, will further enhance the
efficiency of AMAs by allowing greater flexibility for parties to
customize arrangements to meet unique customer needs while at the same
time ensuring that capacity releases that qualify for the exemptions
from tying and bidding granted in this rule are bona fide AMAs. The
rule also extends the benefits of AMAs to sellers of natural gas,
creating an even greater diversity of potential suppliers and
participants in the secondary market.
28. The Commission is also revising its policies to reflect the
realities of today's marketplace by allowing a releasing shipper to
include conditions in a release concerning the sale/and repurchase of
gas in storage inventory, even outside the AMA context. Allowing such
arrangements reflects the fact that in the storage context, storage
capacity is inextricably linked to storage inventory. By permitting the
tying of releases of storage capacity to conditions on storage
inventory, the Commission will enhance the efficient use of storage
capacity while at the same time ensuring that releasing shippers will
have adequate storage inventories for the winter.
29. The Final Rule also extends the blanket exemptions from the
prohibition against tying and from bidding granted to AMAs to capacity
releases made to a
[[Page 37064]]
marketer participating in a state approved retail access program,
finding that such programs provide benefits similar to AMAs.
III. Price Cap Issues
A. Removal of Maximum Rate Ceiling for Short-Term Capacity Releases
30. In this Final Rule, the Commission amends section 284.8 of its
regulations to eliminate the price ceiling for short-term capacity
release transactions of one year or less. The Commission finds that
this action will improve shipper options and market efficiency,
particularly during peak periods, by allowing the prices of short-term
capacity release transactions to reflect short-term variations in the
market value of that capacity. This will enable shippers to better
integrate capacity with the underlying gas transactions, and will
permit more flexible methods of pricing capacity to better reflect the
value of that capacity as revealed by the market price of gas at
different trading points. The Commission has previously provided
pipelines with the flexibility to enter into negotiated rate
transactions which are permitted to exceed the maximum rate ceiling,
and this rule will permit releasing shippers similar flexibility in
pricing release transactions.
31. At the same time, we are convinced that the rates resulting
from removal of the price cap for capacity release will be just and
reasonable. The data collected over many years shows that the value of
short term capacity only exceeds the price ceiling in times when
capacity is scarce. These data are confirmed by the data gathered
during the experimental release of the price ceiling which showed that
capacity release prices exceed the price ceiling only for brief periods
of constraint. Moreover, we are not relying solely on competition to
ensure just and reasonable prices. We are maintaining the rate cap on
pipeline services that will provide the same protection for capacity
release transactions as it now does for pipeline negotiated rate
transactions. Further, we have required informational postings of
capacity release transactions that will provide transparency and
facilitate the filing of complaints if circumstances warrant. The
Commission will also continue to actively monitor the release market.
1. Maximum Rate Ceiling Interferes With Efficient Transactions
32. As we explained in Order No. 637,\46\ the traditional cost-of-
service maximum rates in pipeline tariffs are not well suited to the
short-term capacity release market.\47\ Under the traditional
ratemaking methodology, the Commission develops a maximum annual
transportation rate for each pipeline that, when applied to the
pipeline's contract demand and throughput levels, will enable the
pipeline to recover its annual cost-of-service revenue requirement.
Each pipeline's maximum rates for services of less than a year are
simply the maximum annual rate prorated over the shorter period.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\46\ Order No. 637 at 31,271-75.
\47\ While the Commission offered pipelines the opportunity to
propose other types of rate designs, such as seasonal and term-
differentiated rates, only a very few pipelines have sought to make
such rate design changes, although many pipelines have taken
advantage of negotiated rate authority.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
33. Such prorated annual rates bear no relationship to the
competitive rates that would be established in the short-term capacity
market, particularly during peak periods. The market value of
transportation service from the production area to the downstream
market may be inferred by comparing the downstream delivered gas price
in bundled sales to the market price at upstream market centers in the
production area.\48\ As the DC Circuit recognized in INGAA, ``if the
difference between field prices and city gate prices in a particular
pathway is only $.07, people will not pay more than $.07 for the
unbundled transportation.'' \49\ As discussed in more detail below, the
data set forth in Order No. 637 and the updated data in Figures 1
through 3 below concerning the implicit value of transportation in the
bundled sales market demonstrates the variability of transportation
value in the short-term market and the divergence between the
transportation value and cost-of-service rates. This data shows that
during most of the year, the value of transportation service is
significantly less than the pipelines' annual cost-of-service maximum
transportation rates, but during brief, peak demand periods, the value
of transportation service is measurably greater than the maximum
transportation rates.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\48\ In Order No. 637, the Commission explained ``gas commodity
markets now determine the economic value of pipeline services in
many parts of the country. Thus, even as FERC has sought to isolate
pipeline services from commodity sales, it is within the commodity
markets that one can see revealed the true price for gas
transportation.'' Order No. 637 at 31,274 (quoting M. Barcella, How
Commodity Markets Drive Gas Pipeline Values, Public Utilities
Fortnightly, February 1, 1998 at 24-25).
\49\ INGAA at 31.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
34. Because the existing capacity release price ceiling does not
reflect short-term variations in the market value of the capacity, the
price ceiling inhibits the efficient allocation of capacity and harms,
rather than helps, the short-term shippers it is intended to protect.
The price ceiling operates to prevent the shipper most valuing short-
term capacity on a peak day from being able to obtain it, because that
shipper cannot offer a releasing shipper the full value the shipper
places on that capacity. The price ceiling may also reduce the amount
of released capacity available during peak periods. As the Commission
explained in Order No. 637, ``As a result of the maximum rate, firm
capacity holders may not find it sufficiently profitable to make their
capacity available for release. For instance, a dual fuel industrial
customer might determine that it would be more economic not to use gas,
and to substitute a different fuel, if it could obtain a sufficiently
high price for its released capacity.'' \50\ Thus, during a peak day
the price ceiling may only serve to limit a purchasing shipper's
capacity options, with the result that it must purchase gas in a
bundled transaction in the downstream market at a price reflecting the
market-determined value of the transportation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\50\ Order No. 637 at 31,279.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
35. The increased use by pipelines and shippers of negotiated rate
transactions based on gas price differentials demonstrates that buyers
and sellers value the ability to calibrate the price of transportation
to its value in the market. The maximum rate ceiling applied to
capacity release transactions denies releasing and replacement shippers
the same ability to negotiate transactions that reflect the market
value of capacity at all times. As the Commission has found, providing
the ability to negotiate capacity release transactions based on price
differentials will help in providing short-term capacity to replacement
shippers, such as gas-fired electric generators.\51\ With the price
ceiling in effect, releasing shippers are unable to effectively use
price differentials as a measure of capacity value because they are
denied the ability to recover the value of capacity during peak periods
when that value exceeds the maximum rate cap.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\51\ Standards for Business Practices for Interstate Natural Gas
Pipelines, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 71 FR 64,655 (November 3,
2006), FERC Stats. & Regs. Proposed Regulations ] 32,609, P 17 (Oct.
25, 2006), Order No. 698, 72 FR 38,757 (July 16, 2007), FERC Stats.
& Regs. Regulations Preambles ] 31,251 at P 51 (Jun. 25, 2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
36. The price ceiling also harms captive customers holding long-
term contracts on the pipeline. Those customers pay maximum rates for
both peak and off-peak periods. During off-
[[Page 37065]]
peak periods, they can only recover a small portion of the capacity
cost through capacity release because of the low market value of off-
peak capacity. However, during peak periods, the price ceiling prevents
those customers from releasing their capacity for its full market
value.
37. Finally, the price ceiling reduces the dissemination of
accurate capacity pricing information. That is because the price
ceiling causes transactions to move to the bundled sales market during
peak periods, so that there is no separate capacity transaction to be
reported.
2. Assurance of Just and Reasonable Rates
38. As the court stated in INGAA, the Commission may depart from
cost of service ratemaking upon:
A showing that * * * the goals and purposes of the statute will
be accomplished `through the proposed changes.' To satisfy that
standard, we demanded that the resulting rates be expected to fall
within a `zone of reasonableness, where [they] are neither less than
compensatory nor excessive.' [citation omitted]. While the expected
rates' proximity to cost was a starting point for this inquiry into
reasonableness, [citation omitted], we were quite explicit that
`non-cost factors may legitimate a departure from a rigid cost-based
approach,' [citation omitted]. Finally, we said that FERC must
retain some general oversight over the system, to see if competition
in fact drives rates into the zone of reasonableness `or to check
rates if it does not.' \52\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\52\ INGAA at 31.
Accordingly, we analyze below (1) the extent to which market conditions
and other factors may be expected to keep short-term capacity release
prices within a reasonable zone despite the removal of the price
ceiling, (2) the non-cost factors supporting a removal of the price
ceiling, and (3) our oversight of the short-term capacity release
market after removal of the price ceiling.
a. Market Conditions Ensure Just and Reasonable Rates
39. The Commission finds that the short-term capacity release
market is generally competitive. Therefore competition, together with
our continuing requirement that pipelines must sell short-term firm and
interruptible services to any shipper offering the maximum rate, and
the Commission's ongoing monitoring efforts will keep short-term
capacity release rates within the ``zone of reasonableness'' required
by INGAA and Farmers Union.
40. In Order Nos. 636 and 637, the Commission instituted a number
of policy revisions which have enhanced competition between releasing
shippers as well as between releasing shippers and the pipeline. These
revisions provide shippers with enhanced market mechanisms that will
help ensure a more competitive market and mitigate the potential for
the exercise of market power. The Commission required pipelines to
permit releasing shippers to use flexible point rights and to fully
segment their pipeline capacity. Flexible point rights enable shippers
to use any points within their capacity path on a secondary basis,
which enables shippers to compete effectively on release transactions
with other shippers. Segmentation further enhances the ability to
compete because it enables the releasing shipper to retain the portion
of the pipeline capacity it needs while releasing the unneeded portion.
Effective segmentation makes more capacity available and enhances
competition. As the Commission explained in Order No. 637:
The combination of flexible point rights and segmentation
increases the alternatives available to shippers looking for
capacity. In the example,\53\ a shipper in Atlanta looking for
capacity has multiple choices. It can purchase available capacity
from the pipeline. It can obtain capacity from a shipper with firm
delivery rights at Atlanta or from any shipper with delivery point
rights downstream of Atlanta. The ability to segment capacity
enhances options further. The shipper in New York does not have to
forgo deliveries of gas to New York in order to release capacity to
the shipper seeking to deliver gas in Atlanta. The New York shipper
can both sell capacity to the shipper in Atlanta and retain the
right to inject gas downstream of Atlanta to serve its New York
market.\54\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\53\ In the example used in Order No. 636, a shipper holding
firm capacity from a primary receipt point in the Gulf of Mexico to
primary delivery points in New York could release that capacity to a
replacement shipper moving gas from the Gulf to Atlanta while the
New York releasing shipper could inject gas downstream of Atlanta
and use the remainder of the capacity to deliver the gas to New
York.
\54\ Order No. 637 at 31,301.
41. In addition to enhancing competition through expansion of
flexible point rights and segmentation, the Commission in Order No. 637
also required pipelines to provide shippers with scheduling equal to
that provided by the pipeline, so that replacement shippers can submit
a nomination at the first available opportunity after consummation of
the capacity release transaction. The change makes capacity release
more competitive with pipeline services and increases competition
between capacity releasers by enabling replacement shippers to schedule
the use of capacity obtained through release transactions quickly
rather than having to wait until the next day.
42. The data accumulated by the Commission during the Order No. 637
experiment, as well as review of more recent data, confirm that
capacity release prices reflect competitive condi