Wholesale Competition in Regions With Organized Electric Markets, 12576-12619 [E8-3984]
Download as PDF
12576
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
18 CFR Part 35
[Docket Nos. RM07–19–000 and AD07–7–
000]
Wholesale Competition in Regions
With Organized Electric Markets
Issued February 22, 2008.
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission (Commission) is
proposing to amend its regulations
under the Federal Power Act to improve
the operation of organized wholesale
electric markets in the areas of: Demand
response and market pricing during a
period of operating reserve shortage;
long-term power contracting; marketmonitoring policies; and the
responsiveness of regional transmission
organizations (RTOs) and independent
system operators (ISOs) to stakeholders
and customers, and ultimately to the
consumers who benefit from and pay for
electricity services. The Commission
proposes to require that each RTO and
ISO make certain filings that propose
amendments to its tariff, in order to
comply with the proposed requirements
in each area, or that demonstrate that its
existing tariff and market design already
satisfy the requirements. The
Commission invites all interested
persons to submit comments in
response to the regulations proposed
herein.
DATES:
Comments are due April 21,
2008.
You may submit comments,
identified by docket number by any of
the following methods.
• Agency Web site: https://ferc.gov.
Documents created electronically using
word processing software should be
filed in native applications or print-toPDF format and not in a scanned format.
ADDRESSES:
• Mail/Hand Delivery: Commenters
unable to file comments electronically
must mail or hand deliver an original
and 14 copies of their comments to:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
Secretary of the Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
Instructions: For detailed instructions
on submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process,
see the Comment Procedures Section of
this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
David Kathan (Technical Information),
Office of Energy Market Regulation,
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC
20426, David.Kathan@ferc.gov, (202)
502–6404.
Tina Ham (Legal Information), Office
of the General Counsel, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC
20426,Tina.Ham@ferc.gov, (202) 502–
6224.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Table of Contents
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
Paragraph
numbers
I. Introduction ...........................................................................................................................................................................................
II. Background ...........................................................................................................................................................................................
III. Proposals To Expand the Scope of the Proceeding ..........................................................................................................................
IV. Discussion ...........................................................................................................................................................................................
A. Demand Response and Pricing During Periods of Operating Reserve Shortages in Organized Markets ...............................
1. Background .............................................................................................................................................................................
a. Importance of Demand Response to Competition in RTO/ISO Areas .........................................................................
b. Prior Commission Actions To Address Demand Response .........................................................................................
2. The Need for Commission Action ........................................................................................................................................
3. Proposed Reforms ..................................................................................................................................................................
a. Ancillary Services Provided by Demand Response Resources ....................................................................................
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR .....................................................................................................................
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions ............................................................................................
iii. Commission Proposal ............................................................................................................................................
b. Deviation Charge .............................................................................................................................................................
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR .....................................................................................................................
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions ............................................................................................
iii. Commission Proposal ............................................................................................................................................
c. Aggregation of Retail Customers ....................................................................................................................................
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR .....................................................................................................................
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions ............................................................................................
iii. Commission Proposal ............................................................................................................................................
d. Potential Future Demand Response Reforms ................................................................................................................
e. Market Rules Governing Price Formation During Periods of Operating Reserve Shortage .......................................
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR .....................................................................................................................
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions ............................................................................................
iii. Commission Proposal ............................................................................................................................................
B. Long-Term Power Contracting in Organized Markets ................................................................................................................
1. Background .............................................................................................................................................................................
2. The Need for Commission Action ........................................................................................................................................
3. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR ...................................................................................................................................
4. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions ...........................................................................................................
5. Proposed Reforms ..................................................................................................................................................................
C. Market-Monitoring Policies ..........................................................................................................................................................
1. Background .............................................................................................................................................................................
2. Prior Commission Actions Regarding Market Monitoring ..................................................................................................
3. The Need for Commission Action ........................................................................................................................................
4. Proposed Reforms ..................................................................................................................................................................
a. Independence and Function ...........................................................................................................................................
i. Structure and Tools ..................................................................................................................................................
ii. Oversight ..................................................................................................................................................................
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
1
12
16
26
26
27
28
32
37
46
47
47
50
56
65
65
67
72
80
80
82
86
94
97
97
99
107
129
130
134
138
142
155
162
163
165
169
171
172
173
183
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
12577
Paragraph
numbers
iii. Functions ................................................................................................................................................................
iv. Mitigation and Operations .....................................................................................................................................
v. Ethics ........................................................................................................................................................................
vi. Tariff Provisions .....................................................................................................................................................
b. Information Sharing ........................................................................................................................................................
i. Enhanced Information Dissemination .....................................................................................................................
ii. Tailored Requests for Information .........................................................................................................................
iii. Commission Referrals ............................................................................................................................................
c. Pro Forma Tariff ..............................................................................................................................................................
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR .....................................................................................................................
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions ............................................................................................
iii. Commission Proposal ............................................................................................................................................
D. Responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to Stakeholders and Customers .........................................................................................
1. Background .............................................................................................................................................................................
2. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR ...................................................................................................................................
3. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions ...........................................................................................................
a. Comments on the Hybrid Board Approach ...................................................................................................................
b. Comments on the Board Advisory Committee Approach ............................................................................................
c. Comments on the Need To Increase Management Responsiveness ............................................................................
d. Comments on Regional Differences ...............................................................................................................................
4. The Need for Commission Action ........................................................................................................................................
5. Proposed Reform ....................................................................................................................................................................
V. Applicability of the Proposed Rule and Compliance Procedures ....................................................................................................
VI. Information Collection Statement ......................................................................................................................................................
VII. Environmental Analysis ....................................................................................................................................................................
VIII. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification ..........................................................................................................................................
IX. Comment Procedures .........................................................................................................................................................................
X. Document Availability ........................................................................................................................................................................
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
APPENDIX A: Commenter Acronyms
I. Introduction
1. The Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission (Commission) is proposing
reforms to improve the operation of
organized wholesale electric power
markets.1 Ensuring the competitiveness
of organized wholesale markets is
integral to the Commission fulfilling its
statutory mandate to ensure adequate
and reliable non-discriminatory service
at just and reasonable rates. Effective
competition protects consumers by
providing greater supply options,
encouraging new entry and innovation,
and encouraging demand response and
energy efficiency. In the past several
years, the Commission has received
both formal and informal comments
from market participants, consumer and
industry organizations, state regulators,
and others recommending
improvements to competitive wholesale
markets.
2. In response to these comments, the
Commission held three public
conferences in 2007 in order to gather
more information on competition at the
wholesale level and other related issues.
At the first conference on competition
issues, held on February 27, 2007, most
speakers addressed issues affecting the
RTO and ISO regions, including the
1 Organized market regions are areas of the
country in which a regional transmission
organization (RTO) or independent system operator
(ISO) operates day-ahead and/or real-time energy
markets.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
levels of wholesale prices, the need for
long-term power contracts, the
effectiveness of market monitoring, and
the lack of adequate demand response.2
On April 5, 2007, the Commission also
held a technical conference on market
monitoring policies and heard from
interested commenters on issues such as
the development of the concept and
functions of market monitoring and the
market monitoring units’ (MMU) role
with respect to the Commission, ISOs
and RTOs, and various stakeholders.3
The Commission then held a second
competition conference on May 8, 2007,
to examine in more detail several
specific concerns and challenges
identified in the first conference. This
second conference focused on regions
with organized markets administered by
RTOs and ISOs and dealt with: (1)
Demand response, including the role of
demand response during a period of
operating reserve shortage; (2) fostering
long-term power contracting; and (3) the
responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to
customers and other stakeholders.4
3. Based on the record compiled at
these three conferences, the
Commission issued an Advance Notice
2 See
Second Supplemental Notice of Conference,
Conference on Competition in Wholesale Power
Markets, Docket No. AD07–7–000 (Feb. 26, 2007).
3 See Notice of Agenda for the Conference,
Review of Market Monitoring Policies, Docket No.
AD07–8–000 (Mar. 30, 2007).
4 See Supplemental Notice of Conference,
Conference on Competition in Wholesale Power
Markets, Docket No. AD07–7–000 (Apr. 19, 2007).
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
191
200
211
215
219
220
231
238
241
241
242
243
245
247
249
254
255
264
268
270
272
275
282
286
290
291
292
296
of Proposed Rulemaking (ANOPR) 5 on
June 22, 2007 to identify and implement
improvements to specific aspects of
organized wholesale markets. In the
ANOPR, the Commission identified four
issues in organized market regions that
were not being adequately addressed or
under consideration in other
proceedings. These areas were: (1) The
role of demand response in organized
markets and greater use of market prices
to elicit demand response during a
period of operating reserve shortage; (2)
increasing opportunities for long-term
power contracting; (3) strengthening
market monitoring; and (4) enhancing
the responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to
customers and other stakeholders, and
ultimately to the consumers who benefit
from and pay for electricity services.
4. The Commission received several
thousand pages of comments from over
a hundred commenters in response to
the ANOPR (a list of commenters and
their abbreviated names the
Commission will use for them in this
document appears in Appendix A).6
After review of the comments, and
pursuant to our responsibility under
5 Wholesale Competition in Regions with
Organized Electric Markets, Advance Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking, 72 FR 36,276 (July 2, 2007),
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,617 (2007).
6 We do not summarize in this NOPR every
comment received in response to the ANOPR. The
Commission has reviewed and considered each
comment submitted, however, and appreciates the
careful consideration the commenters have given to
this proceeding.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
12578
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
sections 205 and 206 of the Federal
Power Act (FPA) 7 to ensure that rates,
charges, classifications, and service of
public utilities (and any rule, regulation,
practice, or contract affecting any of
these) are just and reasonable and not
unduly discriminatory, the Commission
is making several proposals in this
NOPR designed to ensure just and
reasonable rates and to remedy undue
discrimination and preference and to
improve wholesale competition in
regions with organized markets. These
proposals reflect the record compiled by
the Commission in its conferences and
in comments to the ANOPR. These
proposals, along with background
information and a summary of
comments received, will be described in
detail in the sections below.
5. In proposing the reforms in the four
areas described below, the Commission
recognizes that there are differences of
opinion on the appropriate scope of this
rulemaking, as well as on the four
specific issues described in the ANOPR.
We are therefore guided by the record in
this proceeding and the need to
undertake timely and concrete reforms
where the record supports them. From
the commencement of our first technical
conference in this proceeding, our goal
has been to identify any specific reforms
that can be made to optimize the
efficiency of organized markets for the
benefit of customers, and ultimately the
consumers who benefit from and pay for
electricity services. As we explain
further below, however, this proceeding
does not represent the final effort to
improve the efficiency of competitive
markets. Rather, we will continue to
evaluate other specific reforms that may
be necessary.
6. In the area of demand response and
the use of market prices to elicit
demand response, the Commission
proposes several requirements for ISOs
and RTOs. These proposals include
requirements to: (1) Accept bids from
demand response resources in their
markets for certain ancillary services,
comparable to any other resources; (2)
eliminate, during a system emergency, a
charge to a buyer in the energy market
for taking less electric energy in the realtime market than purchased in the dayahead market; (3) permit an aggregator
of retail customers (ARC) to bid demand
response on behalf of retail customers
directly into the organized energy
market; (4) modify their market rules, as
necessary, to allow the market-clearing
price, during periods of operating
reserve shortage, to reach a level that
rebalances supply and demand so as to
maintain reliability while providing
7 16
U.S.C. 824d–824e (2000).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
sufficient provisions for mitigating
market power; and (5) study whether
further reforms are necessary to
eliminate barriers to demand response
in organized markets.
7. In the section on long-term power
contracting, the Commission proposes
that ISOs and RTOs be required to
dedicate a portion of their Web sites for
market participants to post offers to buy
or sell power on a long-term basis. This
proposal is designed to promote greater
use of long-term contracts through
improving transparency among market
participants.
8. In the area of improving market
monitoring, the Commission proposes
that each RTO and ISO provide its
MMU with access to market data,
resources and personnel sufficient to
carry out its duties, and that the MMU
(or the external MMU in a hybrid
structure) report directly to the RTO or
ISO board. In addition, the Commission
proposes to require that the MMU’s
functions include: (1) Identifying
ineffective market rules and
recommending proposed rules and tariff
changes; (2) reviewing and reporting on
the performance of the wholesale
markets to the RTO or ISO, the
Commission, and other interested
entities; and (3) notifying appropriate
Commission staff of instances in which
a market participant’s behavior requires
investigation. The Commission also
proposes expanding the list of recipients
to receive MMU recommendations
regarding rule and tariff changes, and
broadening the scope of behavior to be
reported to the Commission. The
Commission further proposes to remove
the MMU from tariff administration,
require each RTO and ISO to include
ethics standards for MMU employees in
its tariff, and consolidate all its MMU
provisions in one section of its tariff.
The Commission also proposes
expanding the dissemination of MMU
market information to a broader
constituency, with reports made on a
more frequent basis, and reducing the
time period before energy market bid
and offer data are released to the public.
9. Finally, the Commission proposes
to establish new criteria intended to
ensure that an RTO or ISO is responsive
to its customers and stakeholders, and
ultimately to the consumers who benefit
from and pay for electricity services.
These principles will include: (1)
Inclusiveness; (2) fairness in balancing
diverse interests; (3) representation of
minority positions; and (4) ongoing
responsiveness.
10. In each of these four areas, the
Commission will require RTOs and ISOs
to consult with their stakeholders and
make a compliance filing that details
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
why the entity’s existing practices
comply with the final rule in this
proceeding, or the entity’s plans to
attain compliance.
11. Finally, as indicated above, these
reforms do not represent our final effort
to improve the functioning of
competitive organized markets for the
benefit of consumers. For example,
although we are proposing specific
reforms to eliminate barriers to demand
response, we propose to require each
RTO or ISO to study whether further
reforms are necessary to eliminate
barriers to demand response in
organized markets. Any reforms must
ensure that demand response resources
are treated on a comparable basis as
other resources. We also are ordering a
staff technical conference on proposals
by American Forest and Portland
Cement Association, et al. to modify the
design of organized markets. Finally, we
direct, as explained further below, each
RTO or ISO to provide a forum for
affected consumers to voice specific
concerns (and to propose regional
solutions) on how to improve the
efficient operation of competitive
markets. The Commission therefore will
continue to evaluate reforms in this
area, but will not allow the prospect of
other reforms to delay the benefits to
consumers from those proposed herein.
II. Background
12. As the Commission noted in the
ANOPR, national policy has been, and
continues to be, to foster competition in
wholesale electric power markets.8 This
policy was embraced in the recent
Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct
2005),9 and is reflected in Commission
policy and practice. The Commission, in
fulfilling its responsibility to ‘‘guard the
consumer from exploitation by noncompetitive electric power
companies,’’ 10 relies on both its own
regulations and competition to ensure
consumer protection. In doing so, the
Commission is aware of the need to vary
the mix of regulation and competition
based on the circumstances of the time,
taking into account advances of
technology, changes in economies of
scale, and new state and federal laws
that affect the energy industry.
13. The Commission has acted over
the last few decades to implement
Congressional policy to expand the
wholesale electric power markets to
facilitate entry of new generators and to
support competitive markets. Absent a
8 ANOPR,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,617 at P 4.
L. No. 109–58, 119 Stat. 594 (2005).
10 Nat’l Ass’n for the Advancement of Colored
People v. FPC, 520 F.2d 432, 438 (DC Cir. 1975),
aff’d, 425 U.S. 662 (1976).
9 Pub.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
single national power market, the
development of regional markets is the
best method of facilitating competition
within the power industry, and the
Commission has made sustained efforts
to recognize and foster such markets.
The Commission acknowledges that
significant differences exist between
regions, including differences in
industry structure, mix of ownership,
sources for electric generation,
population densities, and weather
patterns. Some regions have organized
spot markets administered by an RTO or
ISO, and others rely solely on bilateral
contracting between wholesale sellers
and buyers. The Commission recognizes
and respects these differences across
various regions. At the same time,
wholesale competition can serve
customers well in all regions. The focus
of this proceeding is on further
improving the operation of wholesale
competitive markets in organized
market regions.11
14. Some perceived challenges in the
organized wholesale markets may be
closely related to state retail issues, and
the distinction between wholesale and
retail competition challenges is often
blurred. For example, wholesale
customers typically have more
advanced meters than retail customers;
organized market rates vary with time of
day whereas retail rates typically do not;
and retail choice programs, which tend
to be in areas served by organized
wholesale markets, may rely on RTOs or
ISOs to provide or arrange for the
provision of some functions previously
carried out by vertically integrated
utilities. This has created challenges for
wholesale market design. Although the
Commission acknowledges that issues
with retail markets are often intertwined
with wholesale market issues, the
Commission will not address retail
market issues in this proceeding. This
rulemaking is designed to focus on
wholesale markets; issues related to
retail markets will vary by state and are
more appropriately considered in
separate proceedings before the affected
state(s) or the Commission where the
specific interaction between the retail
and wholesale market can be explored.
15. Comments received on the
ANOPR and made during technical
conferences highlight several potential
problems with wholesale competition
both inside and outside the organized
11 The following RTOs and ISOs have organized
markets: PJM Interconnection, LLC (PJM), New York
Independent System Operator, Inc. (NYISO),
Midwest Independent Transmission System
Operator, Inc. (Midwest ISO), ISO New England,
Inc. (ISO–NE), California Independent Service
Operator Corp. (CAISO), and Southwest Power
Pool, Inc. (SPP).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
market regions that are within the scope
of this proceeding. In the ANOPR, the
Commission noted that it was not
addressing potential reforms outside the
organized market regions, explaining
that many of the important concerns
discussed during the first technical
conference (e.g., nondiscriminatory
access to transmission,
nondiscriminatory rules for power
procurement) were already being
addressed in other proceedings.
Similarly, the Commission has chosen
to limit this proceeding to four discrete
areas involving wholesale competition
within organized markets. As explained
further below, however, these are not
the final reforms the Commission may
pursue with respect to organized
markets; rather, we will continue to
evaluate specific proposals that may
serve to strengthen organized markets.
III. Proposals To Expand the Scope of
the Proceeding
16. Several parties propose to expand
the scope of this proceeding beyond the
four areas covered in the ANOPR. We
received a request from APPA, in its
comments on the ANOPR, and a request
from AARP, et al., a group consisting of
41 entities, for a large-scale
investigation of the workings of
organized markets with respect to their
ability to produce just and reasonable
rates. APPA and AARP, et al. state that
the current market system allows
incumbent sellers (those power
suppliers with older power plants) to
make excess profits while
disadvantaging certain power suppliers
with new generation. APPA and AARP,
et al. argue that this has resulted in
increased cost to consumers without the
corresponding benefit of new generation
being built. APPA and AARP, et al.
claim that the Commission has a
responsibility under sections 205 and
206 of the FPA to investigate the
workings of organized markets based on
their allegations of unjust and
unreasonable rates.
17. The Commission acknowledges
the concerns of APPA and AARP, et al.;
however, we decline to initiate the
broad investigation APPA and AARP, et
al. have requested as part of this
proceeding. As noted above, by listening
to the concerns of market participants,
and evaluating the record of this
proceeding, we have identified four
specific areas in which reforms can
improve wholesale electricity market
operations. Through the competition
conferences and the ANOPR process, we
have developed a solid record in favor
of making those reforms, and a strong
sense of what the Commission can do to
be helpful in these four areas. It is
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12579
important that the Commission move
forward with regard to the specific
reforms under consideration in this
proposed rulemaking to foster
improvements in the near term to the
competitive operation of existing
organized markets administered by
RTOs and ISOs. Further, we also note
that the approach we are taking in this
NOPR is consistent with the ISO/RTO
Council’s proposal.12
18. In contrast to the specific reforms
proposed herein, APPA and AARP, et
al. request a broad, generic inquiry into
alleged (but not specified) market design
flaws. Their request not only fails to
offer any specific solutions, but also
fails to appreciate the differences in
market design that exist in each region.
Over the past five years, the
Commission has undertaken significant
market design reforms in most regions.
We have not adopted a standard market
design, but rather have undertaken
different reforms, at different times in
each region to reflect the differing
characteristics of each market. The
Commission has devoted considerable
resources over the years to improving
the market designs in each organized
market to ensure that they produce just
and reasonable rates. We summarize
some of these efforts below.
19. For example, in response to the
California energy crisis of 2000–2001,
the Commission worked with CAISO
and its stakeholders to develop a Market
Redesign and Technology Upgrade
program designed to improve the
efficiency and proper working of the
market through improved modeling and
new forward markets,13 which the
Commission subsequently approved in
part. In 2004, the Commission approved
the Midwest ISO’s open access
transmission and energy markets tariff,
which provides for terms and
conditions necessary to implement a
market-based congestion management
program and energy spot markets.14
This includes a day-ahead energy
market and a real-time energy market,
12 ISO/RTO Council urges the Commission to
focus on determining the appropriate means of
addressing issues that are ripe for this NOPR and
which ones might be better considered in existing
forums. It states that existing stakeholder processes
provide an appropriate forum for targeted
consideration of various issues, including the ones
raised by APPA and AARP, et al. ISO/RTO Council
at 1, 3.
13 Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp., 116 FERC
¶ 61,274 (2006), order on reh’g, 119 FERC ¶ 61,076
(2007).
14 Midwest Indep. Transmission Sys. Operator,
Inc., 108 FERC ¶ 61,163, order on reh’g, 109 FERC
¶ 61,157 (2004), order on reh’g 111 FERC ¶ 61,043,
reh’g denied, 112 FERC ¶ 61,086 (2005), aff’d sub
nom. Wisconsin Public Power, Inc. v. FERC, 493
F.3d 239 (DC Cir. 2007).
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12580
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
locational marginal pricing, and a
market for financial transmission rights.
20. The Commission has also acted on
proposals developed by regional entities
to ensure that adequate price signals
exist in the market for both short-term
and long-term electric power
transactions, by addressing pricing
issues during reserve shortages and by
approving forward capacity markets.
The Commission has approved a
demand curve for capacity markets in
the region operated by NYISO. The
Commission approved PJM’s Reliability
Pricing Model to provide an auction
process for forward capacity
contracting. The Commission also
approved a settlement agreement for
ISO–NE to create a transitional forward
capacity market to meet the needs of its
stakeholders.15 These actions were
designed to minimize the disruption
during periods of operating reserve
shortage and encourage new investment
in generation, while accepting variation
between regions and allowing for
regional choice.
21. The Commission has also issued
region-specific orders providing for cost
allocation for new transmission
investment, removing uncertainty over
the cost responsibility for the
development of new transmission. In
Opinion No. 494,16 the Commission
approved PJM’s policy for determining
recovery of transmission costs for
existing and new facilities, providing for
region-wide cost sharing for certain new
extra high-voltage transmission
facilities. The Commission also
approved the Midwest ISO’s transitional
pricing scheme, which incorporates cost
sharing for new transmission
facilities.17
22. In addition to these region-specific
actions, the Commission has addressed
incentives for the building of new
generation and transmission in all
regions with organized markets. In
Order No. 679,18 the Commission
allowed parties building transmission to
15 Devon Power, LLC, 115 FERC ¶ 61,340, order
on reh’g, 117 FERC ¶ 61,133 (2006), appeal pending
sub nom. Maine Pub. Utils. Comm’n v. FERC, No.
06–1403 (DC Cir. 2007).
16 PJM Interconnection, LLC, 119 FERC ¶ 61,063
(2007) (Opinion No. 494), reh’g pending.
17 Midwest Indep. Transmission Sys. Operator,
Inc., 114 FERC ¶ 61,106, order on reh’g and
technical conference, 117 FERC ¶ 61,241 (2006),
order on reh’g, 118 FERC ¶ 61,208 (2007), appeal
pending sub nom. Public Service Comm’n of
Wisconsin v. FERC, No. 06–1408 (D.C. Cir., filed
Dec. 13, 2006); Midwest Indep. Transmission Sys.
Operator, Inc., 118 FERC ¶ 61,209, order on reh’g,
120 FERC ¶ 61,080 (2007).
18 Promoting Transmission Investment through
Pricing Reform, Order No. 679, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,222, order on reh’g, Order No. 679–A, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,236 (2006), order on reh’g, 119
FERC ¶ 61,062 (2007).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
apply for recovery of prudently incurred
costs for construction work in progress,
pre-operations, and abandoned
facilities, and it provided for application
for an incentive rate of return on equity
for new transmission investment. As a
further means of reducing uncertainty
and spurring investment, the
Commission finalized rules for
interconnection for large, small and
wind generators. These rules remove
barriers to interconnection by
streamlining the process of, and
improving incentives for, building new
generation. The Commission has also
acted to improve certainty in the cost of
transmission for electric customers by
creating rules for long-term transmission
rights in Order Nos. 681 and 681–A.19
23. In Order No. 890, the Commission
reformed the open access transmission
tariff (OATT) to ensure that it continues
to provide nondiscriminatory access to
transmission service. Among other
things, Order No. 890 requires an open
and transparent regional transmission
planning process.20 The Commission is
now focusing on the compliance phase
of OATT reform to ensure that it is
implemented properly.21 The
Commission also has been pursuing a
cooperative dialogue with the National
Association of Regulatory Utility
Commissioners (NARUC) to identify
and analyze models for competitive
power procurement. This effort is
designed to enhance the ability of loadserving entities (LSEs) to acquire
reliable power supplies at competitive
prices. As noted in the ANOPR, the
Commission has also acted to
investigate demand response in
organized markets, through a
Commission report and a recent
technical conference. This conference
was designed to examine demand
response resources in markets, grid
operations and expansion, and best
practices for the measurement and
evaluation of demand response
resources.22 The Commission also held
a technical conference on December 11,
2007 to explore issues surrounding the
19 Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in
Organized Electricity Markets, Order No. 681, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,226, order on reh’g, Order No.
681–A, 117 FERC ¶ 61,201 (2006).
20 This addresses, in part, concerns raised by
some commenters regarding posting of future
transmission constraints and congestion costs.
21 ANOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,617 at P 33
(citing Preventing Undue Discrimination and
Preference in Transmission Service, Order No. 890,
72 FR 12,266 (Mar. 15, 2007), FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,241, order on reh’g, Order No. 890–A, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,261 (2007)).
22 Supplemental Notice, Demand Response in
Wholesale Markets, Docket No. AD07–11–000
(April 6, 2007).
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
management of interconnection
queues.23
24. In recognition of our continuing
respect for regional differences in
market design, we believe that, if there
are specific concerns about the market
designs in a particular region, they
should be considered, in the first
instance, at the regional level. We
therefore direct each RTO or ISO to
provide a forum for affected consumers
to voice specific concerns (and to
propose regional solutions) to the issues
raised generically by APPA and AARP,
et al. Although most existing
stakeholder processes already allow for
the submission of such proposals, we
encourage RTOs and ISOs to give
priority to any significant concerns that
may be raised on these issues, including
concerns as to the value to the market
of significant changes to the market
rules. For example, PJM recently has
conducted a series of forums on longterm contracts to gather information and
facilitate the exchange of ideas on this
important issue. We encourage similar
efforts on the concerns raised by APPA
and AARP, et al. Any proposed
solutions should be vetted through the
stakeholder process and ultimately
considered by the boards of the RTOs or
ISOs. Ultimately, such matters may be
brought to the Commission after
consideration by the region. We
encourage each region to commence the
consideration of any such issues in the
near future and not await the issuance
of a final rule in this proceeding.
25. However, those entities that have
such concerns have a responsibility to
propose solutions to address those
concerns. For example, American Forest
submitted comments that contained a
mechanism, the Financial Performance
Obligation (FPO), to address concerns
that they raised regarding the structure
of organized markets. Portland Cement
Association, et al., also included a
proposed solution in its comments to
address their concerns regarding the
organized markets. We are encouraged
by entities that actually propose
solutions rather than merely identify
concerns without proposing any
meaningful ways to address those
concerns. While we do not adopt these
proposals in this proceeding, we believe
that they warrant additional
consideration. Therefore, as explained
below, we direct Staff to convene a
technical conference regarding the
American Forest and Portland Cement
Association, et al., proposals so that the
Commission and the industry can learn
23 Notice of Technical Conference,
Interconnection Queuing Practices, Docket No.
AD08–2–000 (November 2, 2007).
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
more about the proposals and the merit
of adopting such changes where
appropriate.
IV. Discussion
A. Demand Response and Pricing
During Periods of Operating Reserve
Shortages in Organized Markets
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
26. This section of the NOPR proposes
several reforms to further eliminate
barriers to demand response in
organized energy markets. These
reforms must ensure that demand
response is treated comparably to other
resources. The Commission proposes to
require RTOs and ISOs to: (1) Accept
bids from demand response resources in
their markets for certain ancillary
services, comparable to other resources;
(2) eliminate, during a system
emergency, certain charges to buyers in
the energy market for voluntarily
reducing demand; and (3) permit ARCs
to bid demand response on behalf of
retail customers directly into the RTO’s
or ISO’s organized markets.24 We also
propose that RTOs and ISOs modify
their rules governing price formation
during periods of operating reserve
shortage. These proposals, if adopted,
would require market rules to ensure
that demand response can participate
directly and is treated comparably to
supply resources in the organized
electric energy and ancillary services
markets. We also propose to require that
each RTO and ISO study further reforms
to address any remaining barriers to
ensure that demand response is treated
comparably to other resources and to
report to the Commission within six
months of the date of the final rule in
this proceeding. In addition, we propose
that each RTO or ISO must adopt
reasonable standards necessary for
system operators to call on demand
response resources, and mechanisms to
measure, verify, and ensure compliance
with any such standards.25 As discussed
further below, we intend to direct staff
to convene a technical conference to
explore issues that the RTOs and ISOs
should include as part of these studies.
The specific reforms being proposed
here are therefore the next step in
removing barriers to demand response,
but not the final step.
24 We will use the phrase ‘‘aggregation of retail
customers’’ to refer to parties that aggregate demand
response bids (which are mostly from retail loads),
or ARCs.
25 We understand that some RTOs and ISOs may
already be developing measurement and
verification requirements, as well as appropriate
mechanisms to ensure compliance. It is not our
intention that these programs be delayed based on
our proposals here.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
1. Background
27. The Commission has expressed
the view on numerous occasions that
the wholesale electric power market
works best when demand can respond
to the wholesale price.26 Based on the
view that the value to customers of
electric power varies,27 the
Commission’s policy is to eliminate
barriers to the participation of demand
response in the organized power
markets, in part because demand
response helps to hold down wholesale
power prices; increases awareness of
energy usage; provides for more efficient
operation of markets; mitigates market
power; enhances reliability; and
encourages new technologies that
support the use of renewable energy
resources, distributed generation, and
advanced metering. The reforms we
propose today would further facilitate
demand response by removing several
barriers to demand response. This will
benefit customers of electric energy
because increased demand response
will improve price signals and provide
for greater flexibility. We provide
background on the benefits of demand
response and prior Commission actions
addressing demand response below.
a. Importance of Demand Response to
Competition in RTO/ISO Areas
28. A well-functioning competitive
wholesale electric market should reflect
current supply and demand conditions.
Enabling demand-side responses, as
well as supply-side resources, improves
the economic operation of electric
power markets by aligning prices more
closely with the value customers place
on electric power.
29. Demand response helps to reduce
prices in competitive wholesale markets
in at least three ways. First, demand
response has both a direct effect and an
indirect effect on wholesale demand.
The direct effect occurs when demand
response is bid directly into the
wholesale market: lower demand means
a lower wholesale price. Demand
response at retail, if not bid directly into
the wholesale market by a retail
customer, affects the wholesale market
indirectly because it reduces the need
for power by the retail customers’ LSE
26 New England Power Pool and ISO New
England, Inc., 101 FERC ¶ 61,344, at P 44–49
(2002), order on reh’g, 103 FERC ¶ 61,304, order on
reh’g, 105 FERC ¶ 61,211 (2003); PJM
Interconnection, LLC, 95 FERC ¶ 61,306 (2001); PJM
Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ¶ 61,227 (2002);
Southwest Power Pool, Inc., 116 FERC ¶ 61,289
(2006).
27 That is, for two customers at the same time and
place, one customer may prefer to reduce
consumption if the price is high, and the other may
be willing to pay a high price to avoid curtailment
in an emergency.
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12581
and in turn reduces that LSE’s need to
purchase power from the wholesale
market.28
30. Second, demand response tends to
flatten an area’s load profile. The
combination of reductions in peak
demand and a shift of at least a portion
of this peak demand to non-peak
periods due to demand response would
tend to make peak and off-peak demand
less divergent—a flatter load profile. A
flatter load profile would reduce the
need to use the more costly resources
during periods of high demand, which
tends to shift the distribution of
resource types toward lower-cost base
load generation and away from highercost peaking generation. This effect
tends to lower the overall average cost
to produce energy.29
31. Third, demand response can help
reduce generator market power. As more
demand response generally is available
during peak periods, power suppliers
need to account more for the price
responsiveness of load when they
consider submitting higher-price bids.
The more demand response is able to
reduce the peak price, the more
downward pressure it places on
generator bidding strategies by
increasing the risk to a supplier that it
will not be dispatched if it bids too
high.30
b. Prior Commission Actions To
Address Demand Response
32. The Commission has issued
numerous orders over the last several
years on various aspects of electric
demand response in organized markets.
A goal of most of these orders was to
remove unnecessary obstacles to
demand response participating in the
wholesale power markets of RTOs and
ISOs.31
33. These orders approved various
types of demand response programs,
including programs to allow demand
response to be used as a capacity
resource 32 and as a resource during
28 See Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
Assessment of Demand Response and Advanced
Metering: Staff Report, Docket No. AD06–2–000, at
11 (August 8, 2006) (2006 FERC Staff Demand
Response Assessment).
29 Id.
30 Id. at 12.
31 See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc.,
92 FERC ¶ 61,073, order on clarification, 92 FERC
¶ 61,181 (2000), order on reh’g, 97 FERC ¶ 61,154
(2001); New England Power Pool and ISO New
England, Inc., 100 FERC ¶ 61,287, order on reh’g,
101 FERC ¶ 61,344 (2002), order on reh’g, 103 FERC
¶ 61,304, order on reh’g, 105 FERC ¶ 61,211 (2003);
PJM Interconnection, LLC, 95 FERC ¶ 61,306 (2001);
PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ¶ 61,139 (2002);
PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ¶ 61,227 (2002).
32 See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, LLC, 117 FERC
¶ 61,331 (2006); Devon Power LLC, 115 FERC
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
Continued
07MRP2
12582
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
system emergencies,33 to allow
wholesale buyers and qualifying large
retail buyers to bid demand response
directly into the day-ahead and realtime energy markets and certain
ancillary service markets, particularly as
a provider of operating reserves, as well
as programs to accept bids from ARCs.34
The Commission also has approved
special demand response applications
such as use of demand response for
synchronized reserves and regulation
service.35 The theme underlying the
Commission’s approval of these
programs has been to allow demand
response resources to participate in
these markets on a basis that is
comparable to other resources.
34. The Commission has approved
programs that allow smaller retail
customers—that cannot individually
meet the RTO or ISO minimum bid size
threshold—to combine individual
demand response into a larger block for
bidding into the organized markets, if
permitted by state law, without having
to go through their LSE.36 A third-party
ARC, often called a curtailment service
provider, typically provides this
aggregation service. The aggregate
demand response may be bid directly
into the energy and ancillary services
markets.
35. In addition, the Commission has
explicitly addressed demand response
in its recent Final Rules on OATT
Reform (Order No. 890) and reliability
standards (Order No. 693).37 Order No.
890 requires any public utility with an
OATT to allow qualified demand
response resources to participate in its
regional transmission planning process
on a comparable basis to generation
resources and to allow qualified
demand response to provide certain
ancillary services. Specifically, the
¶ 61,340, order on reh’g, 117 FERC ¶ 61,133 (2006),
appeal pending sub nom. Maine Pub. Utils.
Comm’n v. FERC, No. 06–1403 (DC Cir. 2007).
33 See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc.,
95 FERC ¶ 61,136 (2001); NSTAR Services Co. v.
New England Power Pool, 95 FERC ¶ 61,250 (2001);
New England Power Pool and ISO New England,
Inc., 100 FERC ¶ 61,287, order on reh’g, 101 FERC
¶ 61,344 (2002), order on reh’g, 103 FERC ¶ 61,304,
order on reh’g, 105 FERC ¶ 61,211 (2003); PJM
Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ¶ 61,139 (2002).
34 See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc.,
95 FERC ¶ 61,223 (2001); New England Power Pool
and ISO New England, Inc., 100 FERC ¶ 61,287,
order on reh’g, 101 FERC ¶ 61,344 (2002), order on
reh’g, 103 FERC ¶ 61,304, order on reh’g, 105 FERC
¶ 61,211 (2003); PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC
¶ 61,227 (2002).
35 See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, LLC, 114 FERC
¶ 61,201 (2006).
36 Supra note 34.
37 See Mandatory Reliability Standards for the
Bulk-Power System, Order No. 693, 72 FR 16,416
(April 4, 2007), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,242, order
on reh’g, Order No. 693–A, 120 FERC ¶ 61,053
(2007).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
Commission agreed with Alcoa’s request
that load resources (i.e., demand
response) should be permitted to selfsupply and sell ancillary services to
third parties.38 In doing so, the
Commission also made clear that a
transmission provider may use nongeneration resources in meeting its
OATT obligation to provide ancillary
services, so long as those resources are
capable of providing the service.39
Order No. 693 requires the Electricity
Reliability Organization to revise its
reliability standards so that all
technically feasible resource options,
including demand response and
generating resources, may be employed
in the management of grid operations
and emergencies.40
36. The Commission has also worked
closely with state regulators to examine
demand response issues. The NARUC–
FERC Collaborative Dialogue on
Demand Response began in November
2006 to explore state-federal
coordination of efforts to promote and
integrate demand response into retail
and wholesale markets. The
Commission has conducted several
technical conferences on demand
response over the last several years,
most recently on April 23, 2007.41 In
addition, as mentioned, in response to
a requirement of EPAct 2005 42 to assess
demand response capability nationally,
in August 2006 the Commission
published a staff report on demand
response and advanced metering.43 In
September 2007, the Commission
published its second annual staff report
on demand response and advanced
metering.44
38 Order No. 890, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,241 at
P 887–88.
39 E.g., Order No. 890, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,241 at OATT Schedule 5 (Operating Reserve—
Spinning Reserve Service). Order No. 890 does not
require transmission providers, however, to
purchase ancillary services from non-generation
resources or generation resources.
40 Order No. 693 directed the Electricity
Reliability Organization to develop new versions of
its BAL–002, BAL–005, and EOP–002 reliability
standards to allow demand side resources to
provide contingency reserves. Order No. 693, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,242 at P 330–35, 404–06, 573.
41 For example, the Commission conducted a
technical conference on January 25, 2006 to help
prepare for a survey and a staff report on demand
response in Docket No. AD06–2–000. See supra
note 28. The April 23, 2007 conference was
convened in Docket No. AD07–11–000.
42 Public Law No. 109–58, § 1252(e)(3), 119 Stat.
594, 966 (2005).
43 See 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment.
44 See Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
2007 Assessment of Demand Response and
Advanced Metering: Staff Report, (September 2007)
(2007 FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment).
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
2. The Need for Commission Action
37. While the Commission and the
various RTOs and ISOs have done much
to eliminate barriers to demand
response in organized power markets,
more needs to be done to ensure
comparable treatment of all resources.
The 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment estimated the total installed
demand response capability from
existing programs nationally to be
37,500 MWs, or about five percent of
current peak demand.45 Several reports
indicate that the potential demand
response capability available in the
United States may be much greater.46
38. The Commission’s policy is to
eliminate barriers to the participation of
demand response in the organized
power markets by ensuring comparable
treatment of resources. This position is
consistent with EPAct 2005, which
states that demand response shall be
encouraged and unnecessary barriers to
demand response participation in
energy, capacity, and ancillary service
markets shall be eliminated.47 The
Commission can take additional steps to
further encourage demand response to
improve the operation of the organized
energy and ancillary services markets by
removing several unnecessary barriers
to demand response participation.48
39. The Commission can further
eliminate barriers to the participation of
demand response in certain ancillary
services markets. Some forms of
demand response are well suited to
provide the ancillary services of
spinning reserves, supplemental
45 2006
FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment
at 7.
46 See, e.g., Ahmad Faruqui et al., The Brattle
Group, The Power of Five Percent: How Dynamic
Pricing Can Save $35 Billion in Electricity Costs
(May 16, 2007), available at https://
www.brattle.com/_documents/UploadLibrary/
Upload574.pdf.
47 Section 1252(f) of the EPAct 2005 states that,
‘‘[i]t is the policy of the United States that timebased pricing and other forms of demand response
whereby electricity customers are provided with
electricity price signals and the ability to benefit by
responding to them, shall be encouraged, the
deployment of such technology and devices that
enable electricity customers to participate in such
pricing and demand response systems shall be
facilitated, and unnecessary barriers to demand
response participation in energy, capacity, and
ancillary service markets shall be eliminated.’’
48 We note that while the Commission can remove
some obstacles to demand participation in
organized markets, more effective demand response
also requires the action of state commissions. An
effective way for demand to respond to price is at
the retail level, through some form of time-based
retail rates (e.g., rates that vary by hour, such as
real-time pricing, or by blocks of time, such as timeof-use rates or critical peak pricing). Demand
response is more effective when retail rates are tied
to current wholesale market-clearing prices.
Effective demand response can be achieved by
linking the wholesale and retail markets.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
reserves, energy imbalance, and
regulation and frequency response.49
Because demand is always connected
and demand response, in principle, can
always be available, some forms of
demand response resources may be able
to provide a rapid, near real-time
response.50 Nevertheless, not all RTOs
and ISOs allow demand response to
participate in ancillary services markets.
ISO–NE, NYISO, and CAISO allow
demand response resources to provide
supplemental (non-spinning) reserves.
As of mid-2007, only PJM allows
demand response resources to provide
synchronized reserves (PJM’s term for
spinning reserves) and regulation
service.51
40. In Order No. 890, the Commission
modified the definitions of certain
ancillary services in the pro forma open
access transmission tariff to clarify that
demand response is eligible to supply
these ancillary services on a comparable
basis to generation resources. Order No.
890 concluded, however, that
procurement and pricing of ancillary
services—including issues related to
competitive procurement—were beyond
the scope of that rulemaking. Though
RTOs and ISOs procure ancillary
services through competitive market
means, they are not currently required
to accept bids from qualified demand
response providers to provide ancillary
services even if those providers are
technically capable of doing so. This
hinders the integration of qualified
demand response resources into these
RTO and ISO ancillary services markets.
41. One reason for the lack of
participation of demand response in
some ancillary service markets may be
that market rules for bidding and
participating in ancillary services
markets were developed with generation
in mind and may not accommodate
demand response resources. For
example, many demand response
resources can respond quickly and at a
low cost if called upon for a short
duration, which may make them well
suited for providing operating reserves.
If market rules require, however, that a
single bid be made into a joint energyplus-reserves market (also known as a
‘‘co-optimized’’ market), those seeking
to offer operating reserves risk being
dispatched to provide energy or other
49 See 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment at 51. For an explanation of each of
these ancillary services, see the pro forma OATT,
Schedules 3 through 6, contained in Order No. 890.
50 For example, electric-arc steel furnaces have
the capability to adjust their consumption rapidly,
and air conditioner cycling programs can respond
within several minutes of execution.
51 We note, however, that no resource has yet
qualified to provide this service to PJM.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
ancillary services for which they are not
well suited. As a result, a potential
operating reserve provider that does not
wish to be called upon frequently or for
a prolonged period in the energy market
may simply decide not to participate in
a co-optimized market, and
consequently not be a source for
providing demand response resources as
operating reserves. Market rules that do
not allow a demand response provider
to limit the frequency and duration of
interruption may thereby create a
disincentive for a demand response
resource to bid into the operating
reserves market.52
42. Further, demand response
providers need market rules that allow
bids to be flexible and that reflect
bidders’ willingness to offer various
levels of service depending on the
market prices. While the design of
today’s organized markets does allow
some flexible and some price-sensitive
bidding into day-ahead and real-time
energy markets, the Commission is
nevertheless concerned that some
market features may inhibit LSEs and
other demand response providers from
bidding load reductions into energy
markets. For example, in most organized
markets, if an LSE’s actual purchase
from the real-time market differs from
the purchase it scheduled in the dayahead market, it may be assessed an
uplift charge (separate from any
imbalance charge). This uplift charge
recovers certain costs of extra generation
when day-ahead purchases exceed realtime purchases. However, these costs
may be minimal during an emergency
when there is no extra generation.
Further, this uplift charge may
unnecessarily discourage an LSE from
urging retail customers to conserve
energy during a system emergency. RTO
and ISO tariffs also do not impose these
types of charges on generators that
generate more power during system
emergencies than scheduled.
Eliminating this uplift charge for
demand response sought by RTOs or
ISOs from buyers in an emergency
removes a disincentive for this demand
response and promotes comparable
treatment of demand and supply
resources.
43. Organized energy market rules
also may restrict the type of bid that a
LSE or ARC may submit.53 There is
usually a minimum bid size threshold
52 See 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment at 123.
53 In some cases, this may be intended to treat a
demand response resource bid the same as a
generation bid, but more often, bidding features
available to generation, such as a guaranteed
minimum price, are not available to demand
response resources.
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12583
in an RTO or ISO market. Also, it is
hard for some demand response
providers to participate if, for example,
they are not able to start and stop
frequently or if cycling output up and
down produces excessive stress on their
equipment. Aggregation programs can
improve the participation of small retail
loads that lack standing as an LSE or
individually cannot meet a requirement
that a demand response bid be of
minimum size. These programs allow a
larger number of customers to access
demand response programs, which
increases the potential market and
reliability benefits realized from
demand response in wholesale markets.
The 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment and comments that we have
received indicate, however, that more
needs to be done to facilitate the direct
participation of ARCs in energy markets.
44. Another factor that may limit
participation in demand response
programs is the use of bid caps and
price caps in wholesale market design.
Bid caps and price caps in RTO and ISO
markets are designed to limit the
opportunity to exercise market power in
these markets, but they also may
prevent the markets from expressing
prices that are legitimately high due to
a shortage. These caps may not permit
buyers in RTO and ISO wholesale
energy markets to see prices high
enough to signal that there is a period
of operating reserve shortage and that
reliability is at risk. Moreover, when
power is in short supply and price is
high, retail prices remain fixed, and
retail customers do not adjust their
demand to react to wholesale price
signals. Consequently, both generation
and demand response can be in short
supply at once, and the market-clearing
price may not reflect the actual cost of
providing more power or the value to
customers of not being interrupted.
Further, as discussed in the long-term
contracting section below, capping the
exposure of LSEs to higher prices may
reduce their incentive to explore various
hedging activities, such as participating
in interruptible demand response
programs, entering into long-term
contracts or similar power supply
procurement options, and building new
generating units.
45. Certain demand response
programs may themselves act to dampen
prices during a period of operating
reserve shortage. The term ‘‘emergency
demand response program’’ is used here
to refer to a demand response program
where participants agree to reduce
demand if called on by the RTO or ISO
during a system emergency. They may
be paid a fixed price rather than the
market-clearing price when called on.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12584
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
As a result, the market-clearing price
may decrease because demand is
reduced when an emergency demand
response resource is used, even though
that resource is the highest-valued
resource used at the time. The reduced
price is contrary to the signal that
should be sent in an emergency. Only
NYISO has integrated its emergency
demand response programs into the
market-clearing process.54
3. Proposed Reforms
46. In order to further eliminate
barriers to demand response in
organized markets, the Commission
proposes reforms to obligate RTOs and
ISOs to: (1) Accept bids from demand
response resources in its markets for
certain ancillary services, comparable to
any other resources; (2) eliminate,
during a system emergency, a charge to
a buyer in the energy market for taking
less electric energy in the real-time
market than purchased in the day-ahead
market; (3) permit an ARC to bid a
demand response on behalf of retail
customers directly into the RTO’s or
ISO’s organized energy markets, unless
the laws or regulations of the relevant
electric retail regulatory authority do
not permit a retail customer to
participate; and (4) modify their market
rules to allow the market-clearing price
to accurately reflect the value of energy
during periods of operating reserve
shortage. The Commission also proposes
to require RTOs and ISOs to study
whether further reforms are necessary to
eliminate barriers to demand response
in organized markets. We believe that
these proposals ensure comparable
treatment of demand response
resources. We discuss these proposals in
greater detail below.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
9. Ancillary Services Provided by
Demand Response Resources
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
47. In the ANOPR, the Commission
sought comment on obligating RTOs
and ISOs to purchase demand response
resources in their markets for certain
ancillary services, similar to any other
resources, if the resources meet the
necessary technical requirements and
submit a bid under the generallyapplicable bidding rules at or below the
market-clearing price. The Commission
contemplated granting an exception
where the seller would not be permitted
to do so by state retail laws or
regulations. The Commission proposed
to require modifications to RTO and ISO
tariffs that would apply this
54 The Commission approved this change in 2003.
New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 102 FERC
¶ 61,313 (2003).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
requirement for energy imbalance,
spinning reserves, and supplemental
reserves, as defined in the pro forma
OATT, or their functional equivalents in
an RTO or ISO tariff. To be eligible to
supply these ancillary services, the
Commission stated that demand
response resources must be capable of
reducing demand within seconds or
minutes and must meet the RTO’s or
ISO’s reasonable size, telemetry,
metering, and bidding requirements.
48. The Commission also sought
comment on requiring modifications to
RTO and ISO tariffs to provide that
demand response resources must be
allowed to provide spinning and
supplemental reserves without also
being required to sell into the energy
market.
49. The Commission requested
comment on, among other things,
whether each RTO or ISO should
propose its own minimum requirements
(for example, as to minimum size bids,
measurement, and telemetry) or whether
the Commission should specify the
appropriate minimum requirements in a
Commission rule.
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
50. Most of the commenters that
address the Commission’s proposal in
the ANOPR support having an RTO or
ISO accept bids from demand response
resources for certain ancillary services
on a comparable basis. For example,
BlueStar Energy states that the
Commission’s proposal ‘‘will lead to
greater economic efficiency, and reduce
costs and risks for retail customers.’’ 55
Industrial Coalitions states that the
Commission’s current proposal is the
next logical step, after Order No. 890, in
promoting the integration of demand
response resources into all RTO- and
ISO-coordinated markets and services.56
51. Other commenters raise concerns
with the ability of smaller entities to
fully participate as resource providers
for ancillary services. APPA argues that
it may be difficult to reconcile the
technical requirements for end users,
necessitated by the instantaneous nature
of certain ancillary services, with the
desire of many larger loads for
reliability, flexibility, and convenience,
thus making it unlikely that many
demand response resources will want to
provide ancillary services.57 The
California PUC argues that requiring
demand response resources to satisfy all
requirements for service provision
comparable to those applied to supply
55 BlueStar
Energy at 2.
Coalitions at 13–14.
57 APPA at 48.
56 Industrial
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
resources could construct considerable
barriers to participation of small
demand response resources.58
52. NYISO and National Grid support
the participation of demand response to
the extent practical in the ancillary
services market. They request, however,
that the Commission clarify that it
would not require the RTO or ISO to
‘‘purchase’’ certain ancillary services
from demand response resources but to
accept bids from them.59
53. Multiple commenters supported
the Commission’s proposal to allow
demand response resources to provide
reserves without being required to sell
into the energy market. Alcoa, for
example, states that demand-responsive
load supplying ancillary services does
not create market power concerns
because such services are not the
primary business of demand response
resources.60 Strategic Energy states that
the proposal would allow customers to
offer operating reserves without
disrupting the company business via
prolonged shutdowns to satisfy an
energy schedule.61
54. Conversely, several commenters
oppose the Commission’s proposal.
ISO–NE does not support the proposal
because its core market design does not
allow separate bids to be placed in the
energy and reserve markets for any
resources.62 NYISO concurs, claiming
that the proposal would not be efficient
in New York because NYISO’s market
design co-optimizes energy and
ancillary services through an integrated
dispatch process and generators in New
York must make themselves available to
supply energy in order to be eligible to
supply ancillary services.63 Thus, any
change to NYISO’s market design could
lead to inefficient scheduling outcomes.
NYISO does state, however, that its
existing bidding procedures are flexible
enough to permit demand response
resources to structure their bids in a
way that virtually eliminates the
possibility that they may be selected to
provide energy involuntarily. NYISO
asserts that it could develop new
bidding rules that would allow demand
response resources to specify that they:
(1) Could not be called on for more than
an hour or a certain maximum number
of times per day; or (2) would be subject
to energy management limits. NYISO
asserts that such rules would allow
demand side resources to convey their
limitations on frequency and duration of
58 California
PUC at 7.
at 28; National Grid at 5.
60 Alcoa at 18–19.
61 Strategic Energy at 4.
62 ISO–NE at 19.
63 NYISO at 32.
59 NYISO
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
activation without undermining the cooptimized market design.
55. A majority of commenters assert
that the Commission should allow RTOs
and ISOs to develop their own
minimum requirements for demand
response participation in ancillary
services markets. EEI states that the
Commission recognized that the various
organized markets and state regulatory
programs are different and had different
physical and state requirements.64
Dominion Resources, Pepco, PGC,
PG&E, and SPP agree. EEI further argues
that given all the regional differences in
control systems and market software,
having a standardized set of
requirements may result in unnecessary
expense and delay in implementation in
certain regions by requiring
incompatible infrastructure. PGC claims
that a ‘‘one-size fits all’’ minimum
requirements rule would be
inappropriate, and states that allowing
each RTO or ISO region to establish its
own requirements would permit each
system the flexibility to modify
requirements as they gain additional
experience with demand response
resources.65 Pepco argues for RTO/ISOestablished technical requirements
because the types of generation
resources available, transmission
constraints, and load pattern
characteristics for each region would all
be taken into account, and would be
appropriate for that region.66
iii. Commission Proposal
56. The Commission proposes to
obligate each RTO or ISO to accept bids
from demand response resources, on a
basis comparable to any other resources,
for ancillary services that are acquired
in a competitive bidding process, if the
demand response resources (1) are
technically capable of providing the
ancillary service and meet the necessary
technical requirements, and (2) submit a
bid under the generally-applicable
bidding rules at or below the marketclearing price, unless the laws or
regulations of the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority do not permit a
retail customer to participate. This
proposal would apply to competitivelybid markets, if any, for energy
imbalance, spinning reserves,
supplemental reserves, reactive supply
and voltage control, and regulation and
frequency response as defined in the pro
forma OATT, or to the markets of their
functional equivalents in an RTO or ISO
tariff. We propose that demand response
resources that are capable of reducing
64 EEI
at 12.
at 10–11.
66 Pepco at 7.
65 PGC
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
demand within the response time
requirement for the ancillary service
and that meet reasonable requirements
adopted by the RTO or ISO as to size,
telemetry, metering, and bidding be
eligible to supply energy imbalance,
spinning reserves, supplemental
reserves, reactive and voltage control,
and regulation and frequency response.
In the compliance filing to be submitted
within six months of the final rule, the
RTO or ISO must adopt reasonable
standards necessary for system
operators to call on demand response
resources, and mechanisms to measure,
verify, and ensure compliance with any
such standards. Such standards would
be subject to Commission approval.
57. We believe that this policy would
increase the competitiveness of
ancillary services markets, help reduce
the price of ancillary services, and
improve the reliability of the grid.
Experience in the PJM, CAISO, and
ERCOT markets has demonstrated that
certain demand response resources can
provide some ancillary services reliably.
Moreover, this proposal would require
that, for ancillary services acquired in a
competitive process, RTOs and ISOs
make any necessary changes to their
tariffs and market rules to allow for
direct demand response resource
participation in the ancillary services
markets.
58. We clarify, in response to NYISO’s
and National Grid’s requests, that this
proposal would not require an RTO or
ISO to purchase certain ancillary
services from demand response
resources, but rather to accept bids from
them for ancillary services acquired in
a competitive bidding process, and if
they meet minimum technical
requirements and clear the market, on a
basis comparable to other resources. The
purpose of the proposal is to ensure that
all RTOs and ISOs treat demand
response resources comparably with
other resources in the market rules for
energy imbalance, spinning reserves,
supplemental reserves, reactive and
voltage control, and regulation and
frequency response. This proposal does
not require the adoption of a
competitive bidding process where one
was previously not utilized.
59. The California PUC’s argument
that ancillary services market rules for
comparable and nondiscriminatory
access for demand response resources
may be a barrier to participation of
small demand response resources has
merit. Experiments and pilot programs
suggest that resources below minimum
size thresholds in RTO and ISO markets
have the potential to respond quickly
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12585
and reliably.67 Adjusting minimum size
thresholds and telemetry requirements
to accommodate smaller demand
response resources may result in a
significant increase in potential sources
of operating reserves. Without extensive
experience with the ability of smaller
demand response resources to provide
ancillary services, however, it is
premature to mandate specific
conditions under which RTOs and ISOs
must accommodate smaller resources
into the spinning reserves,
supplemental reserves, energy
imbalance markets, reactive and voltage
control, and regulation and frequency
response. Instead, we propose to direct
the RTOs and ISOs to perform an
assessment of the technical feasibility
and value to the market of smaller loads
providing some ancillary services one
year from the effective date of the final
rule, including whether (and how)
smaller resources can reliably and
economically provide operating reserves
through pilot projects or other
mechanisms.68
60. In the ANOPR, the Commission
made a preliminary proposal to remove
a disincentive for demand response to
offer operating reserves. The proposal
was to modify RTO and ISO tariffs to
provide that demand resources must be
allowed to provide spinning and
supplemental reserves without also
being required to sell into the energy
market, explaining that customers may
be more likely to offer demand response
as operating reserves if they do not need
to worry about disruptions to their
businesses by participating in the
energy markets. We are sympathetic,
however, to concerns raised in ISO–
NE’s and NYISO’s comments that the
ANOPR proposal could undo their
recent success in resolving design
problems of disjointed markets by
combining and co-optimizing their
energy and ancillary services markets.
The Commission is mindful of these
concerns and does not intend to
negatively affect the market efficiencies
created by co-optimized market designs.
61. NYISO suggests, however, that the
development of new bidding rules could
limit the exposure of demand response
resources selling into the energy
market—rules that would not require
changes to its co-optimized markets.
Resource bids in RTO and ISO markets
typically allow bidders to specify
various parameters of their bid (e.g.,
price, quantity, startup and no-load
67 See 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment at 114.
68 For example, ISO–NE is assessing whether
small demand response resources can provide
operating reserves in its Demand Response Reserves
Pilot.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
12586
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
comply with the proposed requirement
or demonstrate that its existing tariff
and market design already satisfy the
requirement. This filing would be
submitted within six months of the date
the final rule is published in the Federal
Register. The Commission will assess
whether each filing satisfies the
proposed requirement and will issue
additional orders as necessary.
64. We request comment on this
proposed requirement for RTOs and
ISOs to allow demand response
resources to specify a maximum
duration for dispatch, a maximum
number of times per day that demand
response resources could be called, or a
maximum amount of energy per day or
week, and on whether other bidding
parameters should be considered. We
note that any parameters must
accommodate the characteristics of
demand response resources but must
not have the effect of creating an undue
preference for demand response
`
resources vis-a-vis other resources.
Further, we intend that the bidding
parameters would be implemented at all
RTOs and ISOs. Finally, we agree with
commenters that it would not be
appropriate for the Commission to
develop in a rulemaking a standardized
set of minimum requirements for
minimum size bids, measurement,
telemetry, and other factors. Instead, we
will allow each RTO or ISO to develop
its own minimum requirements,
including bidding parameters. We
propose to require the RTOs and ISOs
confer with each other and to provide a
technical and factual basis for any
necessary regional variations.
costs, and minimum downtime between
starts). NYISO suggests new parameters
that would allow demand response
bidders to specify additional constraints
on the dispatch of their resources. In its
comments, NYISO offers that a demand
response bidder could specify the
maximum duration in hours that a bid
can be dispatched, maximum number of
times that a bid can be dispatched
during a day, and a maximum amount
of energy that a resource can produce
either daily or weekly, and that those
parameters could be incorporated into
the bidding rules. We believe that
NYISO’s suggestion has merit.
62. We propose here to require RTOs
and ISOs to allow demand response
resources to specify limits on the
frequency and duration of their service
in their bids to provide ancillary
services—or their bids into the joint
energy-ancillary services market in the
co-optimized RTO markets. These limits
are comparable to the limits generators
may specify on price, quantity, startup
and no-load costs, and minimum
downtime between starts—limits that
may not be available to demand
response resources. The proposal is for
RTOs and ISOs to incorporate new
parameters into their bidding rules that
allow demand response resources to
specify a maximum duration in hours
that the demand response resource may
be dispatched, a maximum number of
times that the demand response
resource may be dispatched during a
day, and a maximum amount of electric
energy that the demand response
resource may be required to provide
either daily or weekly. We expect that
this requirement would encourage
demand response in the spinning
reserves, supplemental reserves, and
regulation and frequency response
markets by reducing the risk that
demand response resources would be
called on too frequently or for too long
a period. We ask for comment on
whether these new parameters should
be available for all bids, not just demand
response resources. These new bidding
parameters could benefit energy-limited
resources or runtime-limited resources,
e.g., hydropower and units with
environmental restrictions. The new
bidding parameters could also benefit
resources that cannot start and stop
quickly. The proposal should not
require fundamental changes to existing
market designs,69 or affect the
efficiencies of co-optimized markets.
63. An RTO or ISO must either
propose amendments to its tariff to
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
65. In the ANOPR, the Commission
stated that it was considering a proposal
to modify RTO and ISO tariffs to
eliminate, during a system emergency, a
charge to a buyer in the energy market
for taking less electric energy in the realtime market than purchased in the dayahead market.70
66. The Commission requested
comment on whether an RTO or ISO
should assess a deviation charge for a
day-ahead to real-time load reduction in
the absence of a system emergency. The
Commission noted that eliminating the
deviation charge might have unintended
consequences and asked whether it
would result in an unfair reallocation of
these costs to others; whether it was
important to retain the deviation charge
to discourage poor scheduling practices;
69 Bidding rules at RTOs and ISOs such as
Midwest ISO and PJM already incorporate aspects
of these proposed new bidding parameters.
70 The Commission noted that it would refer to
the charge that it proposed to eliminate during an
emergency as a ‘‘deviation charge.’’
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
b. Deviation Charge
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
or whether eliminating the deviation
charge would introduce opportunities
for gaming behavior.
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
67. The vast majority of commenters
support the preliminary proposal in the
ANOPR to modify RTO and ISO tariffs
to eliminate a deviation charge during a
system emergency.71 For instance,
APPA asserts that it does not make
much sense to penalize entities that
help the RTO alleviate a system
emergency.72 SMUD states that
eliminating penalties for load
reductions during a system emergency
is a sensible approach to promoting
further development of demand
response as a resource eligible to be bid
into organized markets.73
68. Several supporters prefer allowing
RTOs and ISOs the flexibility to
establish rules for settling deviations.
For example, SoCal Edison-SDG&E
believe each RTO or ISO is different,
and that allowing each region to
determine specific deviation charges
based on individual circumstances may
make more sense than adopting uniform
standards. In their opinion, such an
approach would help mitigate any
unintended consequences, such as
gaming.74
69. Other commenters who disagree
with the Commission’s preliminary
proposal are concerned about the uplift
costs resulting from the elimination of
deviation charges. DC Energy argues
that eliminating the deviation charge
penalty for demand response
participants would negatively impact
the market and result in unfair cost
reallocation. 75 It maintains that such
elimination would create two classes of
market participants and have a
deleterious affect on the market by
inefficiently and unfairly reallocating
costs to others.
70. Two commenters raise concerns
about the applicability of the proposal
to virtual bidding.76 APPA and the
71 A number of commenters appear to
misunderstand the proposal. Several did not
distinguish a voluntary reduction in power
purchase between day-ahead and real time (the
intent here) from a demand response bidder that
fails to deliver its accepted demand response.
72 APPA at 53.
73 SMUD at 4.
74 SoCal Edison-SDG&E at 2–3.
75 DC Energy at 4.
76 Virtual bidding, sometimes called
‘‘convergence bidding,’’ involves sales or purchases
in the RTO or ISO day-ahead market that do not go
to physical delivery. For example, an entity that
does not serve load may make a purchase in the
day-ahead market, which it must pay for, and then
take no power in real time. This lack of
consumption is treated as a sale of the power in the
real-time spot market. By making virtual energy
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
Connecticut and Massachusetts
Municipals worry that virtual bidders
may engage in market manipulation.
Connecticut and Massachusetts
Municipals argue that virtual bidders’
virtual load in the day-ahead market
may create the appearance of a shortage
even without corresponding real-time
load. Therefore, the Commission should
tailor any deviation exemption to apply
to physical loads only.77 APPA agrees.78
71. Suppliers predominantly support
the Commission’s additional ANOPR
proposal to eliminate deviation charges
absent system emergencies. These
commenters argue that any load
reduction, during either a system
emergency or non-emergency, would
benefit all loads in RTOs and ISOs
through greater market efficiency. Other
commenters, including the RTOs and
ISOs, however, oppose this proposal.
Arguments against eliminating
deviation charges for non-emergency
periods include concerns about
potential gaming and inaccurate
scheduling. APPA states that in order to
ensure accurate schedules and cost
accountability, deviation charges should
remain in place absent a system
emergency.79 EEI argues that the
elimination of this charge during nonemergencies ‘‘sends the wrong price
signal to market participants, provides a
disincentive to minimize deviations,
and leads to increased costs to the
market.’’ 80 PJM states that little
reliability value is associated with load
reductions during non-emergencies, and
therefore waiving the deviation charges
is not justified, particularly when costs
would have to be collected through a
socialized uplift charge.81
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
iii. Commission Proposal
72. The Commission proposes to
require that all RTO and ISO tariffs be
modified to eliminate a charge, which
we refer to as a deviation charge,82 to a
buyer 83 in the energy market for taking
sales or purchases in the day-ahead market and
settling these positions in the real-time market, any
market participant can arbitrage price differences
between the two markets.
77 Connecticut and Massachusetts Municipals at
40.
78 APPA at 53.
79 Id. at 54.
80 EEI at 17–19.
81 PJM at 7–8.
82 Deviation charges recover certain costs
including importantly generators’ costs (such as
start-up costs) that exceed their energy market
revenues when real-time demand is less than
forecast. These ‘‘uplift’’ costs may include the cost
of the extra generators committed after the close of
the day-ahead market that are not recovered from
sales of energy at real-time LMPs.
83 Examples of buyers in RTO and ISO energy
markets include a load serving entity that purchases
electricity to meet the load requirements of its retail
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
less electric energy in the real-time
market during a real-time market period
for which the RTO or ISO declares an
operating reserve shortage or makes a
generic request to reduce load to avoid
an operating reserve shortage.
73. An RTO or ISO must either
propose amendments to its tariff to
comply with the proposed requirement
or demonstrate that its existing tariff
and market design already satisfy the
requirement to eliminate the deviation
charge during a system emergency. This
filing would be submitted within six
months of the date the final rule is
published in the Federal Register. The
Commission will assess whether each
filing satisfies the proposed requirement
and will issue additional orders as
necessary.
74. Commenters supporting this
proposal make sound arguments for it.
We agree that removal of this deviation
charge during a system emergency
would remove a disincentive for greater
demand response in the real-time
market. A buyer may be deterred from
reducing load during periods when
supplies are tight and the real-time price
is high if that buyer is subject to a
charge for reducing its real-time
consumption from its day-ahead
purchases. If that buyer takes the
appropriate action to reduce load and is
accordingly penalized by a deviation
charge, this unintended disincentive
may lead the buyer to maintain a high
load or discourage an LSE from calling
on the demand response capabilities of
its retail customers. Removal of this
disincentive is important during a
system emergency when load reduction
is needed (and valued) most.
75. RTO and ISO tariffs already
contain provisions associated with the
dispatch of generators during real time,
and specify payments and deviation
charges for uninstructed deviations.
During system emergencies, all available
generation resources are instructed to
increase output if possible. Because
these units are instructed to increase
output, RTO and ISO tariffs do not
impose deviation charges on generators
that generate more power during system
emergencies than scheduled.
Elimination of deviation charges for
demand response by buyers ensures
comparability between demand and
supply resources.
76. As noted above, although a
majority of commenters express support
for this proposal, a significant number
appear to misunderstand it. For
example, some commenters appear to
believe that the Commission proposed
customers or a retail customer that purchases
electricity directly from the wholesale market.
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12587
to remove any penalty for a day-ahead
bidder of demand response who fails to
reduce demand in real time, and oppose
this idea as discriminating in favor of a
demand response provider.
Accordingly, we provide two
clarifications. First, this proposal
applies to demand response that is in
addition to the demand response of
participants in RTO/ISO wholesale
demand response programs. If demand
response program participants reduce
demand as directed, RTOs and ISOs
already do not levy a deviation charge.
We are not proposing to remove any
penalty for a day-ahead bidder of
demand response who fails to follow
directions to reduce demand in real
time. This proposal focuses on demand
response from LSEs and other buyers
that consume less total energy in real
time during system emergencies than
they had scheduled in the day-ahead
market.84 Second, deviation charges
would be eliminated only when the
RTO or ISO announces an emergency
situation after the close of the day-ahead
market. The RTO or ISO could inform
buyers either by instituting formal
procedures that direct LSEs and electric
utilities to activate retail demand
response programs during a system
emergency or by requesting voluntary
load reductions, which may occur prior
to or at the same time that a system
emergency is declared. This is intended
to ensure that buyers are not penalized
when they voluntarily reduce load to
improve system reliability at the request
of a system operator.
77. In response to concerns that
eliminating the deviation charge during
a system emergency would result in an
unfair allocation of the uplift costs or
the creation of an unfair subsidy to
demand response, we recognize that a
deviation charge covers real costs to
generators and others. These costs
include those associated with the extra
generation committed after the close of
the day-ahead market that are not
recovered from sales of energy in real
time. Since demand response during
system emergencies can be instrumental
in maintaining system reliability and
reducing overall energy prices, the
Commission proposes that these costs
be allocated to all loads of the RTO or
ISO.
78. The Commission’s proposal to
eliminate deviation charges during a
system emergency applies to physical
load reductions. With regard to virtual
84 Note that under our proposal, if a demand
response program participant reduces demand at
greater levels than instructed during a system
emergency, it will not be subjected to a deviation
charge for the higher than instructed demand
response.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12588
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
purchases, we believe that, during an
emergency, these day-ahead purchases
may not cause unneeded generation to
be committed to the market because an
emergency by its nature is a time when
the system is short of generation. As a
result, we believe that virtual
purchasers may not cause significant
additional costs during an emergency.
Indeed, virtual purchases may enhance
reliability by increasing the amount of
generation resources available in real
time during a system emergency.
Assessing a deviation charge on virtual
purchasers during an emergency may be
unfair and may discourage helpful
virtual bidding. Some commenters
contend that virtual purchases add to
system costs but do not address whether
they add to costs during an emergency
situation when the system is short of
generation. The Commission seeks
comment on whether to require RTO
and ISO tariffs to be modified to
eliminate deviation charges for virtual
purchasers during system emergencies.
79. We do not propose to modify RTO
and ISO tariffs to eliminate deviation
charges absent a system emergency, in
light of the comments we received
regarding this ANOPR proposal. We are
concerned about the resulting
possibility of market manipulation and
inefficiencies if deviation charges are
removed, as raised by several
commenters. Given the reliability value
associated with demand response
during system emergencies,
socialization of related uplift costs is
supportable.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
c. Aggregation of Retail Customers
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
80. In the ANOPR the Commission
sought comment on requiring RTOs and
ISOs to amend their market rules as
necessary to permit an ARC to bid
demand response on behalf of retail
customers directly into the RTO’s or
ISO’s organized markets. Under the
preliminary proposal, the amended
market rules could not exclude a
demand response bid from a third-party
ARC that is not an LSE, unless state
laws or regulations do not permit this.
RTOs and ISOs would have the same
rules for ARC participation as for LSEs,
except as needed to comply with state
laws and regulations, unless the RTO or
ISO satisfactorily explained the reason
for any such difference. As part of the
preliminary proposal, the Commission
suggested directing RTOs and ISOs to
coordinate to identify common issues,
best practices, and market rules that are
consistent between regions, particularly
in the areas of market procedures,
bidding protocols, communication
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
protocols, and measurement and
verification, and having them report to
the Commission on their coordination
efforts.
81. The Commission also requested
comments on whether ARCs allow for
inappropriate compensation when a
retail customer is paid for wholesale
demand response and also saves in its
retail bill from the same demand
response. The Commission noted that
some argue that the payments to
customers for demand response are a
form of double payment that provides
an unjustified subsidy.
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
82. A large number of commenters
address at great length the proposal to
require an RTO to accept a demand
response bid into its energy market from
an ARC, if permitted by state law. A
majority—including such diverse
entities as EPSA, CAISO, and Industrial
Consumers—appears to support the
basic proposal although many raise
implementation concerns. Comments in
opposition to the proposal also vary
widely and represent a diversity of
interests, from SoCal Edison-SDG&E to
the Massachusetts Attorney General.
They offer a variety of reasons not to
require market rule changes, with most
concluding that this topic is a subject
better suited for detailed stakeholder
negotiations than a generic rulemaking.
State regulators generally like the state
law exemption, but several worry that
the program could have unintended
consequences and is inappropriate for
non-retail access states. Public power,
cooperatives, and other retail service
providers not regulated by state
commissions ask for clarification that an
RTO or ISO may not accept a bid from
an ARC that aggregates their customers
if their own retail regulations would not
permit this.85
83. Commenters identified multiple
benefits associated with ARCs. ARCs
provide valuable services to retail
customers by handling various tasks
such as developing demand response
action plans, handling event
notifications from system operators, and
managing payment.86 ARCs can reduce
the RTOs’ and ISOs’ administrative
burden of managing individual
customers’ demand response
participation.87 ARCs with risk and
portfolio management expertise can
manage a portfolio of diverse demand
response resources to achieve greater
85 APPA at 56; NRECA at 13; EEI at 19; AEP at
4–5; California Municipals at 8–9.
86 See Public Interest Organizations at 10.
87 See EnerNOC at 6.
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
value and reliability with the aggregated
demand response resource.88
84. RTOs and ISOs indicate that
standardization of several technical
issues may be beneficial. For example,
PJM notes that a few areas that can be
standardized, including (1) the method
for determining baseline consumption,
(2) the tools for establishing the uniform
baseline and measuring the demand
response, (3) the interface tools that
allow demand response providers to use
a common portal and protocol for
offering demand response into the
organized markets, and (4) the telemetry
and metering requirements.89 Several
commenters, however, express concern
that any rules for aggregation must be
tailored to the specific design of the
particular market and regional
circumstances. They argue that these
rules should not be developed in a
generic Commission rulemaking
process. Instead, the Commission
should allow these rules to be
developed by the RTO or ISO through
a regional stakeholder process.90
85. In response to ANOPR questions
about how much to compensate a
demand response aggregator for
reducing its consumption of electric
energy, voluminous comments were
received ranging from strong arguments
for paying the full market price to strong
arguments for avoiding ‘‘double
compensation.’’ Many commenters
oppose having a Commission regulation
setting a price to compensate for
allegedly incorrect retail prices. Several
point out that if retail customers faced
real-time market prices, a retail
aggregation program or any issue of
compensation would not be needed.
The commenters that want to see a
transition to retail customers paying
‘‘efficient’’ market prices do not want
permanent Commission regulations that
compensate for ‘‘inefficient’’ retail
prices.
iii. Commission Proposal
86. The Commission proposes to
require RTOs and ISOs to amend their
market rules as necessary to permit an
ARC to bid demand response on behalf
of retail customers directly into the
RTO’s or ISO’s organized markets,
unless the laws or regulations of the
relevant electric retail regulatory
authority do not permit a retail
customer to participate.
88 See, e.g., Energy Curtailment at 10–15;
EnerNOC at 6; Public Interest Organizations at 9–
10.
89 PJM at 9–10.
90 E.g., NY TO at 8; LPPC at 5–6; Kansas CC at
2–4; SoCal Edison-SDG&E at 3; Old Dominion at 9;
Massachusetts AG at 2–3; Northeast Utilities at 8.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
87. This proposal would reduce a
barrier to demand response by
permitting an ARC to act as an
intermediary for many small retail loads
that cannot individually participate in
the organized market. We agree with
commenters that aggregating small retail
customers into larger pools of resources
allows more customers to access
demand response programs, which
increases the potential market and
reliability benefits realized from
demand response in wholesale
markets.91 Experience with existing
aggregation programs in PJM, NYISO,
and ISO–NE has shown that these
programs increased demand
responsiveness in these regions.
88. In response to comments on the
ANOPR’s preliminary proposal, we offer
these clarifications of our proposal here.
The ARC’s demand response bid must
meet the same requirements as a
demand response bid from any other
entity, such as an LSE. The bidder only
has the opportunity to be among the
bids that clear the market; it does not
guarantee that the bid will clear the
market and be selected. In response to
comments from public power entities,
cooperatives, and other such entities
with retail customers that are sometimes
not subject to state public utility
regulation, we clarify that, for the
purposes of the ARC part of this rule,
the term ‘‘relevant electric retail
regulatory authority’’ means the entity
that establishes the retail electric prices
and any retail competition policies for
those customers, such as the city
council for a municipal utility or the
governing board of a cooperative
utility.92 An ARC can bid demand
response either on behalf of only one
retail customer or multiple retail
customers. Except for circumstances
where the laws and regulations of the
relevant retail regulatory authority do
not permit a retail customer to
participate, there is no prohibition on
who may be an ARC, and an individual
customer may serve as an ARC on behalf
of itself and others. Finally, RTOs or
ISOs may specify certain requirements,
such as registration with the RTO or ISO
and creditworthiness and other
requirements, which qualify a resource
91 See, e.g., PJM at 8; EnerNOC at 5–7; Alcoa at
22; Public Interest Organizations at 6–10.
92 We do not intend to require an RTO or ISO to
accept a demand response bid from an ARC that has
aggregated the demand responses of retail
customers if this is not permitted by laws or
regulations of those regulatory entities covered by
the term ‘‘state regulatory authority’’ for those retail
customers or if the retail customers are served at
retail by a ‘‘nonregulated electric utility,’’ as these
two terms are defined in sections 3(9) and 3(17) of
the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978,
16 U.S.C. 2602(9), (17) (2000).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
provider to make a bid and requests
comments on whether there is any
reason not to subject ARC to the same
requirements as any other bidder in the
energy market.
89. As mentioned, we received
voluminous comments on the issue of
compensation to a demand response
aggregator, with comments on this issue
differing widely. A standard
compensation approach may not be
feasible given the differences in market
designs across the regions, and we are
persuaded that a rule that fixes a single
pricing method in regulations may not
be appropriate. However, the
appropriate valuation of demand
response in organized markets is
addressed further below in our proposal
for pricing during a period of operating
reserve shortage.
90. We agree with commenters who
argue that each region’s market design is
different and that it is important for the
ARC provisions to consider these
regional differences. For this reason, we
do not propose to require detailed
generic market rule amendments for
ARCs. We propose instead to require
RTOs and ISOs to amend their tariffs
and market rules as necessary to allow
an ARC to bid demand response directly
into the RTO’s or ISO’s organized
market in accordance with the following
criteria:
b The ARC’s demand response bid
must meet the same requirements as a
demand response bid from any other
entity such as an LSE. For example,
• Its aggregate demand response must
be as verifiable as eligible LSE or large
industrial customer demand response
that are bid directly into the market.
b The requirements for measurement
and verification of aggregated demand
response should be comparable to the
requirements for other providers of
demand response resources, regarding
such matters as transparency, ability to
be documented, and ensuring
compliance.
b Demand response bids from an
ARC must not be treated differently
from the demand response bids of an
LSE or a large industrial customer.
• The RTO or ISO may require the
ARC to be an RTO member if
membership is a requirement for other
bidders.
• Single aggregated bids consisting of
individual demand response from a
single area, reasonably defined, may be
required by RTOs and ISOs.
• An RTO or ISO may place
appropriate restrictions on demand
response participation by any customer
to avoid counting the same demand
response resource more than once.
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12589
• The market rules do not have to
allow bids from an ARC where this is
not permitted under the laws or
regulations of the relevant electric retail
regulatory authority. The RTO or ISO
must receive explicit notification from
the relevant retail regulatory authority
in order to disqualify a bid from an ARC
that includes the demand response of
that authority’s retail customers.
91. We request comment about
whether these criteria are appropriate
and whether there are additional
appropriate criteria for allowing an ARC
to bid demand response.
92. An RTO or ISO must either
propose amendments to its tariff to
comply with the proposed requirement
or demonstrate that its existing tariff
and market design already satisfy the
requirement to permit an ARC to bid a
demand response on behalf of retail
customers.93 This filing would be
submitted within six months of the date
the final rule is published in the Federal
Register. The Commission will assess
whether each filing satisfies the
proposed requirement and will issue
additional orders as necessary.
93. We note, however, that
cooperation and coordination among the
RTOs and ISOs in developing standard
terms for demand response programs
would be beneficial. Accordingly, we
encourage RTOs and ISOs to coordinate
their efforts through the ISO/RTO
Council to identify common issues, best
practices, and market rules that are
consistent between regions (particularly
in the areas of market procedures,
bidding protocols, communication
protocols, and measurement and
verification) or act to develop common
business practices and measurement
and verification protocols through the
North American Energy Standards
Board (NAESB).
d. Potential Future Demand Response
Reforms
94. The need for, and the focus on,
demand response will continue to
increase. Although the Commission is
proposing specific reforms to eliminate
barriers to demand response here, we
believe that other reforms may be
necessary in the future. However, we do
not wish to delay the adoption of these
specific reforms while the Commission
and industry continue to study and
consider other advances in this area.
Rather, we believe that the reforms
proposed here should proceed while the
93 In particular, this proposal would not
necessarily require any change to an existing
aggregation program that already functions well if
the existing program satisfies the proposed criteria.
See NEPOOL Participants at 12; TAPS at 19–21;
Silicon Valley Power at 7–8.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
12590
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
Commission and stakeholders study
what additional efforts are needed and
develop a record to support further
reforms.
95. In order to achieve this goal, we
intend to direct staff to hold a technical
conference shortly after receiving the
comments on this NOPR to consider the
following issues for demand response
participation in the wholesale markets:
(1) If there are barriers to comparable
treatment of demand response that have
not previously been identified and what
they are; (2) potential solutions to
eliminate any potential barriers to
comparable treatment of demand
response; (3) appropriate compensation
for demand response; and (4) the need
for and the ability to standardize terms,
practices, rules and procedures
associated with demand response,
among other things. The proposed
technical conference will provide a
forum for RTOs/ISOs, demand response
providers, and other stakeholders to
express their views regarding these
issues. It will also serve as guidance to
the RTOs/ISOs of the areas that they
should include as part of the study we
propose to order as well as other issues
identified in the course of the study. We
propose to require each RTO or ISO to
assess and report on the barriers to
comparable treatment of demand
response resources that are within the
Commission’s jurisdiction, including
those listed above, and to submit its
findings and any proposed solutions
along with a timeline for
implementation to address barriers to
the Commission within six months of
the Final Rule (RTO and ISO studies).
To ensure that minority views are
adequately represented, we propose to
require that the RTO or ISO identify any
significant minority views in its filing.
We also will require the Independent
Market Monitor for each RTO or ISO to
provide its views on this issue to the
Commission.
96. These RTO and ISO studies will
have significant value. They have the
potential to provide independent
critical analysis and a basis for
additional reform. In this regard, we
note that section 529 of the Energy
Independence and Security Act of 2007
(EISA) requires the Commission to
complete a national assessment of
demand response both to estimate the
potential for demand response and to
determine how to overcome the barriers
to achieving that potential.94 We believe
that the RTO and ISO studies we are
proposing to require will help us in
preparing the assessment and ultimately
94 The Energy Independence and Security Act of
2007, Pub. L. No. 110–140, 121 Stat. 1492 (2007).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
in developing a national action plan on
demand response as required by EISA.
These studies will also provide a sound
platform and record for the Commission
to consider whether there should be
additional reforms to remove barriers to
demand response in organized markets
that ensure comparable and fair
treatment of demand response resources
as required by the EISA.95 We seek
comment on the proposed approach to
identify and assess remaining barriers to
comparable treatment of demand
response as well as any particular issues
or areas that should be addressed in the
RTO and ISO reports.
e. Market Rules Governing Price
Formation During Periods of Operating
Reserve Shortage
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
97. In the ANOPR, the Commission
sought comment on modifying market
rules that limit the market-clearing price
during an emergency, that is, when the
amount of available supply falls short of
demand plus the operating reserve
requirement.96 When this happens,
reliability is threatened and market
rules that limit the market price may
have the unintended effect of
discouraging demand response.
Limiting the price also discourages
existing generators needed mostly for
emergencies from continuing operation
and discourages entry of new
generation. The ANOPR presented for
comment four possible approaches to
addressing this problem.
98. First, the Commission proposed
requiring RTOs and ISOs to increase the
energy supply offer caps and demand
bid caps above the current levels during
an emergency. This could also result in
a market-clearing price higher than the
existing caps. Second, the Commission
proposed requiring RTOs and ISOs to
allow only demand bid caps to be raised
above the current level, while keeping
generation offer caps in place. Such
high demand bids would be allowed to
set the market price if they clear the
market. As a third possible approach,
the Commission proposed requiring a
demand curve for operating reserves in
each RTO or ISO market. Finally, as a
fourth approach, the Commission
proposed requiring RTOs and ISOs to
modify their market rules to set the
market-clearing price for all supply and
demand response resources dispatched
during an emergency at the payment
95 42 U.S.C. 8241 et seq. (2000), amended by
EISA, Pub. L. No. 110–140, 529, 121 Stat. 1492
(2007).
96 We note that in this section of the NOPR, we
refer to this emergency period as a period of
operating reserve shortage.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
made to participants in an emergency
demand response program.97
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
99. Many commenters advocate an
RTO-by-RTO approach instead of a
rulemaking for addressing this issue.98
They call for the Commission to identify
the general features of a solution,
allowing each RTO and ISO and its
regional stakeholders to develop the
details. Others request that the
Commission act only in coordination
with state regulators because the ability
of ultimate consumers to reduce
demand in an emergency depends on
retail metering, pricing, and other
programs.
100. Many other commenters spoke
for or against all four approaches
collectively. Those opposed to allowing
buyers to see a higher price during an
emergency argue that the proposals are
based on an incorrect assumption that
higher prices would reduce demand.
They contend that most of the buyers in
an RTO’s or ISO’s market are LSEs with
an obligation to buy regardless of the
price; thus, the ultimate consumers (at
retail) will not see the higher price or
reduce demand.99 Some opposing
commenters argue that the proposals in
varying degrees would create new
opportunities for generators to exercise
market power.100 Further, they oppose
some of the proposals because they
would result in an administratively
determined price instead of a true
market price.101
101. Those in support of allowing
buyers to see a higher price during an
emergency argue that prices should be
determined by an unencumbered market
where buyers and sellers are allowed to
make bids and offers with no
restriction.102
97 Based on comments on the ANOPR’s
preliminary proposals, we note that there may be
some confusion regarding the second and fourth
approaches. We clarify that a demand bid is
different from a demand response bid. The first is
an offer by a potential purchaser to buy a certain
amount of energy at a given market price, and the
second is an offer by a purchaser to reduce its
normal purchase by a given amount in return for
compensation.
98 E.g., Ameren at 31; CAISO at 19–20; EEI at 11;
National Grid at 10; NEPOOL Participants at 15–17;
NYISO at 34–35; PJM MMU at 6–7; PG&E at 9.
99 See, e.g., APPA at 59; Industrial Coalitions at
10–12; LPPC at 7–8; OPSI at 38; PJM MMU at 7;
Public Interest Organizations at 11; TAPS at 21.
100 See, e.g., Ameren at 29; Connecticut and
Massachusetts Municipals at 41–42; EEI at 25;
Industrial Consumers at 22; PJM Power Providers at
2–6; PPL Parties at 5–9.
101 See, e.g., EEI at 29; Reliant at 5; PJM Power
Providers at 31.
102 See, e.g., AEP at 5; The Alliance at 9;
Constellation at 5–6; EPSA at 33; Reliant at 5–7;
Strategic Energy at 9.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
102. In general, among those who
favored one or more of the ANOPR’s
four approaches, the first (raise all caps
during an emergency) and third (have a
demand curve for operating reserves)
approaches received the strongest
support. The second (raise only demand
bid caps during an emergency) and
fourth (allow the payments for
emergency demand response to set the
market-clearing price during an
emergency) approaches had the weakest
support.
103. In comments on the first
approach—lifting energy bid caps and
price caps above the current levels only
during an emergency—supporters say
that this course of action allows buyers
and sellers to set a true market price for
electricity during an emergency, reduces
demand by the appropriate amount, and
allows investors in new generation to
assess the value to buyers of new
generating resources. This approach also
has strong opposition, with particular
concerns about the potential for
generators to exercise market power and
the inability of customers to respond to
high prices.
104. The few commenters supporting
the second approach—raising bid caps
above the current level only for demand
bids—say that it decreases generators’
ability to manipulate the market
compared to the first option. They also
make the general point that it is
important to let buyers express their
true value for power. Those objecting to
this proposal raised many of the same
concerns that were raised regarding the
first approach. For instance, they allege
that even raising bid caps only for
demand bids would allow generators to
physically withhold some portion of
their output from the market to obtain
higher prices for the remaining output.
Commenters also argued that the
proposal was based on the false
assumption that buyers that do not enter
a bid to purchase at a high price will not
be served. These commenters maintain
that utilities shed load only as a last
resort during an emergency, and
emergency curtailment programs dictate
the allocation of power during a
shortage in a way that has nothing to do
with the price bid into the energy
market.
105. Support for the third approach of
establishing a demand curve for
operating reserves rests heavily on its
track record, namely that the
Commission has approved these
programs before and many regions have
experience with them.103 Arguments
against this specific proposal are largely
objections to administratively
determined demand curves where
prices may be set at levels that do not
reflect competitive market conditions.
106. In commenting on the fourth
approach—setting the market—clearing
price at the payment made to
participants in an emergency demand
response program—a few commenters
state that this approach is preferable to
allowing no higher price during an
emergency at all and could be supported
as a transitional step in the process of
removing all bid and offer caps.
Opposition to this approach is based on
the market price being administratively
determined and a variety of other
reasons, for example, that it is
inappropriate to set an energy price
based on a reliability payment.
103 Duke Energy at 11; EPSA at 35; PJM MMU at
6–7; National Grid at 10–11; NEPOOL Participants
at 16; New England Power Generators at 6–7;
NYISO at 35; NY TO at 10.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
iii. Commission Proposal
107. We have carefully considered the
comments on this issue and continue to
believe that existing market rules appear
to be unjust, unreasonable and unduly
discriminatory or preferential during
times of scarcity. In particular, they may
not accurately reflect the true value of
energy and, by failing to do so, may
harm reliability, inhibit demand
response, deter new entry of demand
response and generation resources and
thwart innovation. However, we are
cognizant of the fact that this is a
difficult issue and that any change in
market rules must consider the issue of
market power, recognize regional
differences in market rules, and be
based on a sound factual record. We
first explain the potential need for
reform and then we describe our
proposal to address this issue.
108. In a competitive market, demand
and supply respond to price. If the price
of energy is artificially capped during
times of scarcity, this will constitute a
barrier to effectively attracting new
generation and demand resources into
organized markets. When the system
faces a shortage of operating reserves,
additional resources are needed for
operating reserves that help to maintain
grid reliability. At such times, market
prices can elicit demand response from
certain customers who are equipped to
respond and, thus, help balance the
system. When bid and offer caps are in
place, however, it is not always possible
to elicit the optimal level of demand or
generator response.
109. Some commenters argue that
certain barriers to demand response
remain and that the Commission should
not undertake any reform until such
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12591
barriers are removed. The Commission
is taking several important, concrete
steps in this rulemaking to eliminate
remaining barriers to demand response
that are indicated by the existing record
to ensure comparable and fair treatment
of demand response resources. We
recognize, however, that some barriers
may remain. That is why we are
requiring each RTO or ISO, as explained
above, to undertake a further study of
this issue and report back to the
Commission. However, even if some
barriers remain (certain of which may be
subject to state jurisdiction, not our
jurisdiction), price remains an
important factor in encouraging demand
response. Without prices that reflect the
true value of energy, we cannot expect
the full integration of demand response
into organized markets. We therefore do
not believe that reforms in this area
should be delayed until every barrier to
demand response, whether retail or
wholesale, technological or regulatory,
is identified and addressed. We have,
however, included as a primary
criterion for approving price reform
during periods of operating reserve
shortage an adequate record
demonstrating that provisions exist for
mitigating market power and deterring
gaming behavior. These could include,
but are not limited to, use of demand
resources to discipline bidding behavior
to competitive levels during periods of
operating reserve shortages.
110. We recognize that not all
customers are at present equipped to
respond to scarcity pricing.
Nevertheless, putting rules in place that
allow the fraction of the load currently
able to respond can have a very positive
effect on the market and help reduce
prices for all.104 Further, with the
modifications that this proposal
anticipates, more buyers would find it
worthwhile to invest in technologies
that allow them to respond to prices.
This group could include not only large
manufacturers and others buying
directly from the RTO or ISO market,
but also ARCs, and LSEs which can
implement retail demand response
programs designed to reduce load
during reserve shortages.
111. The Commission’s proposed
reforms are also intended to increase
reliability. Our proposal is limited to
periods of true scarcity (i.e., when there
is a shortage of operating reserves). We
have a duty to implement rules that
ensure adequate supplies. If the price of
energy during these periods is
104 See 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment at 7. As reported in the 2006 FERC Staff
Demand Response Assessment, as little as five
percent of load responding to price may discipline
market prices.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
12592
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
artificially constrained, demand cannot
respond efficiently and therefore the
likelihood of involuntary curtailments is
increased. Thus, demand resources may
be a low cost resource that can be used
to meet operating reserves requirements
at the lowest total cost of maintaining
reliability. Furthermore, by artificially
capping prices, the price signals
necessary to attract new entry by both
generation and demand resources are
muted and long-term resource adequacy
is harmed.
112. This is not merely a theoretical
problem. In regions such as PJM and
New England, the Commission has
found in prior orders that existing
energy and capacity markets did not
encourage sufficient new entry and that
these regions therefore faced serious
reliability problems.105 The Commission
adopted forward capacity markets in
those regions to avoid the threats to
reliability and the real costs to our
economy of inadequate generation and
demand resources. The reforms we
propose here can help to avoid these
problems in other regions. Moreover, as
we explain below, in regions that
already have such capacity markets, the
reforms proposed here can reduce the
level of revenues that must be recovered
in such capacity markets.
113. Some commenters appear to
misunderstand our proposal and suggest
that we are proposing to lift the caps on
generation in every organized market.
This is not correct. Only one of our
proposals would lift price caps on
generators bidding energy into
organized markets. The other three
would not do so, but rather would seek
to better reflect the value of energy
during times of scarcity through other
means.
114. In regions that have already
adopted forward capacity markets, the
lifting of such price caps on energy
would primarily shift revenues from
capacity markets to energy markets. In
New England and PJM, the revenues
collected by generators in the energy
market are deducted from the revenues
that need to be recovered in the capacity
markets. Moreover, by shifting the price
signals from capacity markets to energy
markets, the Commission is encouraging
greater demand response, as demand
response may face fewer barriers to
participating in energy markets than
forward capacity markets.
115. Finally, and most importantly,
we are not proposing to change the rules
in each region without regard to the
105 Devon Power, LLC, 115 FERC ¶ 61,340, order
on reh’g, 117 FERC ¶ 61,133 (2006), appeal pending
sub nom. Maine Pub. Utils. Comm’n v. FERC, No.
06–1403 (DC Cir. 2007); PJM Interconnection, LLC,
117 FERC ¶ 61,331 (2006).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
specific circumstances facing that
region. As we explain below, each
region will be permitted to demonstrate
that its current rules do not need to be
reformed because they already
adequately reflect the value of energy
during periods of scarcity.
116. Other commenters raise market
power concerns. We agree that we have
a duty to guard the consumer against
exploitation by sellers with market
power and we will fulfill that duty. As
we explain below, we are proposing that
market power issues be adequately
addressed before any reforms in this
area are adopted.
117. We now explain our proposal for
reform in this area. We propose to
require each organized market to make
a compliance filing, within six months
of a final rule in this proceeding,
proposing any necessary reforms to
ensure that the market price for energy
accurately reflects the value of such
energy during periods of scarcity (i.e.,
an operating reserve shortage). Because
there are regional differences in market
design, we will not mandate any one
type of reform in this area. Rather, each
region may propose one of the four
approaches described in the ANOPR
(and summarized further below) or it
may propose a different approach.
Alternatively, a region may demonstrate
that its existing market rules already
reflect the value of energy during
periods of scarcity and therefore do not
need to be reformed.
118. In recognition of the concerns of
many commenters, we also propose to
adopt further requirements to ensure
that any reforms in this area are
supported by adequate factual support
and show how they are designed to
protect consumers against the exercise
of market power. First, each RTO or ISO
proposing to reform or demonstrate the
adequacy of its existing market rules in
this area must provide an adequate
factual record for the Commission to
evaluate its proposal. Specifically, the
RTO or ISO should provide historical
evidence in its region regarding the
interaction of supply and demand
during periods of scarcity and the
resulting effects on the market price for
energy. To the extent this evidence
indicates that the region’s market rules
are inadequate during these periods, the
RTO or ISO must then explain and
support why its proposed reforms are
tailored to address those inadequacies.
This factual record will allow the
Commission to discharge its duty to
ensure that any reform is necessary and
narrowly tailored to address the
circumstances in that region.
119. As a general matter, we will
consider the factual record compiled by
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
the RTO or ISO to determine whether its
proposal, or its demonstration as to its
existing market rules, would:
• Improve reliability by reducing
demand and increasing generation
during periods of operating reserve
shortage;
• Make it more worthwhile for
customers to invest in demand response
technologies;
• Encourage existing generation and
demand resources needed during an
operating reserve shortage to remain in
business;
• Encourage entry of new generation
and demand resources;
• Provide comparable treatment and
compensation to demand resources
during periods of operating reserve
shortages; and
• Have provisions for mitigating
market power and deterring gaming
behavior, including, but not limited to,
use of demand resources to discipline
bidding behavior to competitive levels
during periods of operating reserve
shortages.
120. We request comment on whether
these criteria are appropriate and
whether there are additional criteria that
we should consider in evaluating a
proposal for pricing during a period of
operating reserve shortage by RTOs and
ISOs.
121. Second, the Commission will
require any RTO proposing reform in
this area to address the adequacy of any
mitigation measures that would be in
place during periods of operating
reserve shortage. We recognize that
many commenters have raised market
power concerns and we take those
concerns seriously. However, we note
that enhanced demand responsiveness
and increased entry by generators can
help to mitigate seller market power by
lowering market prices.106 Moreover, we
note that generator bid and offer caps
are not increased in three of the four
options proposed.107 These caps
provide further protection against the
exercise of seller market power. Further,
the Commission notes that other market
power mitigation measures remain in
106 See B.F. Neenan et al., Neenan Associates,
2004 NYISO Demand Response Program
Evaluation, at E–5, (Feb. 2005); David B. Patton,
Potomac Economics, 2006 State of the Market
Report—The Midwest ISO, at 44 (May 2007).
107 In the first approach, bid and offer caps would
increase for both sellers and buyers. In the second
approach, bid and offer caps for buyers would be
increased, but bid and offer caps for sellers would
remain in place. In the third approach, based on a
demand curve for operating reserves, bid and offer
caps would remain in place for both sellers and
buyers. In the fourth approach (which proposes that
payments to participants in an emergency demand
response program could set the market-clearing
price), bid and offer caps would again remain in
place for both sellers and buyers.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
place during times when operating
reserves are insufficient. For example,
conduct and impact tests are applied in
ISO–NE, NYISO, and Midwest ISO. A
pivotal supplier test is used in PJM. PJM
and CAISO mitigate bids by generators
chosen out of merit order. Moreover, the
Commission intends to closely monitor
market behavior during periods of
operating reserve shortage to ensure that
market participants are following
market rules and to guard against the
exercise of market power.
122. In addition, to ensure that we
have an adequate record on the issue of
market power mitigation, we propose to
solicit the views of the Independent
Market Monitor for each RTO or ISO
region on any proposed reforms in this
area.
123. We now briefly summarize the
four approaches discussed in the
ANOPR and referred to above. As noted,
however, these are not the only
approaches that may be considered.
Under the first approach, RTOs and
ISOs would increase the energy supply
offer caps and demand bid caps above
the current levels only during an
emergency. For example, if operating
reserves drop below levels required in
mandatory reliability standards, then
bid caps would be allowed to rise above
existing caps. As we described above,
increasing energy supply offer and
demand bid caps would allow the
market to clear at a price above the
current (or non-emergency) cap.108
Customers and LSEs could then decide
whether to purchase energy at the
higher price, and those who place a
higher value on energy could continue
to buy it while those who do not value
it as highly could reduce their demand.
Thus, this proposal would allow supply
and demand to operate more efficiently
to allocate limited supply to those who
value it the most.
124. Under the second approach,
RTOs and ISOs would increase bid caps
above the current level only for demand
bids (i.e., the buyers’ offers to purchase
a certain amount of energy at a given
price) while keeping generation bid caps
in place. That is, a buyer would be
allowed to inform the RTO or ISO about
how much energy it would purchase at
various prices above the current bid
caps. These demand bids would be
108 Under this proposal, the price and bid caps
would be removed in the real-time market during
an operating reserve shortage, but not necessarily in
the day-ahead market. Thus, the price and bid caps
would be removed normally for only a fraction of
the spot market. In a severe shortage when the
system operator is aware that the day-ahead market
will produce insufficient generation for day-ahead
energy and operating reserves, the price and bid
caps would also be removed for the day-ahead
market.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
allowed to set the market price if they
clear the market. As with the other
approaches, the higher market price
under this approach would create an
incentive for all buyers to lower their
demands during an emergency. Demand
that is price-sensitive would be reduced
until available supply can meet the
demand plus the need for operating
reserves. This proposal does not change
any rules that govern how demand
response resources operate in the
market.109
125. The third approach is for an RTO
or ISO to establish a demand curve for
operating reserves. The RTO or ISO
would establish market rules that set
real-time prices at specific predetermined values (typically above the
market-wide offer and bid caps) during
an operating reserve shortage. The price
level would increase with the severity of
the shortage. This approach will ensure
that market prices reflect tight
conditions on the grid without altering
any of the market power mitigation
restrictions on either supply offers or
demand bids. The Commission has
already approved this option in the
NYISO and ISO–NE markets.110 These
existing programs for pricing during
reserve shortages have been
implemented and activated during
periods of operating reserve shortage in
these regions. Moreover, the exposure to
higher prices would increase the
incentive for load to engage in hedging
activities, and higher prices during
shortages should attract new generation.
As long as the prices that are
implemented during reserve shortages
are based on costs relevant to the market
(such as the cost of new peak generation
entry), and the particular characteristics
of RTO and ISO regions, demand curves
for operating reserves should induce
sufficient supply and demand
responses. A properly designed demand
curve for operating reserves should also
alleviate concerns about
administratively determined prices. As
109 We clarify that this approach refers to
demand, not demand response. That is, this
proposal allows a buyer to submit a bid to purchase
energy at a price that exceeds the current bid cap.
This proposal in no way affects demand response
resources that participate in a program where they
are paid some amount of money to reduce their
consumption.
110 The Commission approved market rules for
NYISO and ISO–NE that include a demand curve
for operating reserves that sets the real-time market
price when operating reserves are low. New York
Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 106 FERC ¶ 61,111
(2004); New England Power Pool and ISO New
England Inc., 115 FERC ¶ 61,175 (2006). See David
B. Patton & Pallas LeeVanSchaik, 2006 Assessment
of the Electricity Markets in New England (June
2007); David B. Patton & Pallas LeeVanSchaik, 2006
State of the Market Report New York ISO (July
2007).
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12593
noted above, the demand curve is a
reflection of the costs of entering the
energy market and indicates the prices
suppliers would expect to be paid to
provide that energy to the market. Thus,
while the demand curve is
administratively determined, it is based
on market conditions.
126. Under the fourth approach, an
RTO or ISO would amend its market
rules to set the market-clearing price for
all supply and demand response
resources dispatched equal to the
payment made to participants in an
emergency demand response
program.111 Since the emergency
demand response programs are only
called during an emergency when
demand needs to be reduced quickly,
they should be the marginal resource
and set the market-clearing price.
Without such a rule, demand response
payments are made to those demand
response resources that respond to the
RTO’s or ISO’s call to reduce load, yet
prices are still set by the generation
resource with the highest running costs
(or at the price cap). This proposal
would set the market-clearing price by
the actual marginal reliability resource,
the demand response resource. For
example, if participants in emergency
demand response programs were paid
$500/MWh to reduce their consumption
when directed, then the $500/MWh
payment would set the market-clearing
price in the zones where the program
was active.
127. This rulemaking approach to
demand response is directed at all RTOs
and ISOs to ensure that all meet certain
basic demand response goals. However,
we do not intend to alter current RTO
and ISO shortage pricing programs if the
compliance filings satisfy us that the
current programs meet the intent of this
requirement. Some RTOs and ISOs have
already dedicated considerable
resources to develop various shortagepricing programs. These programs have
been developed through established
stakeholder processes in the RTOs and
ISOs and have been approved by the
Commission and determined to be just
and reasonable. Thus, the requirement
proposed here may be satisfied by a
filing demonstrating that the RTO or
ISO already has a Commission-approved
approach for pricing during periods of
operating reserve shortage that meets
the requirements previously discussed
(i.e., in P 117, 118 and 120).
128. Each RTO or ISO may also
consider a ‘‘phase-in’’ of its specific
111 RTOs and ISOs would have to amend their
market rules on unit commitment and settlement to
adjust wholesale energy prices outside the normal
clearing process.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12594
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
emergency pricing method, over a
period of years (e.g., three years). This
phase-in period can gradually introduce
customers to price increases during an
emergency and allow them to develop
ways to reduce demand during an
emergency to avoid high prices. We note
that the phase-in may be linked to key
factors such as the deployment of the
advanced metering needed to
implement their proposed method,
provided the phase-in period is not
protracted. However, the full
deployment of advanced metering is not
a requirement for the implementation of
emergency pricing as price and demand
responsiveness can be achieved without
such a prerequisite.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
B. Long-Term Power Contracting in
Organized Markets
129. In the ANOPR, the Commission
offered for comment three proposals
intended to facilitate long-term
contracting in organized markets, along
with questions about whether to modify
Electric Quarterly Reports (EQR) data
requirements to facilitate long-term
contracting. Following review of the
comments, the Commission proposes to
require that ISOs and RTOs dedicate a
portion of their Web sites for market
participants to post offers to buy or sell
electric energy on a long-term basis. The
Commission will consider reasonable
additional steps in response to
comments on this NOPR, and continues
to encourage ISOs and RTOs to work
within their authorities with
stakeholders to facilitate long-term
power contracting.
1. Background
130. Long-term power contracts are an
important element in a functioning
electric power market. Forward power
contracting allows buyers and sellers to
hedge against the risk that prices may
fluctuate in the future. Both buyers and
sellers should be able to create
portfolios of short, intermediate, and
long-term power supplies to manage
risk and meet customer demand. Longterm contracts also improve price
stability, mitigate the risk of the abuse
of market power, and provide a platform
for investment in new generation and
transmission.
131. As the Commission noted in the
ANOPR, an organized market region
naturally should facilitate long-term
contracting by eliminating pancaked
rates for long distance power sales,
eliminating loop flow problems within
its footprint, and ensuring reliable
transmission operation over a large area.
RTO and ISO transmission services also
expand the size of the markets available
to buyers and sellers of long-term power
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
contracts, and provide independent and
unified transmission scheduling and
operation services over a large area.
132. While most of the comments
submitted in response to the ANOPR
and testimony from parties at the
Commission’s technical conference on
May 8, 2007 agree as to the importance
of long-term contracts, opinions vary as
to the extent of a problem with longterm contracts in the market and its
causes. Many customers argue that
issues of market design and overreliance on the spot market have driven
up prices, making long-term contracting
difficult. On the other hand, many
power sellers believe that markets are
operating well, but parties are unable to
reach long-term contracts due to
differing price expectations and
differing assessments of long-term risk.
133. The Commission has already
taken action in other areas to facilitate
long-term contracting. In Order No. 681,
the Commission adopted a Final Rule
on long-term transmission rights for
organized market regions designed to
assure availability of long-term
transmission at a predictable cost.112
The Commission then adopted
transmission planning reforms in Order
No. 890 to provide an open and
transparent process for wholesale
entities and transmission providers to
plan for the long-term needs of their
customers. Interconnection rules for
large, small and wind generators in
Order Nos. 2003, 2006 and 661 have
improved the interconnection process
and provide for interconnection with
network integration service to facilitate
long-term reliance on new
generation.113 The Commission has also
reformed capacity markets in several
regions to shift reliance from short-term
purchases to forward markets held
sufficiently in advance of delivery (e.g.,
three years) to be more consistent with
112 Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in
Organized Electricity Markets, Order No. 681, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,226 (2006), order on reh’g, Order
No. 681–A, 117 FERC ¶ 61,201 (2006).
113 Standardization of Generator Interconnection
Agreements and Procedures, Order No. 2003, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,146 (2003), order on reh’g, Order
No. 2003–A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,160, order on
reh’g, Order No. 2003–B, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,171 (2004), order on reh’g, Order No. 2003–C,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,190 (2005), aff’d sub nom.
Nat’l Ass’n of Regulatory Util. Comm’rs v. FERC,
475 F.3d 1277 (DC Cir. 2007); Standardization of
Small Generator Interconnection Agreements and
Procedures, Order No. 2006, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,180, order on reh’g, Order No. 2006–A, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,196 (2005), order granting
clarification, Order No. 2006–B, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,221 (2006), appeal pending sub nom.
Consolidated Edison Co. of New York, Inc., et al.
v. FERC Docket No. 06–1018, et al; Interconnection
for Wind Energy, Order No. 661, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,186, order on reh’g, Order No. 661–A, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,198 (2005).
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
the time necessary to construct new
generation.114
2. The Need for Commission Action
134. As noted above, long-term power
contracts are an important element of a
working market. They enable buyers
and sellers to manage risks, they
promote stability in pricing, and they
provide a solid foundation for the
financing of new generation. Despite
this importance, both buyers and sellers
perceive that it is increasingly difficult
to enter into long-term contracts, and
that fewer long-term contracts are being
signed as a result.
135. The Commission believes that
further transparency in long-term
electric energy markets would facilitate
efforts by both sellers and buyers to
incorporate long-term contracts as an
essential part of their energy portfolios.
This is especially true for new market
participants that may not be aware of
the full range of contract options
available to them, including the full
range of potential contract
counterparties. During the panel on
long-term contracting at the second
Commission competition conference, a
representative from PJM stated that he
had spoken to what he termed ‘‘smaller
players’’ who indicated that they were
willing to contract for power but were
unaware of who the available
counterparties were.115 These ‘‘smaller
players’’ said that they would be
interested in a bulletin board on the PJM
Web site that would facilitate
networking.116
136. While the market has the most
important role to play in disseminating
information, an RTO or ISO can play an
important role in promoting greater
transparency and liquidity in long-term
power markets, and thus help reduce
possible over-reliance on its spot
markets. The information systems it
operates are well suited for making such
information available to the parties in
its region.117 As discussed below,
several commenters support having
RTOs and ISOs provide a section of
their Web sites for a long-term contract
bulletin board, which they believe
would be a useful tool in assisting
parties in finding interested
114 Devon Power, LLC, 115 FERC ¶ 61,340, order
on reh’g, 117 FERC ¶ 61,133 (2006), appeal pending
sub nom. Maine Pub. Utils. Comm’n v. FERC, No.
06–1403 (DC Cir. 2007); PJM Interconnection, LLC,
117 FERC ¶ 61,331 (2006).
115 Transcript of Conference at 187, Conference
on Competition in Wholesale Power Markets,
Docket No. AD07–7–000 (May 8, 2007).
116 Id.
117 See id. at 117.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
counterparties and facilitating long-term
contracts.
137. In light of these comments and
our own observation, the Commission
will take action in this area. We do so
because of the importance of long-term
contracts to a working market and
because we believe greater transparency
in the market will facilitate such longterm contracts. We therefore propose
that regional organizations play a
supporting role in encouraging
voluntary contracting by providing an
online forum in which potential buyers
and sellers may exchange information.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
3. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
138. Given the importance of longterm contracts, in the ANOPR the
Commission requested comment on any
concrete steps it could take to facilitate
voluntary long-term power contracting
in organized market regions.118
Specifically, the Commission solicited
comment on whether it should
encourage greater market transparency
by requiring RTOs and ISOs to post
information that could facilitate longterm contracts, such as aggregate
information on long-term contract prices
and quantities, and if so, how the
information could be reported so that it
protects the confidentiality of
individual contracts. The Commission
also asked whether disseminating other
information, such as estimates of
transmission constraints and long-term
congestion costs, would be helpful to
long-term contracting.
139. The Commission also solicited
comment on whether it should require
or encourage efforts to develop new
standardized forward products and
whether standardized products would
facilitate long-term contracting. The
Commission inquired about what role it
should play, whether the Commission
should encourage RTOs or ISOs to play
an active role in this area (or whether
that would place them in a position of
undertaking commercial functions), and
whether this was a role better played by
NAESB or other industry groups.
140. Third, the Commission asked
whether it should require ISOs and
RTOs to dedicate a portion of their Web
sites for market participants to post
offers to buy or sell power long-term.
The Commission asked whether this
proposal would prove helpful, or
whether it was a service that would be
better provided by the market.
118 The Commission noted, however, that it was
mindful of the limits of its jurisdiction in seeking
comment on this issue, as the Commission cannot
compel buyers and sellers to enter into long-term
contracts. The Commission also noted that the
purchasing practices of LSEs are often dictated by
state policies, not those of this Commission.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
141. Finally, the Commission
requested comments on whether it
should consider any modification of the
data requirements of the EQR-for
example, to report the start date, term,
and end date of long-term power
contracts-to provide information that
would make transparent the average
prices of long-term power contracts of
various terms and vintages.
4. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
142. Commenters filed extensive
comments agreeing with the
Commission on the importance of longterm contracts in a functioning market.
They differ, however, on the nature and
extent of the problems with long-term
contracting, what measures would best
address the problems, and whether the
Commission should attempt to deal
with the various problems by requiring
RTO or ISO actions.
143. Most commenters recommend
against most of the actions proposed by
the Commission in the ANOPR, which
address the problems through
regulations applicable to RTOs or ISOs.
Some of these commenters argue that
market participants and the private
sector should address concerns over
long-term contracting opportunities,
while others argue that the Commission
can improve long-term contracting
opportunities by addressing larger
structural issues, identified below.
144. The preliminary proposal to
require RTOs and ISOs to reserve a
section of their Web sites for parties to
post offers to buy or sell power under
long-term contracts has the most
support, although most commenters do
not necessarily support making this a
regulatory requirement. A minority of
commenters support this proposal—
some strongly—including several RTOs
and ISOs, state regulators, wholesale
sellers, many small wholesale buyers,
and Joint Consumer Advocates.
Commenters indicate that such a Web
site would be useful for many market
participants, particularly new market
participants, and would help facilitate
long-term contracting. Midwest ISO and
PJM indicate that they have already
begun working on posting such
discussion boards on their Web sites,
and other RTOs and ISOs such as SPP
indicate support for providing space on
their Web sites to post such offers.
145. Commenters opposed to this
proposal indicate that the market
already adequately performs this
function, and that the RTOs and ISOs
should be able to determine on their
own whether to have a Web site section
for bulletin board postings. EEI and
Duke Energy note that PJM once had a
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12595
bulletin board for similar purposes that
fell into disuse, likely due to a lack of
interest from market participants. Many
commenters, such as EPSA, argue that
RTOs and ISOs should be allowed to
determine, in consultation with
stakeholders, what to post on their Web
sites. Some commenters state that legal
issues may arise from having RTOs or
ISOs post information, including
concerns over confidentiality and
potential liability for the posting of
incorrect information, and that these
issues should be addressed before any
action is taken. The New England
Conference said that it supports a
regional, voluntary solution, where
regional working groups would be
created to discuss measures to increase
information sharing.
146. Commenters offer little support
for the ANOPR proposal to require
RTOs and ISOs to develop new
standardized forward products. Those
few commenters supporting the
proposal believe that new products
would assist customers in developing
long-term contracts. Some commenters,
such as the New York PSC and NRG,
offer qualified support for the concept of
improved forward products, but state
that the Commission should encourage
RTO or ISO participation in developing
such products rather than require their
development by the RTOs and ISOs
themselves.
147. A large majority of commenters
oppose this proposed requirement. They
say that the market already supplies
standardized products, and that it is
better equipped to do so than RTOs or
ISOs. EEI notes that it already has a
process for developing standardized
products that involves working with
market participants to adjust to changes
in the market. Many commenters also
note that long-term contracts vary
considerably from transaction to
transaction, making standardized
products difficult to develop unless they
are quite general and so less useful than
they are for short-term transactions.
Finally, some commenters note that this
proposed requirement would be an
undue burden to ISOs and RTOs.
148. Most commenters argue strongly
against adopting the ANOPR’s
preliminary proposal to require ISOs
and RTOs to post information on longterm contract prices and quantities.
They argue that this proposed
requirement is unnecessary, is possibly
counterproductive, and would create
additional expense for the ISO or RTO.
A few, such as BlueStar and DC Energy,
support the proposal, arguing that it
would increase transparency in the
market, which would lead to greater
liquidity and increased long-term
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
12596
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
contracting. Some ISOs and RTOs also
indicate that they would be willing to
post information if directed to do so, but
that confidentiality concerns would
need to be addressed. Many commenters
think that the requirement would not be
useful because of the wide variation in
long-term contract provisions and the
time lag between contracting and
posting of the information.119 Others,
such as the OMS, argue that the data
collection requirement would unduly
burden RTOs and ISOs. The burden
would be unnecessary, according to
PG&E, PSEG, Allegheny, Ameren and
others, because the market and trade
press already provide sufficient data.
Finally, many commenters point to a
concern over the confidentiality of data
and the possibility that posted data
could be used to game the market.
149. Only a few commenters address
the Commission’s request for comments
on whether we should consider
modifications to the information
collected on long-term contracts in the
EQR. These commenters are generally
opposed to having the Commission
modify the EQR data reporting
requirements. Although SUEZ Energy
supports increased reporting
requirements, arguing that it would
create increased transparency for
providers of retail service, most
commenters believe that the information
in the EQR is already sufficient and that
any new information requirements
could have negative effects on
confidentiality or markets. For instance,
Old Dominion notes that modifying
EQR data could reveal competitive
information and result in reduced
forward liquidity for physical
transactions.
150. The Commission also requested
comments on additional steps that it
could take to promote long-term
contracting opportunities. Many
commenters point to the importance of
contract certainty, long-term stability of
market rules and regulatory policies,
and proper market design in supporting
long-term contracting, although
comments vary on how best to provide
for these elements. For instance, Old
Dominion argues that the Commission
should reaffirm its commitment to
incremental changes to market design to
prevent instability. PSEG notes that the
Commission should resist changing
tariffs and should not revise contracts
under FPA section 206, where either the
buyer or seller has miscalculated risks.
151. A majority of commenters
indicate that structural impediments to
long-term contracting prevent market
119 See Pepco at 13; New England Power
Generators at 8; Dynegy at 3.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
participants from fully utilizing longterm contracts as part of their energy
portfolios. Impediments cited include
differences between buyers and sellers
in assessing the appropriate long-term
price and assessing long-term risks,
over-reliance on spot markets, market
design, and regulatory uncertainty.
Many commenters, such as FirstEnergy,
point to buyers’ and sellers’ inability to
agree on a long-term price as the real
problem with long-term contracts. Some
commenters suggest that the
Commission should review overreliance on the spot markets, which,
they assert, affects forward prices and
creates a disincentive for parties to
engage in long-term deals.
152. Commenters also propose a
variety of more fundamental approaches
for the Commission to consider for
dealing with long-term contracting.
Some commenters argue that the
Commission should take a more
sweeping look at the markets as a
whole, noting that problems with longterm contracting are merely a symptom
of market inefficiency. These include a
request for an investigation of RTO
markets and mandating long-term
contracting through dedicating portions
of transmission lines for long-term
arrangements or requiring entities to
have a percentage of their portfolios as
long-term contracts.
153. Two commenters, American
Forest and Portland Cement
Association, et al., include fairly
detailed proposals to address problems
with the incentives for long-term
contracting. American Forest’s proposal,
the Financial Performance Obligation
(FPO), appears to require every
generating unit that receives a capacity
payment to financially guarantee the
delivery of energy to the real-time
market at or below a specified strike
price in any hour in which it is
dispatched by the RTO to provide
service. American Forest maintains that
the FPO would connect capacity and
energy markets and would provide a
hedge to load by shifting short-term risk
of market volatility in energy markets to
suppliers. It argues that the linked realtime market clearing price and capacity
price that would result from the FPO
would provide an incentive for
suppliers to take steps, such as longterm contracting, to hedge short-term
volatility, and prevent suppliers from
double recovering revenues from
capacity and energy payments. Portland
Cement Association, et al.’s proposal
offers an alternative market design
framework, Forward Capacity and
Energy Market, suggesting that a
combination of competitive and
administrative procedures could be
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
used to obtain the lowest-cost
combination of fixed and variable costs
while preserving the locational
economic signals of Locational Marginal
Pricing. It argues that the proposed
framework also would establish
economic incentives for both buyers
(e.g., LSEs and large customers) and
suppliers to negotiate long-term bilateral
contracts.
154. A significant number of
commenters state that the Commission
should take no action on the long-term
contracting topic, but should instead
leave any long-term contracting solution
to the market.
5. Proposed Reforms
155. The Commission proposes to
require ISOs and RTOs to dedicate a
portion of their Web sites for market
participants to post offers to buy or sell
power on a long-term basis. We are not
proposing here the other potential
actions considered in the ANOPR and
are not proposing to address in this
docket the other long-term contracting
issues raised by some commenters.
156. The proposal for an RTO/ISO
Web site ‘‘bulletin board’’ for posting
long-term offers to sell or buy is
designed to facilitate the long-term
contracting process by increasing the
transparency of available sellers and
buyers for market participants.
Providing a place for buyers and sellers
to offer long-term power transaction
opportunities should alleviate concerns
about sellers and buyers being unable to
find one another and should encourage
more long-term contracting and improve
efficiency in the market at little cost.
Improving information flow can only
increase liquidity among buyers and
sellers. The Commission believes that
this requirement will not be
burdensome for ISOs and RTOs to
implement.
157. The Commission does not
propose to mandate the specific type of
bulletin board that each ISO and RTO
must post, but will require each to work
with its stakeholders in designing a
solution that works for its market
participants. We have in mind,
however, an RTO/ISO bulletin board
that would allow persons to post offers
to sell or buy without making the RTO
or ISO responsible for the content of the
offers. We are encouraged that some
ISOs and RTOs have already undertaken
this effort.
158. The Commission proposes to
require ISOs and RTOs to make a
compliance filing within six months of
the date of publication of the final rule
in the Federal Register. This filing
should explain the actions the ISO or
RTO has taken to comply with the long-
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
term contracts bulletin board
requirement and provide information on
the bulletin board the ISO or RTO has
chosen to implement.
159. The Commission seeks public
comment on its proposal not to set by
rule the specific type of bulletin board
that each ISO and RTO must post. This
includes comment on whether any
features are important enough to specify
generically, such as the structure for the
webpage, the extent to which the ISO or
RTO must seek feedback on its web
design, or whether the ISO or RTO or
the market participant must post the
information. Further, we seek comment
on our assumption that the costs
involved with implementing the
proposal are minimal and should be
recovered in the same manner as other
Web site costs. In addition, the
Commission solicits comment on the
proposal that the RTO or ISO should not
be responsible for the content of the
offers on its bulletin board. Is a Web site
that includes a clear disclaimer
adequate to protect RTOs and ISOs from
liability, or should the Commission take
additional action? Do market
participants that post offers but fail to
reach agreement with counterparties on
contract terms and conditions have any
liability issues?
160. As we noted earlier, PJM recently
has conducted a series of forums on
long-term contracts to gather
information and facilitate the exchange
of ideas.120 We encourage similar efforts
by other RTOs or ISOs, and the ISO/
RTO Council. We encourage RTOs and
ISOs already working on solutions to
these issues to take appropriate steps to
ensure timely implementation of
reasonable solutions as soon as they are
ready. The Commission also directs
Commission staff to perform an analysis
of the level of long-term contracting in
organized market regions.
161. In addition, while we appreciate
the proposals of American Forest and
Portland Cement Association, et al. to
resolve disincentives to conduct longterm contracting, we have concerns that
various aspects of the proposals, such as
the impact of the proposal on capacity
markets, would require additional
development, review and consideration
before it would be ripe for inclusion in
a rulemaking. The shift of revenues from
the spot market to some form of forward
obligation or hedging option that could
occur with the FPO may well have
advantages, but this shift may create
new concerns among LSEs and others
about capacity market operations and
120 More information on the PJM forums is
available at https://www.pjm.com/committees/
stakeholders/drs/ltc.html.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
price levels. To help develop a greater
level of understanding of the proposals
we direct staff to conduct a technical
conference in a separate proceeding to
examine the FPO and Portland Cement
Association, et al.’s alternative market
designs and related issues.
12597
2. Prior Commission Actions Regarding
Market Monitoring
165. The Commission undertook its
first generic consideration of market
monitoring in Order No. 2000, which
required an RTO to include market
monitoring as one of its minimum
functions and to submit a market
monitoring plan as part of its RTO
proposal.122 The Order did not,
however, impose a specific MMU
structure on the RTOs. The Commission
noted in Order No. 2000 that while
MMUs were not intended to supplant
Commission authority, they should be
designed in such a way as to provide the
Commission with an additional means
of detecting market power abuses,
market design flaws and opportunities
for improvements in market
efficiency.123 The Commission ordered
RTOs to incorporate in their market
monitoring plans certain standards to be
met by the MMUs, which included
ensuring objective information about the
markets that the RTO operates or
administers, proposing appropriate
action regarding opportunities for
efficiency improvement, identifying
market design flaws or market power
abuses, and evaluating whether market
participants comply with market
rules.124 The Commission observed that
the information to be gleaned from
market monitoring would be beneficial
not only to the Commission, but also to
state commissions and market
participants.125
166. The Commission next addressed
the role of market monitors in its 2003
Order Amending Market-Based Rate
Tariffs and Authorizations.126 The
Commission clarified the duties of
MMUs in connection with enforcement
matters, directing that MMUs refer
compliance issues to the
Commission 127 and limiting direct
enforcement action by the MMUs to
objectively identifiable and sanctioned
behavior expressly set forth in the RTO/
ISO tariffs.128 In its subsequent Order on
Rehearing, the Commission clarified
that MMU personnel were not a
substitute for Commission enforcement
staff.129 Instead, MMUs were to provide
information to the Commission and its
staff, so that the Commission could take
appropriate action under the FPA.
167. In May of 2005, the Commission
issued a Policy Statement on Market
Monitoring Units,130 identifying four
tasks which MMUs perform for which
they need access to data and other
121 Regional Transmission Organizations, Order
No. 2000, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089 at 31,155
(1999), order on reh’g, Order No. 2000–A, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,092, at 30,993 (2000), aff’d sub
nom. Pub. Util. Dist. No. 1 of Snohomish County,
Washington v. FERC, 272 F.3d 607 (DC Cir. 2001).
122 Prior to this first generic consideration of
market monitoring, the Commission addressed
market monitoring in connection with individual
RTO/ISO proposals. See Pacific Gas and Electric
Co., 77 FERC ¶ 61,265 (1996), order on reh’g, 81
FERC ¶ 61,122 (1997), order on clarification, 83
FERC ¶ 61,033 (1998) (requiring the ISO to file a
detailed monitoring plan and listing minimum
elements for such a plan); Pennsylvania-New JerseyMaryland Interconnection, 81 FERC ¶ 61,257 (1997)
(PJM Formation Order) (requiring PJM to develop a
market monitoring program to evaluate market
power and design flaws).
123 Order No. 2000, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089
at 31,156.
124 Id.
125 Id.
126 Investigation of Terms and Conditions of
Public Utility Market-Based Rate Authorizations,
105 FERC ¶ 61,218 (2003) (Market Behavior Rules
Order), order on reh’g, 107 FERC ¶ 61,175 (2004)
(Market Behavior Rules Rehearing Order).
127 Market Behavior Rules Order, 105 FERC
¶ 61,218 at P 184.
128 Id. P 182.
129 Market Behavior Rules Rehearing Order, 107
FERC ¶ 61,175 at P 165.
130 Market Monitoring Units in Regional
Transmission Organizations and Independent
System Operators, 111 FERC ¶ 61,267 (2005) (Policy
Statement).
C. Market-Monitoring Policies
162. This section of the NOPR
proposes regulations implementing
market monitoring policies.
1. Background
163. Market monitors have played an
integral role in the organized electric
markets since the latter’s inception,
providing valuable reporting and
analysis services not only to the
Commission, but also to RTOs and ISOs,
to market participants, and to state
commissions. In light of their
importance, the Commission has
required that all RTOs and ISOs
incorporate a market monitoring
function.121
164. The span of years over which
market monitors have now been in
existence has given the Commission and
others in the industry a track record
upon which to evaluate the appropriate
roles MMUs should play and the
protections that might be adopted to
assist them in performing those roles. In
this NOPR, we propose reforms for
MMUs designed to improve their
abilities to monitor and report on the
operation of organized wholesale
electric markets.
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12598
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
resources.131 In an Appendix to the
Policy Statement, the Commission set
forth detailed Protocols for the MMUs to
follow in referring potential tariff or
Market Behavior Rule violations to the
Commission.132
168. In 2006, PJM Interconnection,
LLC (PJM) filed proposed revisions to
the MMU sections of its tariff, with the
general aim of conforming its tariff to
the provisions of the Policy
Statement.133 Several parties filed
comments, arguing that PJM’s tariff
should contain a clear statement of the
MMU’s independence and should set
forth all the rules relevant to the
responsibilities and functions of the
MMU. In the Commission’s Order on
Rehearing and Compliance Filing, we
noted that these concerns were of a
generic nature and not necessarily
limited to PJM.134
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
3. The Need for Commission Action
169. The concerns raised by
intervenors in the PJM case impressed
upon the Commission the need to
undertake a generic examination of
MMUs, to see if their roles could be
enhanced so as to improve the
efficiency and transparency of organized
wholesale electric markets. To that end,
the Commission announced that we
would hold a technical conference to
explore the issues raised by the
commenters.135
170. The Commission held the
technical conference on market
monitoring policies on April 5, 2007. At
the conference, the Commissioners
131 Id. P 2–3. These functions were: (1) To
identify ineffective market rules and tariff
provisions and recommend proposed rule and tariff
changes to the ISO or RTO that promote wholesale
competition and efficient market behavior; (2) to
review and report on the performance of wholesale
markets in achieving customer benefits; (3) to
provide support to the ISO or RTO in the
administration of Commission-approved tariff
provisions related to markets administered by the
ISO or RTO; and (4) to identify instances in which
a market participant’s behavior may require
investigation and evaluation to determine whether
a tariff violation has occurred, or which may be a
potential Market Behavior Rule violation, and
immediately notify appropriate Commission staff
for possible investigation.
132 Id. at Appendix A. The Market Behavior Rules
extant at the time of the Policy Statement have
since been in part rescinded, with the remainder
codified. See Conditions for Public Utility MarketBased Rate Authorization Holders, Order No. 674,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,208 (2006) (Order No. 674).
Rescinded Market Behavior Rule 2 has been
replaced by the Commission’s Anti-Manipulation
Rules. See Prohibition of Energy Market
Manipulation, Order No. 670, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,202 (Order No. 670), order denying reh’g, 114
FERC ¶ 61,300 (2006).
133 PJM Interconnection, LLC, 116 FERC ¶ 61,038
(2006) (PJM Tariff Order).
134 PJM Interconnection, LLC, 117 FERC ¶ 61,263,
at P 19 (2006) (PJM Tariff Rehearing Order).
135 Id. P 20.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
heard from interested commenters on
several general subjects.136 Two
principal issues received the bulk of
attention from the commenters at the
technical conference. Those were: (i)
The need for, and suggested methods of
achieving, independence on the part of
MMUs so they can perform their
assigned functions; and (ii) the content
and proper recipients of the market data
and analysis developed by the MMUs.
These issues are in accord with our own
observations of areas within the market
monitoring function that need reform.
For that reason, we have included
proposals in this NOPR designed to
strengthen market monitoring and
thereby enhance the performance and
transparency of organized RTO/ISO
markets.
4. Proposed Reforms
171. The Commission advanced
proposals in the ANOPR that responded
to the concerns expressed by
commenters at the technical conference
and that reflected the Commission’s
own observations formed from working
within the framework of the existing
market monitoring provisions. These
proposals were designed to strengthen
market monitoring by safeguarding
MMU independence and fostering
useful and transparent market analysis.
The Commission sought comment on
the proposals, which fell within the two
general areas of (i) independence and
function and (ii) information sharing. In
this NOPR, the Commission analyzes
the comments received and presents
revised proposals.
a. Independence and Function
172. In the ANOPR, the Commission
acknowledged the importance of
independence on the part of MMUs, and
stated that there are several means by
which to balance independence and
accountability. The Commission
proposed a balanced and flexible
approach to the problem which
included oversight protection, tariff
safeguards and tools, the elimination of
conflicts of interest, and certain changes
in the functions MMUs are expected to
perform. The Commission solicited
comments on the proposed changes.
136 These subjects included: the development of
the concept and functions of market monitoring, the
MMUs’ role with respect to the Commission, the
MMUs’ role with respect to ISOs and RTOs, and the
MMUs’ role with respect to the various stakeholders
such as states, generators, transmission providers,
and customers. See Second Notice of Technical
Conference, Review of Market Monitoring Policies,
Docket No. AD07–8–000 (March 9, 2007).
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
i. Structure and Tools
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
173. The Commission declined in the
ANOPR to propose a ‘‘one size fits all’’
approach to the structure of MMUs,
noting that there was no appreciable
difference among the performance of the
market monitors that could be attributed
to whether they were external (an
independent contractor who is hired by
the RTO or ISO) or internal (one whose
personnel are employees of the RTO or
ISO). Therefore, the Commission
proposed that it be left to the discretion
of each RTO or ISO to decide whether
it should have an internal MMU, an
external MMU, or a hybrid MMU
(consisting of both an internal market
monitor and an external market
monitor).
174. To ensure that MMUs would
have adequate tools with which to do
their job, the Commission proposed
requiring each RTO or ISO to include in
its tariff a provision imposing upon
itself the obligation to provide its MMU
with access to market data, resources,
and personnel sufficient to enable the
MMU to carry out its functions. We also
proposed that RTOs and ISOs include a
tariff provision directing the MMU to
report to the Commission any concerns
it has with inadequate access to market
data, resources, or personnel, and to
describe the steps it has taken with the
RTO or ISO to resolve these concerns.
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
175. The overwhelming bulk of the
commenters agreed with the
Commission’s proposal and opposed
imposition of a ‘‘one size fits all’’
approach. A few favored one or the
other structure. Exelon, Strategic
Energy, and Suez favored an external
model, on the grounds it could best
ensure independence.137 NJBPU favored
an internal model, at least with respect
to PJM.138
176. There was also limited support
for an alternative reporting structure.
The Ohio PUC proposed that MMUs
report to federal-state boards,139 and the
FTC suggested the Commission consider
the costs and benefits of alternative
arrangements, which presumably would
involve a structure other than an
employment or contractual relationship
between the MMU and the RTO or
ISO.140
137 Exelon
at 25; Strategic Energy at 13; Suez at
9.
138 NJBPU
at 1–2.
PUC at 9–14.
140 FTC at 16–17. No particular alternative
arrangement was suggested.
139 Ohio
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
177. APPA stated that the real issue
to be resolved is not structure but
assuring the independence of the MMU.
It proposed ‘‘rules of the road’’ to
accomplish that objective, most of
which have to do with providing the
MMU with adequate tools with which to
do its job.141 Joint Consumers Advocates
also proposed specific MMU principles,
most involving oversight or tools.142
178. Most commenters supported the
Commission’s proposal that RTOs and
ISOs include in their tariffs a
requirement that they must provide the
MMU with adequate tools with which to
do its job.143 Some stated that access to
resources must be full and unfettered.144
Others, while generally supporting the
proposal, called for budgetary and cost
containment provisions.145 The North
Carolina Commission proposed
transparency of budget, with any
disputes being made subject to
Commission review.146 Some
commenters proposed that the MMU’s
offices be located on the premises of the
RTO or ISO.147 The PJM MMU argued
for control over its own data
repository.148 EEI stated it did not
believe a tariff provision requiring the
MMU to report to the Commission any
concerns it has with adequacy of
resources was needed, as MMUs are in
regular contact with the Commission
and can convey any concerns they may
have in this regard.149
(c) Commission Proposal
179. The Commission agrees with the
bulk of the commenters that the nature
of the MMU structure is not
determinative of either independence or
quality of performance, and proposes
that each RTO and ISO decide for itself,
through its appropriate stakeholder
process, whether it will have an
external, internal or hybrid MMU
structure. The Commission also declines
to remove MMUs from overview by
their RTOs and ISOs; the MMU’s
principal duties involve monitoring
RTO/ISO markets and advising the RTO
or ISO on market performance. The fact
that MMUs also have reporting
obligations to outside parties does not
141 APPA
at 72–73.
Consumer Advocates at 16–19.
143 See, e.g., Ameren at 36–37; Duke Energy at 20;
FirstEnergy at 10; NYISO at 16; Ohio PUC at 12–
14; Portland Cement at 17; Xcel at 23.
144 American Forest at 45; APPA at 70; The
Alliance at 17.
145 EEI at 42; EPSA at 4; Mirant at 11; North
Carolina Commission at 7; Pepco at 15; PJM Power
Providers at 8; PSEG at 17; Reliant at 16.
146 North Carolina Commission at 7.
147 See, e.g., NYISO at 20; North Carolina
Commission at 6.
148 PJM MMU at 10.
149 149 EEI at 43.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
142 Joint
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
change the relationship they have with
the RTOs and ISOs, which are, by
Commission policy, required to
maintain a market monitoring function.
It is also doubtful that an alternative
outside structural arrangement, such as
reporting to a federal-state board, could
as effectively replicate the existing close
exchange of data between the RTO or
ISO and the MMU, which all
acknowledge is vital if the MMU is to
properly perform its duties.
180. The Commission further
proposes that each RTO or ISO include
in its tariff a provision imposing upon
itself the obligation to provide its MMU
with access to market data, resources,
and personnel sufficient to enable the
MMU to carry out its functions. The
RTO or ISO should, in addition, also be
mindful of these obligations in
developing its market monitoring
budget. Furthermore, to ensure
independence of the MMU and its
analyses, the RTO or ISO tariff should
specifically provide that the MMU shall
have access to the RTO’s or ISO’s
database of market information. The
tariff should also specify that any data
created by the MMUs, including
reconfiguring of the RTO/ISO data, be
kept within the exclusive control of the
MMU.
181. The Commission declines to
micro-manage the RTO/ISO
relationships with their MMUs to the
extent of requiring that MMU offices be
located on the RTO/ISO premises. We
are of the view that concerns of this
type, as well as appropriate budgetary
constraints, are best worked out on an
individual basis.
182. The Commission has
reconsidered its ANOPR proposal
regarding inclusion of a tariff provision
directing the MMU to report to the
Commission any concerns it has with
inadequate access to market data,
resources, or personnel, or to describe
the steps it has taken with the RTO or
ISO to resolve these concerns. The
inclusion of such a requirement may
suggest that the Commission anticipates
non-compliance on the part of the RTOs
and ISOs, whereas the opposite is true.
Furthermore, as EEI notes, adequate
mechanisms are already in place for the
MMU to bring any concerns it may have
to the Commission’s attention,
including the complaint process,
referrals to the Commission’s Office of
Enforcement, and informal discussions
with Commission staff.
ii. Oversight
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
183. The Commission noted that an
inherent tension exists in a structure
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12599
that requires MMUs to report to RTO/
ISO management yet, at the same time,
perform evaluations and issue reports
that may be critical of that management.
We stated that it could be difficult for
an MMU to discharge these oversight
and reporting obligations effectively
unless it had some degree of
independence from RTO/ISO
management. The Commission
proposed that each RTO and ISO, in
addition to maintaining a market
monitoring function, be required to have
its MMU, whether internal, external, or
a hybrid combination of the two, report
either directly to the RTO’s or ISO’s
board of directors or directly to a
committee of independent board
directors.150 The ANOPR sought
comment on the Commission’s authority
to impose this type of requirement on
RTOs and ISOs, as well as on the
proposal itself.
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
184. The great preponderance of
commenters agreed with the
Commission’s proposal, stating that
reporting to the RTO or ISO board
would give the MMU more
independence than if the MMU were to
report to management.151 However,
CAISO and NYISO propose that in the
case of a hybrid structure such as theirs
(i.e., one which has both an internal,
employee-staffed MMU and an external,
non-employee-staffed MMU), the
internal MMU be permitted to report to
management, with the external MMU
reporting to the board.152 CAISO states
that this reporting arrangement ensures
that the chief executive officer is
attuned to the needs of the MMU and
that other employees in the organization
are committed to supporting its
functions, while NYISO states that the
arrangement enables its internal market
monitor to work closely with the rest of
company staff and have greater
opportunities to review real-time market
operations. Others suggested that the
MMU report to management for
administrative purposes (such as human
resources and payroll).153
185. A few commenters opposed any
RTO or ISO reporting requirement at all,
preferring that the MMU report to the
150 The ANOPR noted that this policy would
mark a departure from the holding in the PJM Tariff
Order. PJM Tariff Order, 116 FERC ¶ 61,038 at P 38
(2006).
151 See, e.g., BP Energy at 29–30; BlueStar Energy
at 6; Dynegy at 4; EPSA at 45; FirstEnergy at 10;
Industrial Consumers at 21; Joint Consumer
Advocates at 19; Mirant at 11; NARUC at 10;
NEPOOL Participants at 28; Pepco at 15; Steel
Producers at 18.
152 CAISO at 3; NYISO at 26.
153 EEI at 43; SoCal Edison-SDG&E at 10.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12600
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
Commission or to a joint federal/state
board.154 NRECA proposed that the
Commission periodically audit the
quality of the MMU’s reports and
investigations,155 and TAPS proposed
that any change in the MMU’s status,
such as contract termination or renewal,
be reviewed and approved by the
Commission.156
186. Reliant proposed that the MMU
must report to a full cross-section of the
board.157 Conversely, other commenters
felt that management representatives on
the board should be excluded from
MMU oversight.158 PJM agreed with the
ANOPR proposal, but expressed
concern that the board might be given
an oversight responsibility without the
authority to actually oversee the
MMU.159 PJM states that any approach
that does not place responsibility in the
Commission for the functioning and
performance of MMUs, while limiting
the RTO’s ability to supervise or oversee
the MMU, would ‘‘raise serious legal
questions about the Commission’s
ability to limit a public utility’s
management of its business.’’ 160 This
conditional objection was the only
comment that suggested the
Commission may not have the authority
to order the proposed reporting
relationship.161
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
(c) Commission Proposal
187. The Commission proposes that
the MMU, for purposes of supervision
over its market monitoring functions,
should report to the RTO or ISO board
rather than to management. The
Commission further proposes that
management representatives on the
board be excluded from this oversight
function. However, the RTOs and ISOs,
should they deem it appropriate, may
have the MMU report to management
for administrative purposes, such as
pension management, payroll and the
like. Furthermore, the Commission is
sympathetic to the desires expressed by
CAISO and NYISO to retain the
advantages they see in their hybrid
reporting structures. Thus, if an RTO or
154 See, e.g., OMS at 14–15; OPSI at 4–6; Ohio
PUC at 9; North Carolina Commission at 6.
155 NRECA at 26.
156 TAPS at 58.
157 Reliant at 16.
158 OPSI at 4–6; Old Dominion at 22.
159 PJM at 22–24.
160 PJM at 24. PJM argues that the Commission
does not have jurisdiction over utility employment
relationships or contracts with service providers, on
the grounds these functions do not constitute ‘‘a
sale for resale or transmission of electric power in
interstate commerce.’’ PJM at n. 41.
161 California PUC did not disagree that the
Commission can require MMUs to report to the
RTO or ISO board, but requested the Commission
to set forth the basis for this authority and provide
an opportunity to comment. California PUC at 17.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
ISO has two market monitoring bodies,
an internal and an external one, the
Commission proposes that the RTO or
ISO may have the internal MMU report
to management with respect to both its
market monitoring and administrative
functions, and the external MMU report
to the board.
188. The Commission, as noted above,
finds little merit in the suggestions that
the MMU report to a body other than the
RTO or ISO, such as to the Commission
or to a federal/state board. Commenters
afford no details as to how this
structural arrangement could be
achieved, either from an economic,
jurisdictional, or practical point of view,
or how such a potentially cumbersome
structure as a joint inter-governmental
body could oversee MMUs in a timely
and responsive manner. The
Commission itself will be adequately
informed of the results of MMU
monitoring through the referral process
and through the various venues for the
sharing of market information; this
sharing of market information applies as
well to the states and other interested
bodies, who will thereby be adequately
apprised of MMU performance and can
bring any concerns they may have in
this regard to the RTO or ISO or to the
Commission.
189. The Commission declines to
propose a formal auditing procedure for
MMUs, but expects that their work
product will be of the highest quality.
The Commission remains free to
undertake an audit in any given
instance, should that appear to be
appropriate, and any concerns regarding
the quality of MMU work product can
always be brought to the Commission’s
attention. The Commission also declines
to propose a blanket requirement that all
changes in MMU status, such as
contract termination or renewal, be
subject to Commission review and
approval. Although requirements of this
type are currently contained in the
contractual arrangements of certain
RTOs and ISOs,162 the Commission
declines to propose extending this
requirement to all RTOs and ISOs, in
accordance with our reluctance to
162 E.g., Midwest ISO cannot terminate its
agreement with its market monitor (an independent
contractor) without Commission approval. Open
Access Transmission and Energy Markets Tariff for
the Midwest Independent Transmission System
Operator, Inc., Attachment S–1, FERC Electric
Tariff, Third Revised Volume No. 1, Second
Revised Sheet No. 1659 (2005). SPP cannot
terminate its agreement with its external market
monitor without Commission approval. Southwest
Power Pool Open Access Transmission Tariff, FERC
Electric Tariff, Fourth Revised Volume No. 1,
Attachment AJ, § 11, Second Revised Sheet No. 699
(2006). The same is true for ISO–NE. Participants
Agreement among ISO New England, Inc. and the
New England Power Pool, et al., § 9.4.5.
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
impose a ‘‘one size fits all’’ approach in
structural areas. We believe the issue
should be dealt with on a case-by-case
basis.
190. With respect to PJM’s concern
that it may be burdened with oversight
responsibility over MMUs without
possessing full authority to carry out
that responsibility, the Commission
notes that its reporting proposal does
nothing to increase the limitations on an
RTO’s or ISO’s authority over its MMU.
For MMUs that currently report to
management, the proposal merely shifts
oversight from management to the
board.163 Furthermore, the monitoring
functions of MMUs affect sales for resale
and the transmission of electric power
in interstate commerce, and as such are
properly subject to Commission
regulation to ensure MMU objectivity.
As we noted in Order No. 2000,164 the
Commission has a responsibility to
protect against anticompetitive effects in
electricity markets,165 and an
independent MMU is an important
element upon which we rely to
safeguard such competition. Our
proposal maintains oversight authority
within the RTO or ISO, while fostering
MMU independence through the
elimination of direct management
control. For these reasons, the
Commission believes the proposal
strikes the appropriate balance between
MMU independence and RTO/ISO
oversight.
iii. Functions
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
191. Noting that the issue of
independence is integrally related to
that of the functions MMUs are
expected to perform, the Commission
proposed continuing the following
existing functions of MMUs: (1)
Identifying ineffective market rules and
163 PJM cites Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp. v.
FERC, 372 F.3d 395 (DC Cir. 2004), in support of
its concern. However, that case involved FERC’s
attempt to replace existing CAISO board members
with a slate proposed by an independent search
firm. Obviously, alteration of the very composition
of an RTO or ISO board is an entirely different
matter from a requirement that MMUs report to the
board, instead of to management. The latter
requirement in no way interferes with the internal
composition of the board. Furthermore, the cited
case noted that if FERC concluded that CAISO
lacked the independence or other necessary
attributes to constitute an ISO, it need not approve
CAISO as an ISO. Id. at 404. Similarly, it is the
Commission’s view that the MMU may lack
sufficient independence if it reports to
management, rather than to the board; thus we may
require RTOs and ISOs, as a condition of their
continued RTO/ISO status, to incorporate the
proposed requirement in their tariffs.
164 Order No. 2000, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089
at 31,155.
165 See Gulf States Utilities v. FPC, 411 U.S. 747,
758–59 (1973).
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
tariff provisions and recommending
proposed rule and tariff changes; (2)
reviewing and reporting on the
performance of the wholesale markets;
and (3) identifying and notifying the
Commission staff of instances in which
a market participant’s behavior may
require investigation. The Commission
also proposed requiring the MMUs to
advise the Commission and other
interested entities, in addition to the
RTO or ISO, of recommendations for
rule or tariff changes; retaining the
existing Protocols (with appropriate
updates) governing referral of potential
market violations to the Commission,
which are included as an Appendix to
the Policy Statement; 166 and expanding
the subject matter of such referrals to
include suspected rule or tariff
violations committed by an RTO or ISO
as well as by market participants, as
well as suspected violations of other
Commission-approved rules and
regulations, such as Affiliate
Restrictions 167 and Standards of
Conduct.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
192. There was general agreement
from commenters concerning
continuation of the three functions
identified in the ANOPR. Several
commenters stated that MMUs should
not themselves participate in
effectuating market design, although
they should advise the RTO or ISO on
proposed weaknesses in the existing
market design and make suggestions for
improving it.168 A few commenters
opposed reporting suspected RTO or
ISO violations, arguing that this would
impair the frank exchange of
information between RTO or ISO
employees and the MMU.169 However,
most comments on the subject
supported such reporting, and several
commenters suggested that such
reporting be expanded to include
instances of inappropriate dispatch
(either too conservative or too
166 The Commission clarified that since issuance
of the Policy Statement, Market Behavior Rule 2,
referred to in the Protocols, has been rescinded and
replaced by the Commission’s Anti-Manipulation
Rules. Therefore, violations currently to be referred
to the Commission include conduct suspected of
violating the Anti-Manipulation Rules, as well as
tariff violations and violations of the remaining,
codified Market Behavior Rules. See Order No. 674
and Order No. 670.
167 The previous term ‘‘Code of Conduct’’ has
been replaced by ‘‘Affiliate Restrictions’’ in the final
rule for Market-Based Rates for Wholesale Sales of
Electric Energy, Capacity, and Ancillary Services by
Public Utilities, Order No. 697, 72 FR 39,904 (July
20, 2007), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,252 (2007).
168 See, e.g., Old Dominion at 23; OMS at 18;
OPSI at 9; NY TO at 15.
169 NYISO at 25–26; CAISO at 7–8.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
aggressive) which, although not
constituting tariff violations, might
nonetheless impair optimal market
performance.170
193. Several commenters opposed a
requirement that MMUs report
suspected violations of the Standards of
Conduct or Affiliate Restrictions,
arguing that the MMUs do not have
expertise in this area and should not be
diverted from their main task of
monitoring the markets.171 A number of
the comments suggested that the MMUs
should not audit for such violations, but
should report them if they come across
them in the ordinary course of
business.172 Similarly, some
commenters suggested that MMUs
should not audit for suspected rule or
tariff violations by the RTOs or ISOs,
but should report them if they came
across them in the ordinary course of
business.173
194. The commenters generally
supported reporting proposed tariff or
rule changes to other interested parties
as well as to the RTO and ISO,
particularly mentioning market
participants and stakeholders.174
NEPOOL Participants, however,
cautioned that in certain instances this
might effectively broadcast the existence
of a ‘‘loophole’’ that could be exploited
before a rule or tariff change could be
accomplished.175
(c) Commission Proposal
195. The Commission notes that its
proposals in the ANOPR did not
contemplate that the MMU make market
design decisions itself, which are within
the purview of the RTO or ISO through
stakeholder processes and Commission
approval, but rather that the MMU
should advise the RTO or ISO and the
Commission in this area. It was also not
the Commission’s intention that the
MMU be required to seek out potential
violations by the RTO or ISO, or audit
for Standards of Conduct or Affiliate
Restrictions violations. The Commission
agrees that any proactive investigations
in these areas would divert the
resources of the MMU from its primary
responsibilities and potentially embroil
it in areas not within its core expertise.
Standards of Conduct and Affiliate
Restrictions violations in particular may
be difficult to identify without
possession of specialized knowledge.
170 Strategic
Energy at 13.
171 See, e.g., EEI at 45; EPSA at 47; Exelon at 26;
FirstEnergy at 10–11; Pepco at 17.
172 Duke Energy at 23; NYISO at 25–26; ISO–NE
at 8–9.
173 ISO–NE at 8; Duke Energy at 22.
174 See, e.g., Old Dominion at 23; Pepco at 16;
Ameren at 13; APPA at 76–77.
175 NEPOOL Participants at 29–30.
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12601
Therefore, the Commission agrees that
any suspected violations in these areas
need be referred only if discovered in
the ordinary course of the MMU’s
monitoring duties. Any final
determination as to whether a violation
has occurred would, of course, be the
responsibility of the Commission.
196. However, the Commission finds
little merit in the suggestion that our
proposal to require MMUs to report
suspected misconduct by RTOs and
ISOs would impair the frank exchange
of information between RTO or ISO
employees and the MMU. Such an
argument could equally be applied to
scrutiny by any independent entity and,
taken to its logical conclusion, would
effectively exempt RTOs and ISOs from
investigation. Permitting such an
exemption might encourage a culture of
lax adherence to rule and tariff
requirements.
197. The Commission agrees that an
RTO or ISO could conduct dispatch in
such a way as to result in unnecessary
market inefficiencies, and therefore
proposes that the MMU should advise
Commission staff of any substantial
concerns it has along these lines.176
With respect to broadening the reporting
of proposed rule and tariff changes to
other interested parties as well as to the
RTO or ISO, the Commission finds merit
in the concern that such broad
dissemination of information might
make entities aware of a ‘‘loophole’’ that
could be exploited before the necessary
rule or tariff change could be effected.
For that reason, the Commission
proposes that an exception be made to
the general rule of full disclosure, which
exception would provide that in the
event the MMU believes broad
dissemination of such information in a
given instance could lead to
exploitation, that it limit distribution of
the information to the RTO or ISO and
to Commission staff, with an
explanation of why further
dissemination should be avoided at that
time.
198. The Commission therefore
proposes that the functions an MMU is
to perform include the following: (1)
Evaluating existing and proposed
market rules, tariff provisions and
market design elements for their
effectiveness, and recommending
176 If the MMU believes the dispatch practice
rises to the level of a tariff violation, the MMU
should follow the procedures outlined in the
Protocols for referring market violations to the
Commission, which involve a written referral to the
Office of Enforcement with copies to the Office of
Energy Market Regulation and the Commission’s
Office of the General Counsel. Otherwise, its
concerns should be brought to the attention of the
Division of Energy Market Oversight in the Office
of Enforcement.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12602
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
proposed rule and tariff changes not
only to the RTO or ISO, but also to the
Commission’s Office of Energy Market
Regulation staff and to other interested
entities such as state commissions and
market participants, with the caveat that
the MMU is not to effectuate its
proposed market design itself (a task
belonging to the RTO or ISO), and with
the further caveat that the MMU should
limit distribution of its identifications
and recommendations to the RTO or
ISO and to Commission staff in the
event it believes broader dissemination
could lead to exploitation, with an
explanation of why further
dissemination should be avoided at that
time; (2) reviewing and reporting on the
performance of the wholesale markets to
the RTO or ISO, the Commission, and
other interested entities such as state
commissions and market participants;
and (3) identifying and notifying the
Commission’s Office of Enforcement
staff of instances in which a market
participant’s behavior, or that of the
RTO or ISO, may require investigation,
including suspected rule or tariff
violations, market manipulation,
inappropriate dispatch, and suspected
violations of Commission-approved
rules and regulations.
199. In furtherance of its goal of
ensuring independent analysis on the
part of MMUs, the Commission also
proposes that RTOs and ISOs include a
provision in their tariffs specifying that
they may not alter the reports generated
by the MMUs nor dictate the
conclusions reached by the MMUs,
although they may establish a
reasonable mechanism for review and
comment on MMU reports while still in
draft form. The Commission believes
this proposal will enable the MMU to
receive potentially helpful comment,
while removing the ability of the RTO
or ISO to unreasonably influence or
impede the MMU’s analysis.
iv. Mitigation and Operations
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
200. The Commission expressed
concern about whether it was possible
for MMUs to maintain independence in
evaluating and reporting on market
performance while at the same time
providing support to the RTO or ISO in
the administration of its tariff, which
often takes the form of MMU-conducted
market power mitigation. The
Commission noted that because the
operation and mitigation functions
performed by MMUs directly affect
market outcomes and performance, an
inherent conflict arises when an MMU
reports on market outcomes that the
MMU itself has influenced. For these
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
reasons, the Commission proposed
requiring that MMUs refrain from
assisting the RTO or ISO in tariff
administration, from participating in
RTO/ISO market operations such as
mitigation, and from taking direct
actions to influence the market, and
instead concentrate on their role of
providing market evaluation, reports,
and advice.
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
201. As to the issue of tariff
administration, there was substantial,
although not universal, agreement that
this was a task which properly falls
within the purview of the RTO or ISO,
not the MMU. A few commenters took
a middle position, suggesting that in a
hybrid structure, the internal MMU
could be involved in tariff
administration, but not the external
MMU.177 Some commenters requested
clarification as to what was envisioned
in the concept of tariff
administration.178
202. There was no such agreement on
the proposal to remove MMUs from
mitigation, and this issue proved to be
the most contentious one in the entire
market monitoring section. A
substantial minority of commenters
concurred in the ANOPR proposal,
agreeing that it constituted a conflict of
interest for the MMUs to conduct
mitigation, and stating that it would
compromise the MMU’s independence
for it to both evaluate market
performance and conduct mitigation.179
A number of market participants, such
as Dominion Resources, FirstEnergy,
Duke Energy, Dynegy and Pepco,
support the proposal. NCEMC, AWEA,
and Silicon Valley Power also support
the proposal.
203. EPSA stated that the MMU
should not assist tariff administration or
market operations, including mitigation,
on any independent basis not clearly
outlined in the tariff.180 EEI agreed that
there should be a functional separation
between the MMUs and the operational
activities of the RTOs and ISOs, which
EEI states can be accomplished either by
having the RTOs and ISOs perform
operational functions, or having the
internal market monitor perform
them.181
204. A majority of commenters,
representing a spectrum of market
177 EEI at 46; New York PSC at 11–12; NY TO at
16–17.
178 See, e.g., OMS at 25–26; OPSI at 20–22; PSEG
at 17–19.
179 See, e.g., Ameren at 39; Xcel at 24; Dynegy at
5; Duke Energy at 23; EPSA at 45–46; Mirant at 13.
180 EPSA at 45.
181 EEI at 46.
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
participants, consumer groups, and
RTOs and ISOs, opposed the proposal to
remove the MMU from mitigation, and
advanced a variety of reasons against
it.182 Several commenters, including
Portland Cement, the Pennsylvania
PUC, OPSI and OMS, maintained that it
would create an even greater conflict of
interest, because the RTO or ISO would
have a role both in rule development
and implementation.183 Commenters
also stated that the RTO or ISO would
be more heavily influenced than would
an MMU by market participants, upon
whom it depends for its existence, and
that its employees have close personal
relationships with market participants
and are often former employees of
market participants.184 OMS suggested
RTO or ISO management might be
hesitant to perform a needed mitigation
measure if the measure were to affect a
market participant with a credible threat
to leave the RTO or ISO.185 Potomac
Economics suggested the RTO or ISO
can be insulated from market
participant influence by having the
MMU administer mitigation, whereas if
the RTO or ISO had responsibility for
the task it would face the full brunt of
market participant displeasure and
influence.186 Midwest ISO and OPSI
opined that consumers would feel less
confidence in the fair application of
mitigation were the function to be
transferred to the RTO or ISO.187
205. Another argument against the
proposal was voiced by the
Pennsylvania PUC, which stated that
RTO and ISO managers have acquired
their primary expertise in transmission
or generation operations and have little
expertise in economics.188 ISO–NE and
TAPS suggested that administering
mitigation gives the MMU better
familiarity with the working of the
market and assists it in performing its
analytical functions.189 Other
commenters stated that most mitigation
is non-discretionary, and therefore
would not draw the MMU into a
substantial conflict of interest as far as
its analytic tasks are concerned.190 One
commenter suggested that a technical
182 See, e.g., American Forest at 47–49; APPA at
74–77; BP Energy at 31; California PUC at 21–23;
Industrial Coalitions at 21–23; Joint Consumer
Advocates at 20–21; NARUC at 11; NEPOOL
Participants at 30–32; Northeast Utilities at 13–14;
New England Power Generators at 12–13; OMS at
23; OPSI at 13–19; Pennsylvania PUC at 16–17.
183 Portland Cement at 19; Pennsylvania PUC at
16; OPSI at 17; OMS at 23.
184 See, e.g., Portland Cement at 19.
185 OMS at 23.
186 Potomac Economics at 7–8.
187 Midwest ISO at 25–26; OPSI at 13.
188 Pennsylvania PUC at 16–17.
189 ISO–NE at 10–12; TAPS at 59.
190 See, e.g., Potomac Economics at 6.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
conference be convened to examine the
issue.191
206. The RTOs and ISOs, including
ISO–NE, Midwest ISO, and NYISO,
were mainly opposed to removing the
MMU from mitigation.192 CAISO stated
it had no opinion, but wanted
clarification as to whether the ISO or an
independent entity would do the
mitigation.193 SPP stated it did not
object, but indicated that it believed it
would be in compliance if its internal
MMU administered the mitigation
(which was not the intent of the ANOPR
proposal).194 PJM, whose market
monitor does not administer mitigation,
supports the proposal.195
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
(c) Commission Proposal
207. The ANOPR proposal to remove
MMUs from tariff administration was
designed to strengthen their
independence. The current practice of
allowing MMUs to support the RTOs
and ISOs in tariff administration
necessarily makes their role subordinate
to that of the RTOs and ISOs, and thus
weakens that independence.
Furthermore, freeing MMUs from tariff
administration would allow them to
objectively monitor the markets,
without the bias that might arise from
their personal involvement in tariff
administration.
208. Some commenters argue that
RTOs and ISOs do not currently have
individuals qualified to carry out
mitigation. If true, this condition is
simply a reflection of the fact that the
RTOs and ISOs have not needed to hire
such personnel, since the MMUs were
already performing the task for them. If
necessary, RTOs and ISOs could acquire
the staff needed to carry out mitigation
functions, and once this was
accomplished the MMUs would be able
to concentrate on their core job of
monitoring the markets, without the
potential conflict of interest that arises
from reviewing their own mitigation.
209. Several commenters contend that
RTOs and ISOs are more susceptible to
influence from market participants than
are MMUs, and therefore would not be
as diligent in performing mitigation.
However, mitigation is supposed to be
nondiscretionary in nature. RTOs and
ISOs, as well as MMUs, are required to
limit the administration of tariff
compliance to those provisions
expressly set forth in the tariff, involve
objectively identifiable behavior, and do
191 New
England Conference at 19.
at 9–12; Midwest ISO at 25; NYISO
192 ISO–NE
at 23–24.
193 CAISO at 8.
194 SPP at 10.
195 PJM at 25–27.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
not subject the seller to sanctions or
consequences other than those expressly
approved by the Commission and set
forth in the tariff, with the right of
appeal to the Commission.196 That being
the case, any failure by the RTO or ISO
to carry out required mitigation would
be readily apparent to the MMU, whose
job of monitoring the markets
necessarily includes determining
whether mitigation has been properly
performed. Any persistent or substantial
failure by the RTO or ISO in this regard
would constitute a tariff violation and,
as such, should be referred to the
Commission’s Office of Enforcement
staff.
210. The Commission therefore
proposes that MMUs be removed from
tariff administration, including
mitigation. Although we believe the
advantages of doing so outweigh the
temporary transition pains that may
result, we are nonetheless sensitive to
the many concerns raised by those
commenters who oppose the proposal.
We therefore solicit comments on the
activities that would be needed to make
the transition to RTO/ISO-administered
mitigation, on any difficulties the MMU
might be anticipated to experience in
monitoring mitigation performed by the
RTO or ISO, and any additional
sensitivities that commenters wish to
raise regarding the proposal.
v. Ethics
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
211. The Commission proposed
imposing certain minimum ethics
standards upon market monitor
personnel, in particular prohibiting
such personnel from owning financial
interests in any market participants. The
Commission noted that all existing
RTOs and ISOs have some type of
conflict of interest or other ethics
provisions, although not always in their
tariffs, and proposed standardizing such
provisions and requiring their inclusion
in the tariffs themselves.
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
212. Most commenters agreed that
certain minimum ethical standards
should be imposed on MMU employees,
citing in particular conflict of interest
provisions.197 Many argued that the
RTOs and ISOs be allowed the
flexibility to develop their own
provisions, in addition to the core
196 Market Behavior Rules Order, 105 FERC
¶ 61,218 at P 182; Policy Statement, 111 FERC
¶ 61,267 at P 5.
197 See, e.g., Duke Energy at 24; Old Dominion at
25; OMS at 27–28; OPSI at 22; Silicon Valley Power
at 13; Steel Producers at 19.
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12603
minimum set forth by the
Commission.198 Some commenters
thought it unnecessary to include the
standards in the tariffs, suggesting they
could be posted on the RTO or ISO Web
site instead.199
(c) Commission Proposal
213. The Commission agrees with the
majority of the commenters that ethical
standards for MMU employees should
be included in the RTO or ISO tariff.
Such inclusion would allow protest by
intervenors and permit Commission
review and enforcement.
214. In light of the fact that RTOs and
ISOs currently impose ethical standards
on their MMUs, although not always in
their tariffs, and which in some cases
are the same standards they apply to
their other employees, the Commission
proposes that development of the
particular ethical standards to be
applied to MMUs be left in the first
instance to the discretion of the RTOs
and ISOs. However, the Commission
believes these standards should include
certain minimum requirements to be
imposed on MMU employees, as
follows: (i) Employees shall have no
material affiliation (to be defined by the
RTO or ISO) with any market
participant or affiliate; (ii) employees
shall not serve as an officer, employee,
or partner of a market participant; (iii)
employees shall have no material
financial interest in any market
participant or affiliate (allowing for such
potential exceptions as mutual funds
and non-directed investments); (iv)
employees shall not engage in any
market transactions other than the
performance of their duties under the
tariff; (v) employees shall not be
compensated, other than by the RTO or
ISO, for any expert witness testimony or
other commercial services to the RTO or
ISO or to any other party in connection
with any legal or regulatory proceeding
or commercial transaction relating to the
RTO or ISO or to the RTO or ISO
markets; (vi) employees may not accept
anything of value from a market
participant in excess of a de minimis
amount, to be decided on by the RTO
or ISO; and (vii) employees must advise
their supervisor (or, in the case of the
MMU manager himself, advise the RTO
or ISO board) in the event they seek
employment with a market participant
and must disqualify themselves from
participating in any matter that would
198 See, e.g., APPA at 77; EEI at 49; Midwest ISO
at 28; NYISO at 17; Pepco at 18–19.
199 EPSA at 46; Exelon at 27.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12604
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
have an effect on the financial interest
of such market participant.200
vi. Tariff Provisions
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
215. The Commission proposed that
each RTO and ISO set forth all its
provisions involving market monitoring
in one section of its tariff, noting that in
order for MMUs to achieve transparency
of function, the detailed obligations
imposed upon them must be made clear
and accessible, and also be subject to
approval and enforcement by the
Commission.
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
216. There was widespread support
for this proposal, although some
commenters proposed that nonsubstantive MMU provisions be posted
instead on the RTO or ISO Web site.201
Duke Energy proposed that the RTO or
ISO be allowed to perform
centralization of the tariff provisions the
next time it makes an amendment to its
market monitoring rules.202 The PJM
MMU proposed that MMU provisions be
included elsewhere in the tariff as well
as in the MMU section, if the context so
requires.203
(c) Commission Proposal
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
217. In accordance with the bulk of
the comments on this subject, the
Commission proposes that the RTOs
and ISOs be required to include in their
tariffs, and centralize in one section, all
their MMU provisions. Including all
MMU provisions in the tariff will ensure
they are subject to the compliance
requirements that attach to tariff
provisions, and will give notice to
interested parties, and thus an
opportunity to intervene, when a tariff
filing is made. As noted in the ANOPR,
centralization of the MMU provisions
has the obvious advantage of clarity and
ease of reference. The Commission also
proposes that the RTOs and ISOs
include a mission statement for the
MMU in the introductory portions of the
section. This statement should set forth
the goals to be achieved by the MMU,
including the protection of both
consumers and market participants by
the identification and reporting of
200 Some external MMUs may currently have
business associations which would be prohibited
under these proposed minimum requirements, such
as unrelated consulting work for participants in its
RTO’s or ISO’s markets. If that is the case, the RTO
or ISO should propose a suitable transition plan in
its compliance filing.
201 EPSA at 46; Pepco at 19.
202 Duke Energy at 24.
203 PJM MMU at 17.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
market design flaws and market power
abuses.
218. The Commission disagrees with
the comment requesting that the RTOs
or ISOs be permitted to delay
centralization until such time as they
may choose, or otherwise be required, to
make an amendment to their MMU
rules. Such amendments will in all
likelihood be required after issuance of
a final rulemaking in this proceeding,
and in any event the requirement
should not be unduly onerous.
Therefore, the Commission proposes
that the RTOs and ISOs centralize their
MMU tariff provisions when they make
their compliance filings in connection
with this proceeding. The Commission
also sees no reason to forbid the RTOs
and ISOs from posting MMU provisions
elsewhere in their tariffs as well as in
their MMU sections, should clarity and
context so require, as long as
appropriate cross-referencing is made.
b. Information Sharing
219. The Commission advanced
proposals in the ANOPR that responded
to requests of commenters at the
technical conference for dissemination
of expanded market information, and to
a broader group of recipients. In
particular, given the integral
relationship between wholesale and
retail rates, the Commission
acknowledged the need for information
by state commissions to assist them in
performing their regulatory functions.
However, the Commission noted that
since public disclosure of certain
information could harm market
participants or could facilitate collusion
under some circumstances, it was
necessary to balance the need for
information access with confidentiality
concerns. The Commission solicited
comments on the proposed changes.
i. Enhanced Information Dissemination
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
220. The Commission proposed
enhancing the dissemination of
information in several areas.
Specifically, the Commission proposed
that MMUs be required to report
comprehensively on aggregate market
and RTO/ISO performance on a regular
basis, but no less frequently than
quarterly, to Commission staff, to staff of
interested state commissions, and to the
management and board of directors of
the RTOs or ISOs. Further, the
Commission proposed that MMUs
should be required to deliver materials
supporting their conclusions; make one
or more of their staff members available
for a conference call with
representatives from the Commission,
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
state commissions, and RTO or ISO; and
work cooperatively to develop any
further materials which might be useful
to the Commission, to the state
commissions and to the RTOs or
ISOs.204 Finally, the Commission
proposed that offer and bid data,
without identification of the market
participants and with a lag of three
months, be posted on the RTO or ISO
Web site.
221. The Commission requested
comment on whether the proposal met
the needs of the state commissions and
whether there were other kinds of
information needed by state
commissions to fulfill their regulatory
responsibilities. The Commission
further solicited comment on whether
there was a generic standard or test that
could be used to determine what
specific information should be provided
to state commissions.
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
222. No comments were received
proposing a generic standard or test to
determine the specific information that
should be provided to state
commissions. There were relatively few
comments identifying specific types of
data needed; 205 rather, most
commenters supporting greater access
argued that state agencies should
receive all available market information
in order to assist them in their
regulatory tasks.206
223. There was substantial support for
the proposal to require quarterly reports
and conference calls.207 Some
commenters, however, thought
comprehensive reports would be too
costly and unduly time consuming.208
Pepco suggested that these quarterly
204 The Commission clarified that such reports
and meetings were not intended to restrict the
MMU from meeting individually with Commission
staff, staff of state commissions, market
participants, or other stakeholders, or sharing
information with these various constituencies,
subject to appropriate restrictions on
confidentiality.
205 The California PUC set forth a lengthy list of
desired market information, such as confidential
and disaggregated data, bid data, generator dispatch
data, generator performance data, unit commitment,
scheduled and operational levels, and what units
set clearing prices. It cautioned, however, that
California’s needs are specific to its market design
and structure as a single state ISO, and that data
reporting protocols would vary from state to state.
California PUC at 27–30.
206 See, e.g., FirstEnergy at 11; NARUC at 6;
Massachusetts AG at 5; Joint Consumer Advocates
at 22; New York PSC at 13.
207 See, e.g., BlueStar Energy at 6–7; Duke Energy
at 26; Industrial Consumers at 37; NEPOOL
Participants at 32; New England Conference at 19;
North Carolina Electric Membership at 11; NRECA
at 24; Old Dominion at 26.
208 EEI at 50; EPSA at 48; Mirant at 15; Duke
Energy at 26.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
reports not be as extensive as the
current annual reports, in order to avoid
an excessive drain on the money and
resources of the MMUs.209 There was
also concern that confidentiality
protections be observed.210 At least one
commenter suggested that state
attorneys general be included in the
process as well as state commissions,
since not all energy providers and
consumers are associated with entities
regulated by state commissions.211
Some commenters, although recognizing
that inclusion of market participants in
conference calls would be unwieldy,
proposed that they be included in the
dissemination of the reports.212
224. There was substantial comment
on the proposal to reduce the lag period
for offer and bid data to three months,
with a majority either favoring the
Commission’s proposal or not actively
opposing it.213 Some commenters stated
that the lag period should be even
shorter than three months, arguing that
such information is released in
Australia and the United Kingdom in
close to real time, with no apparent
adverse effects.214 Others favored
retention of the six-month period.215
There was substantial support for
something slightly longer than three
months, in order to avoid the problem
of data release within the same season;
such release, it was argued, would
provide opportunities for collusion and
market power abuse.216 EEI notes that
different RTOs and ISOs have reached
differing conclusions as to the
appropriate lag time, and suggested that
the Commission take into account
regional differences, with a lag time no
greater than six months and no less than
three months.217
225. Some commenters argued that
masking the identity of the participants
harmed the smaller players, contending
that the larger players already have
software programs which enable them to
ascertain the identities of the
participants.218 OPSI supported
maintaining confidentiality by the
209 Pepco
at 19–20.
at 19; J. Aron, Barclays, Morgan
Stanley at 6; Old Dominion at 26.
211 APPA at 84. See also LPPC at 15.
212 See, e.g., Old Dominion at 26.
213 See, e.g., Reliant at 22; PJM at 29; PSEG at 20;
SMUD at 15; CAISO at 10; Connecticut and
Massachusetts Municipals at 27; DC Energy at 9;
Massachusetts AG at 5; Midwest ISO at 29;
NEPOOL Participants at 33.
214 Industrial Consumers at 37–38; TAPS at 61.
215 See, e.g., Ameren at 42; Duke Energy at 26–
27; Dynegy at 6; Industrial Coalitions at 24; NJBPU
at 2; PJM MMU at 18.
216 See, e.g., Dynegy at 6; NJPBU at 2; OMS at 35;
OPSI at 29; Old Dominion at 26.
217 EEI at 52–53.
218 Pennsylvania PUC at 18; TAPS at 62.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
210 Constellation
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
aggregation of cost data,219 and Reliant
argued that bidding data should be
masked to avoid matching offers with
the known output of the plant in
question, thereby revealing the identity
of the participant.220
(c) Commission Proposal
226. The Commission declines to
propose a generic standard or test to
determine the type of information that
may be disseminated to state
commissions. Inasmuch as there was no
support for such a standard, the
Commission believes the type of
information to be released may most
fruitfully continue to be developed on a
case-by-case basis, so long as it
generally consists of market analyses of
the type regularly gathered by the
MMUs in the course of business, and so
long as it remains subject to appropriate
confidentiality restrictions.
227. The Commission proposes that
market participants be included in the
dissemination of reports, which could
be accomplished via posting them on
the RTO or ISO Web site. However, the
Commission agrees that including
market participants on conference calls
would be unwieldy, and proposes
limiting participation on such calls to
Commission staff, RTO and ISO staff,
staff of interested state commissions,
and staff of state attorneys general
should they express a desire to attend.
228. The Commission agrees that
quarterly reports should not be as
extensive as the annual state of the
market reports. Preparing overly
extensive reports would divert the
attention of the MMUs from their tasks
of daily monitoring and of providing
recommendations to the RTO or ISO
and the Commission regarding desirable
rule and tariff changes. The Commission
also believes that the annual state of the
market reports have proven to be useful
documents, and proposes that the RTOs
and ISOs include in their tariffs a
requirement for the MMUs to produce
them, with the same dissemination (or
broader, if desired) as the quarterly
reports.
229. The Commission is persuaded by
the comments that no harm generally
would result from shortening the
current six-month lag period.221
However, the Commission
219 OPSI at 30. OPSI includes reference price or
unit estimated cost data within the term.
220 Reliant at 22. Reliant used the term ‘‘bid data,’’
which the Commission assumes refers to offers,
given the company’s concern over matching offers
to unit output.
221 The Commission recently approved the
request of ISO–NE and NEPOOL to shorten the lag
time for release of ISO–NE offer and bid data from
six months to roughly three months. ISO New
England Inc. and New England Power Pool, 121
FERC ¶ 61,035 (2007) (ISO–NE Bid/Offer Order).
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12605
acknowledges that in some instances
release of such information in the same
season could afford opportunities for
collusion.222 Therefore, the Commission
proposes that the time period for the
release of offer and bid data be reduced
to three months, but that the RTO or ISO
may propose a shorter period, with
accompanying justification. However, if
the RTO or ISO demonstrates a potential
collusion concern, it may propose a
four-month lag period or, alternatively,
some other mechanism to delay the
release of a report if the release were
otherwise to occur in the same season
as reflected in the data.
230. The Commission proposes
retaining the practice of masking the
identity of participants when releasing
offer and bid data. The possibility raised
by a few commenters that some players
may be able to surmise the identity of
participants argues, if anything, for
further protection, not for less. The
Commission further proposes that the
RTO or ISO include in its compliance
filing a justification of its policy
regarding the aggregation or lack thereof
of offer data and of cost data, discussing
the manner in which it believes its
policy avoids participant harm and the
possibility of collusion, while fostering
market transparency.
ii. Tailored Requests for Information
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
231. The Commission proposed that
state commissions may make reasonable
requests for additional tailored
information from the MMUs,
acknowledging that information such as
general analyses of the market and
aggregated price data may assist state
commissions in performing their
regulatory functions. The Commission
stated that these requests should be
limited to information regarding general
market trends and performance, and not
encompass information designed to aid
state enforcement or actions against
individual companies. This restriction
was proposed in light of the limited
resources of MMUs and the fact that
states have their own enforcement
agencies which are more properly
employed for such tasks. However, the
Commission proposed that a state
commission could, on a case-by-case
basis, request that the Commission
authorize the release of otherwise
proscribed data. The Commission would
then evaluate whether there was a
222 In the ISO–NE Bid/Offer Order, we found that
the combination of ISO–NE’s ability to
expeditiously file for a rule change if negative
impacts on the market were experienced, and the
existing tariff language that masks the bid/offer
data, adequately protected against the risk of
collusion.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12606
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
compelling need for the requested
information, and decide whether
adequate protections could be fashioned
for commercially sensitive material.
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
232. There was substantial support for
the Commission’s proposal to allow
state commissions to make tailored
requests for information, with the caveat
that such requests should not be
permitted to place too great a burden on
the workload of the MMUs.223 Several
commenters suggested this problem
could be solved by limiting the
information provided by the MMU to
that generated in the ordinary course of
business.224 Other commenters objected
to the restriction prohibiting the release
of information designed for enforcement
purposes, arguing that the states have
little other means of access to the
necessary information.225 A number of
commenters cautioned that requests for
information must be accompanied by
assurances of confidentiality.226 At least
some RTOs and ISOs currently have
provisions in their tariffs governing the
release of confidential information; 227
however, OMS asserts that such tariff
provisions (at least with respect to
Midwest ISO) are so restrictive as to
effectively bar the release of needed
information.228 Several commenters
proposed that before an MMU be
allowed to release information
pertaining to a particular market
participant, that the participant be given
the opportunity to object and to correct
any inaccurate information proposed to
be released.229
(c) Commission Proposal
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
233. The Commission notes that
entertaining tailored requests for
information from state commissions
subjects the MMU to the risk that it will
be diverted from its core functions of
monitoring the market and making rule
and tariff recommendations to the RTO
or ISO. Therefore, the decision as to
whether to respond to such requests,
assuming they otherwise fall within
acceptable parameters, should be made
by the MMU, in light of its budgetary
and time limitations.
223 See, e.g., Reliant at 19; PJM Power Providers
at 10.
224 See, e.g., PJM Power Providers at 10; Exelon
at 28.
225 NARUC at 9; Ohio PUC at 19.
226 Constellation at 19; Joint Consumer Advocates
at 22; Midwest ISO at 30.
227 See, e.g., Midwest ISO at 30; SPP at 11.
228 OMS at 31.
229 See, e.g., EEI at 51; FirstEnergy at 11; DC
Energy at 8.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
234. The Commission continues to
believe its proposed restriction on
information designed for enforcement
purposes is a reasonable one. Such
requests would not only implicate
serious confidentiality concerns, they
could overwhelm the MMU’s workload,
as they would likely involve more
detailed investigations than would be
required for general market information
or for MMU referrals to the Commission.
While states may not have the tools and
expertise to monitor the market as
effectively as can the MMUs, they do
have access to resources to carry out
enforcement functions. Furthermore, the
costs of state enforcement should
rightfully be borne by the states, not by
the MMUs or RTOs and ISOs. Therefore,
the Commission proposes that MMUs
may entertain requests for information
from state commissions, so long as such
information pertains to general market
trends and performance, is not designed
to aid state enforcement or actions
against individual companies,230 and
the MMU can accommodate such
requests within its budgetary and time
constraints without jeopardizing its
ability to perform its core tariff-defined
functions.
235. The Commission also believes
that while confidentiality provisions
serve a useful purpose, they should not
be drafted in such a way as to impose
unnecessary barriers to the
dissemination of information. Therefore,
the Commission proposes that RTOs
and ISOs develop confidentiality
provisions for their tariffs that will
protect commercially sensitive material,
but which will not be so restrictive as
to permit the release of little if any
information.
236. The Commission also agrees that
if requested information pertains to
specific market participants, other than
offer and bid data, that as a matter of
fairness the named market participant
should be given notice and the
opportunity to contest the information.
Therefore, the Commission proposes
that the RTOs and ISOs include such a
provision in their tariffs.
237. In the ANOPR, the Commission
proposed permitting state commissions
to petition the Commission on a caseby-case basis for information that does
not fall within the proposed acceptable
parameters. This safety valve should
alleviate state concerns that they may be
prevented from acquiring information
for which they have a compelling need,
while also ensuring that the
230 However, if during the ordinary course of its
activities an MMU were to discover evidence of
wrongdoing that was within a state commission’s
jurisdiction, it is expected that the MMU would
report such information to the state commission.
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
Commission will be able to examine
such requests in light both of state needs
and the ability to fashion adequate
confidentiality protections. Therefore,
the Commission proposes that the RTOs
and ISOs note the availability of this
exception in their tariffs.
iii. Commission Referrals
(a) Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
238. The Commission stated that
MMUs should continue to respect the
confidentiality of their referrals of
suspected wrongdoing to the
Commission, and not disclose such
referrals to other entities, including state
commissions. The Commission also
expressed its intention not to
disseminate information regarding its
investigations, noting that the
Commission’s rules require that such
information be kept nonpublic unless
the Commission authorizes, in any
given case, that it be publicly
disclosed.231 The Commission noted,
however, that it intended to continue
the practice of Commission staff
providing the MMUs with generic
feedback regarding enforcement issues.
(b) Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
239. Comments were received on both
sides of this issue, with state
representatives arguing for release of
MMU referral information, for the
results of Commission investigations,
and for disclosure of the progress of
Commission investigations.232 Other
commenters acknowledged the legal and
policy considerations noted by the
Commission, and concurred in the need
to maintain confidentiality.233 The
California PUC, while stating that it
understood the need for confidentiality,
proposed that in the event wrongdoing
is discovered that affects a state
commission with appropriate
jurisdiction, that such commission
should be notified of the wrongdoing.234
Some commenters argued that state
bodies have procedures in place to
protect confidentiality, and so should
not be barred from receiving such
information from the MMUs and the
Commission.235 Constellation, however,
cautions that these procedures may not
protect disclosure from Freedom of
231 18 CFR 1b.9 (2007). Other exceptions include
cases where the information has been made a matter
of public record in an adjudicatory proceeding, and
where disclosure is required by the Freedom of
Information Act, 5 U.S.C. 552 et seq. (2006).
232 See, e.g., California PUC at 32; Ohio PUC at
19; OMS at 37–38; OPSI at 31–32.
233 See, e.g., Reliant at 19; Exelon at 29.
234 California PUC at 32.
235 See, e.g., New York PSC at 15; North Carolina
Commission at 7; OPSI at 32.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
Information Act (FOIA) requests or
requests made under equivalent state
statutes.236
variations. NYISO cautioned against the
Commission attempting a pro forma
mitigation provision.
(c) Commission Proposal
240. The Commission notes that the
commenters that argued for the release
of referral and investigative information
to such bodies as state commissions did
not generally address the substantial
legal and policy arguments against such
release, other than to note that some
state bodies have confidentiality
procedures (which may or may not
withstand FOIA-type requests). As the
Commission observed in the ANOPR,
not only do Commission rules prohibit
such release, but release could impede
the willingness of market participants to
self-report and otherwise cooperate in
investigations, and could injure
innocent persons who might be
erroneously implicated or adversely
affected by simply being associated with
an investigation. Therefore, the
Commission proposes that the existing
provisions regarding the confidentiality
of MMU referrals to the Commission, as
well as the confidentiality of the
progress and results of its own
investigations, be retained.
iii. Commission Proposal
243. The Commission had proposed
in the ANOPR that a pro forma MMU
tariff section would be limited to
essential core MMU provisions, such as
functions, oversight, tools and
information sharing, thus freeing the
RTOs and ISOs to propose regional
variations. In light of the fact that in this
NOPR we are proposing that many
important aspects of the market
monitoring relationship with the RTOs
and ISOs be left to the discretion of the
individual RTOs and ISOs, and in light
of the fact that there may well be other
regional variations which the RTOs and
ISOs may wish to propose, the
Commission believes a pro forma tariff
section, which would necessarily have a
large number of blank subsections,
would be of limited value.
244. For that reason, the Commission
proposes that instead of requiring the
RTOs and ISOs to follow the outlines of
a pro forma MMU tariff section, that
they conform their tariff to the
requirements that will be ultimately set
forth in the rulemaking to be issued in
this docket, including centralization of
the MMU provisions in one section. The
Commission also proposes that each
RTO and ISO include in its tariff
protocols for the referral of tariff, rule
and market manipulation violations to
the Office of Enforcement, revised as
discussed above, and for the referral of
perceived market design flaws and
recommended tariff changes to the
Office of Energy Market Regulation.
c. Pro Forma Tariff
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
241. Finally, the Commission in the
ANOPR stated our intent to include in
this NOPR a proposed pro forma MMU
section for RTO/ISO tariffs, which
would contain standardized core
provisions but also allow for regional
variations. The Commission stated that
it anticipates including in the pro forma
MMU section protocols for the referral
of tariff, rule and market manipulation
violations to the Office of Enforcement,
as well as protocols for the referral of
perceived market design flaws and
recommended tariff changes to the
Office of Energy Market Regulation. The
Commission solicited comments on the
structure and content of such a pro
forma section.
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
242. There was substantial support for
a pro forma tariff section of core MMU
provisions. However, a number of
entities, such as the Midwest ISO,
cautioned that a pro forma tariff would
ignore regional variations, disregard
stakeholder consensus and increase
compliance burdens. Those arguing for
a pro forma tariff supported the ANOPR
proposal that each RTO or ISO be given
the flexibility to propose individual
provisions, in order to reflect regional
236 Constellation
VerDate Aug<31>2005
at 19.
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
D. Responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to
Stakeholders and Customers
245. In this section of the NOPR, the
Commission proposes to establish new
criteria intended to ensure that an RTO
or ISO board is responsive to the RTO’s
or ISO’s customers and other
stakeholders. These criteria will
include: (1) Inclusiveness; (2) fairness in
balancing diverse interests; (3)
representation of minority positions;
and (4) ongoing responsiveness. The
Commission proposes to require each
RTO or ISO to submit a compliance
filing demonstrating that it has in place
or will adopt practices and procedures
to ensure that it is responsive to
stakeholders and customers. In the
compliance filing, the Commission
encourages each RTO or ISO to evaluate
what practices and procedures may best
satisfy the responsiveness criteria.
246. In the ANOPR, the Commission
made a preliminary proposal to improve
responsiveness of RTO and ISO boards
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12607
of directors to customers and other
stakeholders. By responsiveness, we
mean an RTO or ISO board’s
willingness, as evidenced in its
practices and procedures, to directly
receive concerns and recommendations
from customers and other stakeholders,
and to fully consider and take actions in
response to the issues that are raised.
We also sought comment on several
issues focusing on whether and how
RTO and ISO responsiveness to
stakeholders can be improved,
including management practices and
stakeholder participation in the
budgeting process.
1. Background
247. In Order No. 888, the
Commission encouraged but did not
require the formation of ISOs,
delineating eleven principles defining
the operations and structure of a
properly functioning ISO.237 Similarly,
in Order No. 2000, the Commission
encouraged utilities to join RTOs
voluntarily and set out the
characteristics that an RTO must
possess and the minimum functions that
it must perform.238 Embodied in Order
Nos. 888 and 2000 is the requirement
that the regional transmission entity be
independent from market participants.
248. Although it required
independence, Order No. 2000 did not
mandate detailed governance
requirements for an RTO board of
directors. The Commission stated that,
given the early stage of RTO formation,
it would be ‘‘counterproductive’’ to
impose a one-size-fits-all approach to
governance when RTOs may have
varying structures based on their
regional needs.239 Therefore, the
Commission stated that it would review
governance proposals on a case-by-case
basis.240 The Commission also provided
guidance based on existing governance
arrangements, emphasizing the
237 Promoting Wholesale Competition Through
Open Access Non-Discriminatory Transmission
Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded
Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities,
Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,036, at
31,730–32 (1996), order on reh’g, Order No. 888–
A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,048, order on reh’g,
Order No. 888–B, 81 FERC ¶ 61,248 (1997), order
on reh’g, Order No. 888–C, 82 FERC ¶ 61,046
(1998), aff’d in relevant part sub nom. Transmission
Access Policy Study Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667
(DC Cir. 2000), aff’d sub nom. New York v. FERC,
535 U.S. 1 (2002).
238 Order No. 2000–A, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,092 at 30,993.
239 Id. at 31,073. The Commission noted that
existing ISOs have varying forms of governance.
Some used a two-tier form of governance with a
non-stakeholder board and advisory committees of
stakeholders while one ISO in particular, CAISO,
employed a decision-making board consisting of
both stakeholders and non-stakeholders. Id.
240 Id. at 31,073–74.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12608
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
importance of stakeholder input
regarding both RTO formation and
ongoing operations. The Commission
stated that stakeholder committees
should have balanced representation on
such committees so that no one
stakeholder class dominates the
committee’s recommendations. The
Commission added that, in the case of
a non-stakeholder board, it is important
that this board not become isolated.241
For these reasons, the Commission
explained that both formal and informal
mechanisms should be used to ensure
that stakeholders can convey their
concerns to the non-stakeholder board.
This standard is no different for
currently-operating ISOs, as the ISO
principle of independence requires fair
representation of all types of users of the
system to ensure that the ISO formulates
policies, operates the system, and
resolves disputes in a fair and nondiscriminatory manner.242
2. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR
249. In the ANOPR, the Commission
made the preliminary conclusion that
representatives of RTO and ISO
customers and other stakeholders
should have some form of effective
direct access to the RTO or ISO board
of directors.243 The Commission asked
whether each RTO and ISO should be
required to develop and implement a
means to ensure that customers and
other stakeholders have such access.244
The Commission made the preliminary
proposal that either of two mechanisms,
a hybrid board or a board advisory
committee, could accomplish the goal of
enhancing customer and other
stakeholder access to the board.245
250. The Commission explained that
a hybrid board would be composed of
both independent members and
stakeholder members, with each
member holding a seat on the board and
participating fully in board decisions
with an equal vote. The Commission
stated that a hybrid board would
directly expose the board to
stakeholders’ concerns and that it
believed that it should be possible to
structure a hybrid board without
sacrificing overall board
independence.246
251. Alternatively, the Commission
suggested that a board advisory
241 Id.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
242 Order
No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,036
at 31,730–31.
243 ANOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,617 at P 148.
244 Id. P 149.
245 Id. P 151, 153.
246 The Commission also noted that certain
restrictions may be necessary for the hybrid board
proposal to ensure that stakeholder members do not
inappropriately serve their own interests. Id. P 152.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
committee, comprised of senior
executives of the various stakeholder
groups, could serve as an expert panel
that would inform the board of
stakeholder views. The board advisory
committee would have no voting
authority on board decisions, but could
make recommendations directly to the
board on matters before the board and
on matters it believes the board should
address. The Commission stated that it
envisioned such a committee to include
members selected to represent a
reasonable range of diverse interests.247
252. Based on these two models of
improving RTO and ISO responsiveness,
the Commission sought comments on
the following questions:
• How should any hybrid board be
structured? What is an appropriate limit
on the percentage of non-independent
board members? If a variety of customer
views are to be represented, what
implications does this have for the size
of the board?
• What, if any, rules and restrictions
should be placed on the stakeholder
board members of a hybrid board?
• Can the reform proposed here be
met through other means such as
increased direct board interaction with
customers and other stakeholders, e.g.,
through open board meetings or through
required attendance of board members
at major stakeholder meetings of the
RTO?
• Are there measures—such as
customer satisfaction measures, cost
oversight benchmarks, or stakeholder
participation measures—that RTOs and
ISOs should use to assess the success of
the mechanism for improving
responsiveness?
253. In the ANOPR, the Commission
also requested comment on whether any
reforms are necessary to increase
management responsiveness to
stakeholders. Among specific topics, the
Commission requested comment on
whether it should encourage or require
RTOs and ISOs to publish a strategic
plan that includes plans for ensuring
responsiveness to customers and
stakeholders, set performance criteria
for executive managers based in part on
responsiveness to stakeholders, and
relate executive compensation to a
measure of responsiveness to
stakeholders.
3. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals
and Questions
254. The Commission received
numerous responses from commenters
regarding the questions posed in the
ANOPR. A majority agrees with the
Commission’s conclusion that more
247 Id.
PO 00000
P 153–54.
Frm 00034
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
effective direct access to RTO and ISO
boards is needed. They do not agree,
however, on the mechanism to achieve
that goal. Some commenters favor the
hybrid board, but many express concern
with this approach, preferring the board
advisory committee. Several
commenters support using both a hybrid
board and a board advisory
committee,248 noting that the two
approaches are not mutually
exclusive.249 Several commenters
discussed changes in RTO and ISO
management practices to improve the
responsiveness.
a. Comments on the Hybrid Board
Approach
255. Some commenters support the
proposal for a hybrid board approach,
stating that a hybrid board would
improve RTO responsiveness and allow
stakeholder access to an RTO and ISO
board.250 While they believe that such a
board would be a good mechanism to
achieve the Commission’s goal, they
also state that some requirements on
how such a board should be structured
are necessary. For example, California
Munis state that stakeholder board
members should not form a majority of
an RTO’s or ISO’s board under a hybrid
board form of governance.251 SMUD
states that a hybrid board should
include diverse representation and must
be properly balanced so that no single
interest is unduly influential.252 TAPS
recommends that within a hybrid board,
independent directors should hold a
majority of board seats to prevent
capture by stakeholders.253 Further,
before implementing the hybrid board
approach, the Connecticut and
Massachusetts Municipals recommend
that the Commission provide clarity
regarding any possible conflict of
interest concerns among stakeholder
directors.254
256. Industrial Consumers
recommend that the Commission
require each RTO or ISO to establish a
hybrid board, but only if representatives
of loads (large and small customers) are
assured equal representation with
248 E.g., AEP at 7; Ameren at 44; APPA at 88.
SMUD states that the Commission should explore
both approaches. SMUD at 20–22.
249 NYISO suggested a shared governance model
as an alternative to the hybrid board and the board
advisory committee models proposed in the
ANOPR. NYISO at 6.
250 E.g., California Munis at 15; Silicon Valley
Power at 15; Connecticut and Massachusetts
Municipals at 16; Wisconsin Industrial at 11; TAPS
at 34; Industrial Consumers at 40.
251 California Munis at 15.
252 SMUD at 21.
253 TAPS at 34.
254 Connecticut and Massachusetts Municipals at
17.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
supply-side interests. They note that
Electric Reliability Council of Texas
(ERCOT) already has a hybrid board.255
Industrial Consumers propose that nonindependent stakeholder members
should represent less than half of the
total ISO and RTO board (unlike in
ERCOT). They add that an equal number
of stakeholders should represent
supply-side and demand-side
(consumer) interests.256 To that end,
Industrial Consumers state that it may
be necessary to require some form of
rotation among stakeholder groups.
Finally, they note that all existing ISO
and RTO boards already have a
‘‘hybrid’’ feature because some members
are retired utility executives, and they
urge the Commission to consider
counting such members as stakeholders
in hybrid boards.
257. Wisconsin Industrial also
recommends a hybrid board structure,
with the condition that end-use
customer and supplier representation be
equal. Wisconsin Industrial believes
that a hybrid board has an advantage in
that a variety of stakeholder interests
can be objectively and directly
represented without first being filtered
through RTO and ISO management.257
258. Further, several of the
commenters that support the hybrid
board oppose the advisory board
committee, noting that such a
committee would not provide for direct
discussion and information exchange,
and that its advice could be ignored by
board members.258 Others note the
disadvantages of an advisory board
committee.259
259. Many commenters, however, do
not support the hybrid board approach,
emphasizing that a hybrid board can,
among other things, jeopardize the
independence of an RTO or ISO
255 Industrial Consumers note that the ERCOT
hybrid board is composed of the following: (1) Five
unaffiliated independent board members (two serve
as chair and vice chair); (2) independent power
marketers; (3) industrial consumers; (4) commercial
consumers; (5) independent retail electric
providers; (6) electric cooperatives; (7) residential
consumers; (8) investor-owned utilities; (9)
independent generators; and (10) municipallyowned utilities. Industrial Consumers at 41.
256 For example, a ten-member board would have
four stakeholder members: two representing
suppliers and two representing consumers. Id.
257 Wisconsin Industrial at 11.
258 E.g., TAPS at 40–42.
259 For example, Indianapolis P&L notes that,
while the Midwest ISO advisory committee
provides some value, it faces challenges in its
communication with the board of directors because
management views are sometimes at odds with
stakeholder views, the time for the advisory
committee to consult with the board on technically
complex issues is limited, and competing messages
from committee members dilute and muddle the
message. Indianapolis P&L at 6–7.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
board.260 They contend that RTO and
ISO independence must be preserved
because it gives participants in
organized wholesale markets the
confidence that: (1) The markets are
being administered fairly; (2)
proprietary and critical infrastructure
information is being protected; and (3)
customers will ultimately receive the
benefits of competition.
260. Many commenters argue that
stakeholder representation on a hybrid
board would conflict with stakeholders’
fiduciary responsibility to their
employers, making it difficult for the
stakeholder member to be impartial
when the goal of that member’s
organization is to maximize its
company’s profits. Therefore, they note
that it is unrealistic to expect
stakeholder board members to refrain
from acting in the best interests of the
entity with which they are affiliated.
261. Some commenters also question
whether a hybrid board can ensure fair
representation, arguing that smaller
companies are less likely to have the
resources necessary to participate in
such a board,261 thus not all sectors of
the market would be fairly represented,
resulting in the potential for undue
influence.
262. To address those concerns for
undue influence, commenters have
suggested that the selection of nonindependent board members should
require a supermajority vote. APPA
recommends that RTO and ISO
stakeholder directors be elected by a
supermajority of stakeholder sectors,
contending that stakeholder
representatives should be balanced
between generation and load
interests.262 APPA further expands on
its proposal by stating that using a
supermajority election process will
‘‘ensure that well-respected and
knowledgeable members of the
stakeholder community serve in this
capacity.’’ 263 TAPS suggests that a
supermajority vote requirement for
selection of stakeholder board members
would go a long way to mitigate
concerns that the stakeholder board
members would use their position
260 E.g., California PUC at 34–35; DC Energy at 9;
Comverge at 12; Dominion Resources at 10; Duke
Energy at 29; Dynegy at 7; FirstEnergy at 12;
Industrial Coalitions at 27; ITC at 5–13; Joint
Consumer Advocates at 24; North Carolina
Commission at 8; OMS at 42; NARUC at 12; Old
Dominion at 31; Pepco at 22; The Alliance at 19;
Xcel at 27.
261 E.g., Comverge at 12; Industrial Coalitions at
25–28; The Alliance at 19–20.
262 APPA at 13.
263 Id. at 93.
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12609
inappropriately to advance their
parochial interests.264
263. Further, some commenters
contend that a hybrid board composed
of both independent and stakeholder
members could complicate and impede
effective board decision-making because
of the effort of non-independent
stakeholders to serve their own
interests.265 They note that a hybrid
board is far more likely to be unwieldy
and ineffective because of the need to
represent so many different market
interests. Several commenters also argue
that the Commission does not have the
legal authority to dictate the
composition of the board of a
Commission-regulated entity.266
b. Comments on the Board Advisory
Committee Approach
264. Many commenters indicate that
having a board advisory committee is
the preferable approach to achieving the
Commission’s goal of improving
responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs.267
They state that a board advisory
committee with a wide range of
stakeholder interests that has direct
access to the board of directors would
increase RTO and ISO responsiveness
and be the most effective way to balance
the interests of stakeholders.
265. Several commenters state that a
board advisory committee would be a
good starting point for improving
communications between the board and
stakeholders. For example, North
Carolina Electric Membership believes
that a board advisory committee would
allow stakeholders to provide and
receive strategic insight to the boards.268
In addition to such a committee, it notes
the need for more opportunities for
communication between the board and
the stakeholders. Such communication
can be achieved by board member
attendance at major stakeholder
meetings and by board solicitation of
stakeholder position papers on relevant
264 TAPS at 45. Both APPA and TAPS reference
a similar recommendation from a Wisconsin Public
Power Inc. (WPPI) white paper, contained as
Attachment A to the TAPS comments. WPPI
suggests that ‘‘selection of the interested [nonindependent] board members should require
supermajority voting approval’’ and that ‘‘an
election of an interested board member should
require an affirmative vote of 67 [percent] of all
sectors.’’ Id. at 70.
265 E.g., Alcoa at 28; DC Energy at 10; California
PUC at 35.
266 See, e.g., California PUC at 35 (citing Cal.
Indep. Sys. Operator Corp. v. FERC, 372 F.3d 395
(DC Cir. 2004)).
267 E.g., California PUC at 36; Comverge at 12;
Suez at 9; Old Dominion at 31; OPSI at 42; Joint
Consumer Advocates at 24; North Carolina
Commission at 9; NARUC at 12; Pepco at 22–23;
Xcel at 27–28.
268 North Carolina Electric Membership at 4.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12610
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
issues.269 A few of the commenters also
note that they support open RTO and
ISO board meetings.270
266. Some commenters suggest
guidelines on how a board advisory
committee should be structured and
how it should function. For example,
OPSI states that the board advisory
committee: (1) Must have authority to
make recommendations directly to the
board on matters before the board and
on matters it believes the board should
address; (2) must be required to allow
for the communication of minority
views to the board; and (3) should have
membership limited to a reasonable
number of individuals.271 OPSI and
NARUC recommend that state
commissions and state consumer
advocates be entitled to representation
on the board advisory committee.272
North Carolina Commission proposes
that the board advisory committee
should be given the right to suggest
nominees to board positions and that
the RTO and ISO board could be
required to respond in writing to
proposals submitted by the advisory
committee.
267. Additionally, LPPC states that a
board advisory committee must be
closely involved in RTO and ISO board
discussions, must represent a broader
range of stakeholder interests, and
should supplement, not replace,
existing stakeholder representation on
operating technical committees.273
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
c. Comments on the Need To Increase
Management Responsiveness
268. APPA, TAPS, and the
Connecticut and Massachusetts
Municipals recommend that RTO and
ISO mission statements and/or charters
clearly define consumer-oriented goals.
269 For example, North Carolina Electric
Membership suggests ‘‘town hall’’ sessions for
members where board attendance is required on
topics derived by the liaison committee (i.e., board
advisory committee). It also notes that requiring the
board to explain the basis for its decision on
particular issues in writing could improve
communication and add transparency to the
process. North Carolina Electric Membership at 5.
270 For example, the OMS believes that an open
board meeting would allow stakeholders to assess
the nature and quality of the information being
provided to the board, whether the board has
adequately understood and considered stakeholder
issues and concerns, and whether the board has
made a fair and balanced decision. OMS at 43. In
contrast, SMUD does not support open board
meetings, but suggests that a better alternative may
be for boards to hold technical sessions with
stakeholders for information gathering before board
meetings take place. SMUD at 22.
271 OPSI at 43.
272 Id. See also NARUC at 12.
273 LPPC at 17. See also Industrial Consumers at
41 (suggesting that a board advisory committee
should be balanced, be charged with electing the
board members, and be responsible for approving
any changes in the bylaws).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
They recommend that these documents
be modified to require the RTO or ISO
to provide ‘‘reliable service at the lowest
possible reasonable rates,’’ 274 or similar
wording to that effect. APPA would
include an explicit obligation that the
RTO or ISO work to reduce power costs
to consumers.
269. Several commenters also
addressed the topic of performance
criteria for executive managers’
responsiveness to stakeholder and
consumer interests. For example, DC
Energy supports the Commission
requiring each RTO and ISO to take
steps to ensure management
responsiveness, such as stakeholder
input on public strategic plans, periodic
measurement of customer satisfaction,
and RTO- or ISO-developed
performance criteria for executive
managers with a focus on reliability and
market efficiency criteria.275 North
Carolina Commission suggests the
Commission focus on measures of
responsiveness such as timely responses
to customer or stakeholder requests.276
The North Carolina Commission also
suggests that the Commission should
focus on behavior-based measures to
improve RTO and ISO effectiveness,
such as whether the RTO and ISO has
clear staff assignments; whether it has
contact information easily available on
its Web site; the length of time for a
stakeholder to secure an answer to a
question; how long it takes a market
participant to receive a correction of a
billing or settlement error; and how
often transmission service or
interconnection studies are delayed.
LPPC suggests four areas that should be
covered in performance measures
include accomplishment of the mission,
ability to meet budget projections,
compliance with NERC standards, and
measured stakeholder satisfaction.277
CAISO supports Commission adoption
of performance criteria for executive
managers, stating that it has already
implemented most of the ANOPR
proposals, including an incentive
compensation program for all
employees that contains specific goals
for improving stakeholder processes and
timely response to stakeholder
inquiries.278
d. Comments on Regional Differences
270. In addition to the two
approaches described in the ANOPR,
several commenters suggest that the
Commission should allow for regional
274 TAPS
at 33.
Energy at 10.
276 North Carolina Commission at 9–10.
277 LPPC at 19.
278 CAISO at 14.
275 DC
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
differences, and not administer a onesize-fits-all approach.279 Instead, given
the differences among RTOs and ISOs in
governance and stakeholder needs, the
Commission should require RTOs and
ISOs to work with customers and other
stakeholders to create programs specific
to each regional entity. For example, EEI
notes that it is important that each RTO
and ISO have the flexibility to adopt the
means of direct stakeholder access that
is most effective for that particular RTO
or ISO.280 NARUC also notes that
stakeholder representation in RTO and
ISO processes is not uniform across all
sectors; therefore, it urges the
Commission to review RTO and ISO
processes to ensure equivalent treatment
of all stakeholders.281
271. OPSI recommends that the
Commission not impose particular
mandates, but should express its
intention to hold RTO and ISO boards
accountable, and leave it to the boards
to develop appropriate ways to ensure
such responsiveness. OPSI also urges
the Commission to establish an annual
opportunity for interested parties to
submit an assessment of the RTO’s or
ISO’s performance in the preceding year
to the Commission.282
4. The Need for Commission Action
272. In Order No. 2000, the
Commission determined that
independence is a required
characteristic necessary for an RTO to
prevent any undue discrimination and
to bring benefits to market participants.
In that respect, the Commission stated
that an RTO’s decision-making process
must be independent in both reality and
perception.283 The Commission did not
believe that detailed guidance regarding
governance structure was necessary
given the early stage of RTO formation
and the varying structures of governance
among regional entities. Instead, the
Commission required RTOs to have an
‘‘open architecture’’ so that the
organization and its members would
have the necessary flexibility to improve
the structure, geographic scope, market
scope, and operations of the
279 E.g., Allegheny at 7; ISO–NE at 31–33; EPSA
at 50; Pepco at 23; SPP at 12–13; National Grid at
17–20; EEI at 57–61.
280 EEI recommends that the Commission issue a
policy statement declaring that stakeholders should
have effective direct access to RTO and ISO boards
and executive management. It also argues that ‘‘the
Commission should not take any action that would
require the basic structure of RTOs and ISOs and
their underlying governing contracts, such as the
transmission owners’ agreement, to be reopened
without the consent of the parties involved.’’ EEI at
59.
281 NARUC at 13.
282 OPSI at 45.
283 Order No. 2000, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089
at 31,061.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
organization. Although the Commission
required that proposed changes
continue to satisfy RTO minimum
characteristics and functions,284 open
architecture allowed the original RTO
design to evolve to reflect changes in
member needs.
273. Since Order No. 2000 was issued,
RTOs and ISOs have evolved. Given the
size and complexity of RTOs and ISOs
today, it is not surprising that tension
has arisen between the goals of
independent decision-making and
responsiveness to stakeholders, as an
RTO or ISO cannot satisfy every group
on every issue. The RTO and ISO
management and boards of directors
face increasing difficulty (as well as
increasing responsibility) in
understanding the impact of their
decisions on the various stakeholder
classes. Attempting to accommodate
stakeholders’ needs on each issue has
been a difficult task borne by the boards
and other employees of the RTOs and
ISOs.
274. Creating a mechanism and
process to enable the board to be
responsive to the needs of stakeholders
is critical to an independent governance
structure. Moreover, it is necessary for
customers and other stakeholders to
have confidence in the decisions that
come out of RTO and ISO processes.
Similarly, management responsiveness
to customers and stakeholders plays an
important role in implementing the RTO
and ISO policies and achieving its
objectives in a manner that customers
and other stakeholders perceive to be
fair, balanced, and effective. The
Commission proposes a set of criteria,
discussed below, for assessing the
mechanism or process by which an RTO
or ISO achieves board responsiveness to
its members and customers.
5. Proposed Reform
275. The Commission proposes to
require each RTO and ISO to
demonstrate in a compliance filing that
it is achieving RTO and ISO
responsiveness, and we propose to
assess the filed practices or procedures
for achieving RTO and ISO board
responsiveness using the following
criteria: (1) Inclusiveness; (2) fairness in
balancing diverse interests; (3)
representation of minority positions;
and (4) ongoing responsiveness. We
believe that access by customers and
other stakeholders to the board based on
these criteria will provide them with the
opportunity to ensure that their
concerns are considered. We also
believe that any RTO or ISO practices or
procedures that satisfy these criteria
284 Id.
at 31,170.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
12611
will ensure that RTO and ISO boards
and management are reasonably
responsive to the needs of RTO and ISO
members and customers.
276. Accordingly, an RTO or ISO
must comply with this proposed
requirement by submitting a filing that
proposes changes to its responsiveness
practices and procedures to comply
with the proposed requirement or that
demonstrates its practices and
procedures already satisfy the
requirement for responsiveness. This
filing would be submitted within six
months of the date the final rule is
published in the Federal Register. The
Commission will assess whether each
filing satisfies the proposed requirement
and issue additional orders as
necessary.
277. The Commission agrees with
commenters that a one-size-fits-all
approach may not be beneficial given
the varying structure and needs of each
regional entity. Therefore, instead of
prescribing a specific mechanism for all
RTOs and ISOs, the Commission
proposes to take a flexible approach.
Various mechanisms may satisfy the
proposed criteria. We encourage each
RTO or ISO to develop a mechanism
that best suits its own governance
structure and stakeholder needs. The
Commission presented two options for
consideration, the board advisory
committee and the hybrid board.285
While we view the board advisory
committee as a particularly strong
mechanism for enhancing
responsiveness, the Commission expects
each RTO or ISO and its stakeholders to
develop the mechanism that best suits
its needs.
278. We seek comment, however, on
whether RTOs and ISOs should be
encouraged, or required, to base their
process for selecting non-independent
members of the board or of a board
advisory committee on a supermajority
vote of eligible stakeholders.
279. We propose to require each RTO
and ISO, in its compliance filing, to
demonstrate that it has satisfied the
following criteria:
• Inclusiveness—The practices and
procedures must ensure that any
customer or other stakeholder affected
by the operation of the RTO or ISO, or
its representative is permitted to
communicate its views to the RTO or
ISO board.
• Fairness in Balancing Diverse
Interests—The practices and procedures
must ensure that the interests of
customers or other stakeholders are
equitably considered and that
deliberation and consideration of RTO
and ISO issues are not dominated by
any single stakeholder category.
• Representation of Minority
Positions—The practices and
procedures must ensure that, in
instances where stakeholders are not in
total agreement on a particular issue,
minority positions are communicated to
the board at the same time as majority
positions.
• Ongoing Responsiveness—The
practices and procedures must provide
for stakeholder input into RTO or ISO
decisions as well as mechanisms to
provide feedback to stakeholders to
ensure that information exchange and
communication continue over time.
280. The Commission proposes to
require that each RTO and ISO post on
its Web site a mission statement or
charter for its organization. The
Commission encourages each RTO and
ISO to set forth in these documents the
organization’s purpose, guiding
principles, and commitment to
responsiveness to customers and other
stakeholders, and ultimately to the
consumers who benefit from and pay for
electricity services.
281. We also encourage each RTO and
ISO to ensure that its management
programs, including, but not limited to,
incentive compensation plans for
executive managers, give appropriate
weight to stakeholder responsiveness.
Such plans should give appropriate
consideration to important service
delivery goals such as reducing
congestion costs, timely response to
transmission service requests, prompt
resolution of statements, billing, and
disputes, and other customer service
measures of performance.286
285 Any RTO or ISO that chooses to propose a
hybrid board structure must ensure that the nonindependent board members constitute less than a
majority of the board and must limit the eligibility
to be a non-independent board member to market
participants in that RTO or ISO market.
286 The Commission understands that RTO and
ISO executive management compensation plans
may already be based on various measures of
performance. If these already adequately take
account of customer responsiveness, the RTO or
ISO may report this in its compliance filing.
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
V. Applicability of the Proposed Rule
and Compliance Procedures
282. The Commission has a
responsibility under FPA sections 205
and 206 to ensure that the rates, charges,
classifications, and service of public
utilities (and any rule, regulation,
practice, or contract affecting any of
these) are just and reasonable and not
unduly discriminatory, and to remedy
undue discrimination in the provision
of such services. Our action in this
NOPR proposes to fulfill those
responsibilities by proposing reforms to
improve the operation of organized
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12612
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
wholesale markets. It is necessary to
remedy any problems in wholesale
markets to ensure that rates and services
in RTO and ISO markets remain just and
reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory.
283. The Commission proposes to
apply the final rule in this proceeding
to all RTOs and ISOs by requiring them
to demonstrate compliance with the
proposed requirements discussed in
each section of the NOPR: (1) Demand
response; (2) long-term power
contracting; (3) market monitoring; and
(4) RTO and ISO responsiveness. The
Commission proposes to require each
RTO and ISO to report to the
Commission, on the deadlines specified
below or six months following its
certification as an RTO or
commencement of operations as an ISO,
that describes whether the entity is
already in compliance with the
requirements of the final rule, or
describing its plans to attain
compliance, including a timeline with
intermediate deadlines and appropriate
proposed tariff and market rule
revisions. The Commission will assess
whether each filing satisfies the
proposed requirements and issue further
orders for each RTO and ISO.
284. For the proposed requirements
under demand response, the filing
addressing ancillary services and
deviation charges, and the filing for
ARCs and shortage pricing must be
submitted within six months of the date
the final rule is published in the Federal
Register.
285. The filing to comply with the
proposed requirements regarding longterm contracts, MMU reforms and RTO
responsiveness must be submitted
within six months of the date the final
rule is published in the Federal
Register.
VI. Information Collection Statement
286. The Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) regulations require
approval of certain information
collection requirements imposed by
agency rules.287 Upon approval of a
collection(s) of information, OMB will
assign an OMB control number and an
expiration date. Respondents subject to
the filing requirements of this rule will
not be penalized for failing to respond
to these collections of information
unless the collections of information
display a valid OMB control number.
This NOPR amends the Commission’s
regulations to improve the operation of
organized wholesale electric power
markets. The objective of this proposed
rule is to improve market design and
competition in organized markets.
Through this rule the Commission
hopes to provide remedies by ensuring
(1) that new criteria are established so
RTOs and ISOs are responsive to their
customers and stakeholders; (2) improve
market monitoring within RTOs and
ISOs by requiring them to provide their
Market Monitoring Units with access to
Number of
respondents
Data collection
market data and sufficient resources to
perform their duties; (3) transparency in
the marketplace by requiring RTOs and
ISOs to dedicate portions of their Web
sites so market participants can avail
themselves of information concerning
offers to buy or sell power on a longterm basis; and (4) require RTOs and
ISOs to institute certain reforms in the
demand response programs to remove
several disincentives and barriers to
provide for more efficient operation of
markets while at the same time
encouraging new technologies. Filings
by RTOs and ISOs would be made
under Part 35 of the Commission’s
regulations. The information provided
for under Part 35 is identified as FERC–
516.
287. The Commission is submitting
these reporting requirements to OMB for
its review and approval under section
3507(d) of the Paperwork Reduction
Act.288 Comments are solicited on the
Commission’s need for this information,
whether the information will have
practical utility, the accuracy of
provided burden estimates, ways to
enhance the quality, utility, and clarity
of the information to be collected, and
any suggested methods for minimizing
the respondent’s burden, including the
use of automated information
techniques.
Burden Estimate: The Public
Reporting burden for the requirements
contained in the NOPR is as follows:
Number of
responses
Hours per
response
Total annual
hours
6
5
6
6
6
6
6
6
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
433
288
102.5
649
30
129
180
650
2,598
1,440
615
3,894
180
774
1080
3,900
Totals ........................................................................................................
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
FERC–516 Task Allow demand response to provide certain ancillary services ...............................................................................................................
Remove certain deviation charges ..................................................................
Permit aggregation of Retail Customers .........................................................
Allow pricing to ration demand during a shortage ...........................................
Long-term contract postings ............................................................................
MMUs ...............................................................................................................
Require RTO board responsiveness to customers .........................................
Require RTO self-assessment .........................................................................
........................
........................
........................
14,481
Total Annual Hours for Collection:
(Reporting + recordkeeping, (if
appropriate)) = Total hours for
performing tasks 1 through 8 as
identified above = 14,481 hours.
Information Collection Costs: The
Commission seeks comments on the
costs to comply with these
requirements. It has projected the
average annualized cost to be:
Legal expertise = $473,526 (2,368 hours
@ $200 an hour)
287 5
CFR 1320.11 (2007).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Technical Expertise = $712,038 (4,747
hours @ $150 an hour) (RTO/ISO
Senior Staff, Stakeholder participants)
Administrative Support = $108,701
(2,718 hours @ $40 an hour)
IT Support = $236,448 (2,489 hours @
$95 an hour)
Participatory Expenditures = $2,160,000
(96 participants @ $1,000 per day on
average 4.5 days per activity for five
of the eight activities identified above)
Total = $3,690,713
288 44
Jkt 214001
PO 00000
* Differences in RTO/ISO staff hourly
rates are to differentiate between
administrative support staff and senior
staff.
Total cost estimates: $3,690,713.
Title: FERC–516 ‘‘Electric Rate
Schedule Filings’’.
Action: Proposed Collections.
OMB Control No: 1902–0096.
Respondents: Business or other for
profit, and/or not for profit institutions.
Frequency of Responses: One time to
initially comply with the rule, and then
U.S.C. 3507(d) (2000).
Frm 00038
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
on occasion as needed to revise or
modify.
Necessity of the Information: This
proposed rule, if adopted, would further
the improvement of competitive
wholesale electric markets and the
provision of transmission services in the
RTO and ISO regions. The Commission
recognizes that significant differences
exist among the regions, industry
structures, and sources of electric
generation, population demographics
and even weather patterns. In fulfilling
its responsibilities under sections 205
and 206 of the Federal Power Act, the
Commission is required to address, and
has the authority to remedy, undue
discrimination and anticompetitive
effects.
Internal review: The Commission has
reviewed the requirements pertaining to
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets and
determined the proposed requirements
are necessary to meet the provisions of
the Federal Power Act.
288. These requirements conform to
the Commission’s plan for efficient
information collection, communication
and management within the energy
industry. The Commission has assured
itself, by means of internal review, that
there is specific, objective support for
the burden estimates associated with the
information requirements.
289. Interested persons may obtain
information on the reporting
requirements by contacting: Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
Attention: Michael Miller, Office of the
Executive Director, Phone: (202) 502–
8415, fax: (202) 273–0873, e-mail:
michael.miller@ferc.gov. Comments on
the requirements of the proposed rule
may also be sent to the Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs,
Office of Management and Budget,
Washington, DC 20503, Attention: Desk
Officer for the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, fax (202) 395–
7285, e-mail:
oira_submission@omb.eop.gov.
VII. Environmental Analysis
290. The Commission is required to
prepare an Environmental Assessment
or an Environmental Impact Statement
for any action that may have a
significant adverse effect on the human
environment.289 The Commission
concludes that neither an
Environmental Assessment nor an
Environmental Impact statement is
required for this NOPR under section
289 Regulations Implementing the National
Environmental Policy Act, Order No. 486, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 30,783 (1987).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
380.4(a)(15) of the Commission’s
regulations, which provides a
categorical exemption for approval of
actions under sections 205 and 206 of
the FPA relating to the filing of
schedules containing all rates and
charges for the transmission or sale
subject to the Commission’s
jurisdiction, plus the classification,
practices, contracts, and regulations that
affect rates, charges, classifications, and
services.290
VIII. Regulatory Flexibility Act
Certification
291. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 (RFA) 291 generally requires a
description and analysis of rules that
will have significant economic impact
on a substantial number of small
entities. Most, if not all, of the
transmission organizations to which the
requirements of this rule would apply
do not fall within the definition of small
entities.292
Those entities to be impacted directly
by this rule include the following:
• California Independent Service
Operator Corp. (CAISO) is a nonprofit
organization comprised of more than 90
electric transmission companies and
generators operating in its markets and
serving more than 30 million customers.
• New York Independent System
Operator, Inc. (NYISO) is a nonprofit
organization that oversees wholesale
electricity markets serving 19.2 million
customers. NYISO manages a 10,775mile network of high-voltage lines.
• PJM Interconnection, LLC (PJM) is
comprised of more than 450 members
including power generators,
transmission owners, electricity
distributors, power marketers and large
industrial customers and serving 13
states and the District of Columbia.
• Southwest Power Pool, Inc. (SPP) is
comprised of 50 members serving 4.5
million customers in 8 states and has
52,301 miles of transmission lines.
• Midwest Independent Transmission
System Operator, Inc. (Midwest ISO) is
a nonprofit organization with over
290 18
CFR 380.4(a)(15) (2007).
U.S.C. 601–12 (2000).
292 The RFA definition of ‘‘small entity’’ refers to
the definition provided in the Small Business Act,
which defines a ‘‘small business concern’’ as a
business that is independently owned and operated
and that is not dominant in its field of operation.
See 5 U.S.C. 601(3), citing to Section 3 of the Small
Business Act, 15 U.S.C. 632 (2000). The Small
Business Size Standards component of the North
American Industry Classification system defines a
small utility as one that, including its affiliates is
primarily engaged in the generation, transmission,
or distribution of electric energy for sale, and whose
total electric output for the preceding fiscal years
did not exceed 4 MWh. 13 CFR 121.202 (Sector 22,
Utilities, North American Industry Classification
System, NAICS) (2004).
291 5
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12613
131,000 megawatts of installed
generation. Midwest ISO has 93,600
miles of transmission lines and serves
15 states and one Canadian province.
• ISO New England Inc. (ISO–NE) is
a regional transmission organization
serving 6 states in New England. The
system is comprised of more than 8,000
miles of high voltage transmission lines
and several hundred generating
facilities of which more than 350 are
under ISO–NE’s direct control.
Therefore, the Commission certifies
that this rule will not have a significant
economic impact on a substantial
number of small entities. Accordingly,
no regulatory flexibility analysis is
required.
IX. Comment Procedures
292. The Commission invites
interested persons to submit comments
on the matters and issues proposed in
this notice to be adopted, including any
related matters or alternative proposals
that commenters may wish to discuss.
Comments are due April 21, 2008.
Comments must refer to Docket Nos.
AD07–7–000 and RM07–19–000, and
must include the commenter’s name,
the organization they represent, if
applicable, and their address in their
comments.
293. The Commission encourages
comments to be filed electronically via
the eFiling link on the Commission’s
Web site at https://www.ferc.gov. The
Commission accepts most standard
word processing formats. Documents
created electronically using word
processing software should be filed in
native applications or print-to-PDF
format and not in a scanned format.
Commenters filing electronically do not
need to make a paper filing.
294. Commenters that are not able to
file comments electronically must send
an original and 14 copies of their
comments to: Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, Secretary of the
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426.
295. All comments will be placed in
the Commission’s public files and may
be viewed, printed, or downloaded
remotely as described in the Document
Availability section below. Commenters
on this proposal are not required to
serve copies of their comments on other
commenters.
X. Document Availability
296. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through
FERC’s Home Page (https://www.ferc.gov)
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12614
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
and in FERC’s Public Reference Room
during normal business hours (8:30 a.m.
to 5 p.m. Eastern time) at 888 First
Street, NE., Room 2A, Washington DC
20426.
297. From FERC’s Home Page on the
Internet, this information is available on
eLibrary. The full text of this document
is available on eLibrary in PDF and
Microsoft Word format for viewing,
printing, and/or downloading. To access
this document in eLibrary, type the
docket number excluding the last three
digits of this document in the docket
number field.
298. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the FERC’s Web site during
normal business hours from FERC
Online Support at 202–502–6652 (toll
free at 1–866–208–3676) or e-mail at
ferconlinesupport@ferc.gov, or the
Public Reference Room at (202) 502–
8371, TTY (202) 502–8659. E-mail the
Public Reference Room at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 35
Electric power rates, Electric utilities,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements.
By direction of the Commission.
Commissioner Kelly concurring in part
and dissenting in part with a separate
statement attached. Commissioner
Wellinghoff concurring with a separate
statement attached.
Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr.,
Deputy Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission proposes to amend part 35,
Chapter I, Title 18, of the Code of
Federal Regulations, as follows:
PART 35—FILING OF RATE
SCHEDULES AND TARIFFS
1. The authority citation for part 35
continues to read as follows:
Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a–825r, 2601–
2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352.
2. Amend § 35.28 as follows:
a. Amend paragraph (b) to add
paragraphs (b)(4), (b)(5), (b)(6), and
(b)(7).
b. Add a new paragraph (g).
§ 35.28 Non-discriminatory open access
transmission tariff.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
*
*
*
*
*
(b) * * *
(4) Demand response means a
reduction in the consumption of electric
energy by customers from their expected
consumption in response to an increase
in the price of electric energy or to
incentive payments designed to induce
lower consumption of electric energy.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
(5) Demand response resource means
a resource capable of providing demand
response.
(6) An operating reserve shortage
means a period when the amount of
available supply falls short of demand
plus the operating reserve requirement.
(7) Market Monitoring Unit (MMU)
means the person or entity responsible
for carrying out the market monitoring
functions which the Commission has
ordered Commission-approved ISOs and
RTOs to perform.
*
*
*
*
*
(g) Tariffs and operations of
Commission-approved ISOs and
RTOs—(1) Demand response and
pricing. (i) Ancillary services provided
by demand response resources. (A)
Every Commission-approved ISO and
RTO that operates organized markets
based on competitive bidding for energy
imbalance, spinning reserves,
supplemental reserves, reactive power
and voltage control, and regulation and
frequency response ancillary services
(or its functional equivalent in the
Commission-approved ISO’s or RTO’s
tariff) must accept bids from demand
response resources in these markets for
that product on a basis comparable to
any other resources, if the demand
response resource meets the necessary
technical requirements under the tariff
and submits a bid under the
Commission-approved ISO’s or RTO’s
bidding rules at or below the marketclearing price, unless the laws or
regulations of the relevant retail
regulatory authority do not permit a
retail customer to participate.
(B) The Commission-approved ISO or
RTO must allow providers of a demand
response resource to specify the
following in their bids:
(1) A maximum duration in hours that
the demand response resource may be
dispatched;
(2) A maximum number of times that
the demand response resource may be
dispatched during a day; and
(3) A maximum amount of electric
energy that the demand response
resource may be required to provide
either daily or weekly.
(ii) Removal of deviation charges. A
Commission-approved ISO or RTO with
a tariff that contains a day-ahead and a
real-time market may not assess a charge
to a purchaser of electric energy in its
day-ahead market for purchasing less
power in the real-time market during a
real-time market period for which the
Commission-approved ISO or RTO
declares an operating reserve shortage or
makes a generic request to reduce load
to avoid an operating reserve shortage.
(iii) Aggregation of retail customers.
Commission-approved ISOs or RTOs
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
must permit a qualified aggregator of
retail customers to bid a demand
response on behalf of retail customers
directly into the Commission-approved
ISO’s or RTO’s organized markets,
unless the laws and regulations of the
relevant electric retail regulatory
authority do not permit a retail
customer to participate.
(iv) Price formation during periods of
operating reserve shortage. (A)
Commission-approved ISOs and RTOs
must modify their market rules to allow
the market-clearing price during periods
of operating reserve shortage to reach a
level that rebalances supply and
demand so as to maintain reliability
while providing sufficient provisions for
mitigating market power.
(B) A Commission-approved ISO or
RTO may phase in this modification of
its market rules.
(2) Long-term power contracting in
organized markets. A Commissionapproved ISO or RTO must provide a
portion of its Web site for market
participants to post offers to buy or sell
power on a long-term basis.
(3) Market monitoring policies. (i)
Commission-approved ISOs and RTOs
must modify their tariff provisions
governing their Market Monitoring
Units to reflect the directives provided
in Order No. [insert order number],
including the following:
(A) Commission-approved ISOs and
RTOs must include in their tariffs a
provision to provide their Market
Monitoring Units access to Commissionapproved ISO and RTO market data,
resources and personnel to enable the
Market Monitoring Unit to carry out
their functions.
(B) The tariff provision must provide
the Market Monitoring Unit complete
access to the Commission-approved
ISO’s and RTO’s database of market
information.
(C) The tariff provision must provide
that any data created by the Market
Monitoring Unit, including, but not
limited to, reconfiguring of the
Commission-approved ISO’s and RTO’s
data, will be kept within the exclusive
control of the Market Monitoring Unit.
(D) The Market Monitoring Unit must
report to the Commission-approved ISO
or RTO board of directors, with its
management members removed, or to an
independent committee of the
Commission-approved ISO or RTO
board of directors. A Commissionapproved ISO and RTO that has both an
internal MMU and an external MMU
may permit the internal MMU to report
to management and the external MMU
to report to the Commission-approved
ISO or RTO board of directors with its
management members removed, or to an
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
independent committee of the
Commission-approved ISO or RTO
board of directors.
(E) Commission-approved ISOs and
RTOs may not alter the reports
generated by the Market Monitoring
Unit, or dictate the conclusions reached
by the Market Monitoring Unit.
(F) Commission-approved ISOs and
RTOs must consolidate the core Market
Monitoring Unit provisions into one
section in their tariffs as provided in
paragraph (g)(6) of this section.
(ii) Functions of Market Monitoring
Unit. The Market Monitoring Unit must
perform the following functions:
(A) Evaluate existing and proposed
market rules, tariff provisions and
market design elements for their
effectiveness and recommend proposed
rule and tariff changes to the
Commission-approved ISO or RTO, to
the Commission’s Office of Energy
Market Regulation staff and to other
interested entities such as state
commissions and market participants.
(B) Review and report on the
performance of the wholesale markets to
the Commission-approved ISO or RTO,
the Commission, and other interested
entities such as state commissions and
market participants on at least a
quarterly basis and submit a more
comprehensive annual state of the
market report. The Market Monitoring
Unit may issue additional reports as
necessary.
(C) Identify and notify the
Commission’s Office of Enforcement
staff of instances in which a market
participant’s or the Commissionapproved ISO’s or RTO’s behavior may
require investigation, including, but not
limited to, suspected rule or tariff
violations, market manipulation,
inappropriate dispatch, and suspected
violations of Commission-approved
rules and regulations.
(D) The Market Monitoring Unit,
whether internal or external, may not
participate in the administration of the
Commission-approved ISO’s or RTO’s
tariff, including mitigation.
(iii) Market Monitoring Unit ethical
standards. Commission-approved ISOs
and RTOs must include ethical
standards for employees in their Market
Monitoring Units. At a minimum, the
ethical standards must include the
following requirements:
(A) Market Monitoring Unit
employees must have no material
affiliation with any market participant
or affiliate.
(B) Market Monitoring Unit
employees must not serve as an officer,
employee, or partner of a market
participant.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
(C) Market Monitoring Unit
employees must have no material
financial interest in any market
participant or affiliate with potential
exceptions for mutual funds and nondirected investments.
(D) Market Monitoring Unit
employees must not engage in any
market transactions other than the
performance of their duties under the
tariff.
(E) Market Monitoring Unit
employees must not be compensated for
any expert witness testimony or other
commercial services to the Commissionapproved ISO or RTO or to any other
party in connection with any legal or
regulatory proceeding or commercial
transaction relating to the Commissionapproved ISO or RTO or to the
Commission-approved ISO or RTO
markets.
(F) Market Monitoring Unit
employees may not accept anything of
value from a market participant in
excess of a de minimis amount.
(G) Market Monitoring Unit
employees must advise a supervisor in
the event they seek employment with a
market participant, and must disqualify
themselves from participating in any
matter that would have an effect on the
financial interest of the market
participant.
(4) Offer and bid data. (i) Unless a
Commission-approved ISO or RTO
obtains Commission approval for a
different period, Commission-approved
ISOs and RTOs must release their offer
and bid data within three months.
(ii) Commission-approved ISOs and
RTOs may mask the identity of market
participants when releasing offer and
bid data.
(5) Responsiveness of Commissionapproved ISOs and RTOs. Commissionapproved ISOs and RTOs must adopt
business practices and procedures that
achieve Commission-approved ISO and
RTO board of directors’ responsiveness
to customers and other stakeholders and
satisfy the following criteria:
(i) Inclusiveness. The practices and
procedures must ensure that any
customer or stakeholder affected by the
operation of the Commission-approved
ISO or RTO, or its representative, is
permitted to communicate its views to
the RTO or ISO board;
(ii) Fairness in balancing diverse
interests. The practices and procedures
must ensure that the interests of
customers or other stakeholders are
equitably considered and that
deliberation and consideration of
Commission-approved ISO and RTO
issues are not dominated by any single
stakeholder category;
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12615
(iii) Representation of minority
positions. The practices and procedures
must ensure that, in instances where
stakeholders are not in total agreement
on a particular issue, minority positions
are communicated to the board of
directors at the same time as majority
positions; and
(iv) Ongoing responsiveness. The
practices and procedures must provide
for stakeholder input into RTO or ISO
decisions as well as mechanisms to
provide feedback to stakeholders to
ensure that information exchange and
communication continue over time.
(6) Compliance filings. All
Commission-approved ISOs and RTOs
must make a compliance filing with the
Commission as described in Order No.
[insert order number] under the
following schedule:
(i) The compliance filing addressing
the accepting of bids from demand
response resources in markets for
ancillary services on a basis comparable
to other resources, removal of deviation
charges, aggregation of retail customers,
shortage pricing during periods of
operating reserve shortage, long-term
power contracting in organized markets,
Market Monitoring Units, Commissionapproved ISO and RTO board of
directors’ responsiveness, and reporting
on the study of the need for further
reforms to remove barriers to
comparable treatment of demand
response resources must be submitted
on or before [insert date that is six
months after date of publication of Final
Rule in the Federal Register].
(ii) A public utility that is approved
as a Regional Transmission
Organization under § 35.34 of this part,
or that is not approved but begins to
operate regional markets for electric
energy or ancillary services after [insert
effective date of Final Rule], must
comply with Order No. [insert order
number] and the provisions of
paragraphs (g)(1) through (g)(5) of this
section before beginning operations.
Note: The following appendices will not
appear in the Code of Federal Regulations.
Appendix A: Commenter Acronyms
Commenters to the ANOPR in Docket
Nos. RM07–19–000 and AD07–7–000
AARP, et al.—AARP; American Antitrust
Institute; American Chemistry Council;
American Forest & Paper Association;
American Iron and Steel Institute; American
Municipal Power–Ohio; American Public
Power Association; Association of Businesses
Advocating Tariff Equity; Citizen Power;
Citizens Utility Board of Illinois; Coalition of
Midwest Transmission Customers; Colorado
Office of Consumer Counsel; Consumer
Federation of America; Council of Industrial
Boiler Owners; Democracy and Regulation;
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
12616
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
Electricity Consumers Resource Council;
Florida Industrial Power Users Group;
Illinois Industrial Energy Consumers; Illinois
Public Interest Research Group; Industrial
Energy Consumers of America; Industrial
Energy Consumers of Pennsylvania;
Industrial Energy Users–Ohio; Louisiana
Energy Users Group; Maryland Office of the
People’s Counsel; Maryland Public Interest
Research Group; Missouri Industrial Energy
Consumers; National Association of State
Utility Consumer Advocates; NEPOOL
Industrial Customer Coalition; Office of the
People’s Counsel of the District of Columbia;
Ohio Hospital Association, Ohio
Manufacturers’ Association; Ohio Partners
for Affordable Energy; PJM Industrial
Customer Coalition, Portland Cement
Association; Power in the Public Interest,
Public Citizen, Inc.; Public Utility Law
Project of New York, Inc.; Steel
Manufacturers Association; West Virginia
Energy Users Group; Wisconsin Industrial
Energy Group, Inc.; and Wisconsin Paper
Council.
AEP—American Electric Power Service
Corporation.
Alcoa—Alcoa, Inc.
Allegheny Energy—Allegheny Power and
Allegheny Energy Supply Company, LLC.
Ameren—Ameren Services Company.
American Forest—American Forest &
Paper Association.
APPA—American Public Power
Association.
ATC—American Transmission Company,
LLC.
AWEA—American Wind Energy
Association.
Blue Ridge—Blue Ridge Power Agency.
BlueStar Energy—BlueStar Energy
Services, Inc.
BP Energy—BP Energy Company.
Cal DWR—California Department of Water
Resources State Water Project.
CAISO—California Independent System
Operator Corporation.
California Munis—California Municipal
Utilities Association.
California PUC—California Public Utilities
Commission.
COMPETE Coalition—171 various entities.
COMPETE, et al.—7-Eleven, Inc.;
Allegheny Energy, Alliance for Real Energy
Options; Alliance for Retail Choice, Alliance
for Retail Energy Markets; Alliance for Retail
Markets; Ardmore Power Logistics; Professor
Ross Baldick, IEEE Fellow, Department of
Electrical and Computer Engineering, The
University of Texas at Austin; Big Lots
Stores, Inc.; Nora Mead Brownell, BC
Consulting, former FERC Commissioner and
former PaPUC Commissioner; H. Sterling
Burnett, PhD., Senior Fellow, National Center
for Policy Analysis; California Alliance for
Competitive Energy Solutions; California
Grocers Association; California Retailers
Association; Laura Chappelle, Attorney,
former Chairman, MI PSC; Colorado
Independent Energy Association;
Constellation Energy; Comverge, Maryland;
DC Energy, LLC; David W. DeRamus, Partner,
Bates White, LLC; Direct Energy Services,
LLC; Richard A. Drom, Partner, Powell
Goldstein LLP; Edison Mission Energy;
Electric Power Supply Association; Electric
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
Power Generation Association; Energy
Association of Pennsylvania; Energy
Curtailment Specialists, Inc.; Enermetrix;
Enerwise Global Technologies; Exelon
Corporation; FirstEnergy Corp.; William L.
Flynn, Partner, Harris Beach PLLS, former
Chairman, NY PSC; John Hanger, former
PaPUC Commissioner; Hess Corp.; William
W. Hogan, Raymond Plank Professor of
Global Energy Policy, John F. Kennedy
School of Government, Harvard University;
Illinois Energy Association; Independent
Power Producers of New York; JC Penny;
Kimball Resources, Inc.; Jerry J. Langdon,
former FERC Commissioner; LS Power
Associates, LP; Luminant; Macy’s Inc.,
Midwest Independent Power Suppliers;
Mirant Corporation; Elizabeth A. Moler,
Exelon Corp., former Chair of FERC; National
Energy Marketers Association; New England
Energy Alliance; New England Power
Generators Association, Inc.; Northwest and
Intermountain Power Producers Coalition;
NRG Energy, Inc.; Nuclear Energy Institute;
PennFuture; PetSmart, Inc.; Piney Creek LP;
PJM Power Providers Group; PowerGrid
Systems, Inc.; PPL Corporation; Priority
Power Management, Ltd.; PSEG Companies;
John M. Quain, Buchanan Ingersoll & Rooney
PC, former Chairman of PaPUC; Reliant
Energy; Retail Energy Suppliers Association;
Safeway, Inc.; School Project for Utility Rate
Reduction; Sempra Energy; Shell Energy
North America; Silicon Valley Leadership
Group; Vernon L. Smith, Nobel Laureate,
Professor of Economics and Law, Chapman
University; David A. Svanda, Svanda
Consulting, former MI PSC Commissioner
and former President of NARUC; Glen
Thomas, GT Power, former Chairman of
PaPUC; Telga Corporation; Texas
Competitive Power Advocates; TXU Energy;
Wal-Mart Stores, Inc.; Western Power
Trading Forum; and Pat Wood, III, former
Chairman of FERC and the PUCT.
Comverge—Comverge, Inc.
Connecticut and Massachusetts
Municipals—Connecticut Municipal Electric
Energy Cooperative and Massachusetts
Municipal Wholesale Electric Company.
Constellation—Constellation Energy
Commodities Group, Inc.; Constellation
NewEnergy, Inc.; and Constellation
Generation Group, LLC.
DC Energy—DC Energy, LLC.
Detroit Edison—Detroit Edison Company.
Dominion Resources—Dominion Resources
Services, Inc.
Duke Energy—Duke Energy Corporation.
Dynegy—Dynegy Power Corporation.
EEI—Edison Electric Institute and Alliance
of Energy Suppliers.
EnergyConnect—Energy Connect, Inc.
Energy Curtailment—Energy Curtailment
Specialists, Inc.
EnerNOC—EnerNOC, Inc.
EPSA—The Electric Power Supply
Association.
Exelon—Exelon Corporation.
FTC—Federal Trade Commission.
FirstEnergy—FirstEnergy Service
Company, on behalf of FirstEnergy Solutions
Corp. and the transmission and distribution
owning utility subsidiaries of FirstEnergy
Corp.: American Transmission Systems, Inc.;
The Cleveland Electric Illuminating
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
Company; Jersey Central Power and Light
Company; Metropolitan Edison Company;
Ohio Edison Company; Pennsylvania Electric
Company; Pennsylvania Power Company;
and The Toledo Edison Company.
Mr. Hogan—William W. Hogan and Susan
L. Pope.
Indianapolis P&L—Indianapolis Power and
Light Company.
Industrial Coalitions—Coalition of
Midwest Transmission Customers; NEPOOL
Industrial Customer Coalition; and PJM
Industrial Customer Coalition.
Industrial Consumers—Electricity
Consumers Resource Council; American Iron
and Steel Institute; and American Chemistry
Council.
ISO–NE—ISO New England, Inc.
ISO/RTO Council—ISO/RTO Council:
California Independent System Operator
Corporation; ISO New England, Inc.; the
Midwest Independent Transmission System
Operator, Inc.; New York Independent
System Operator, Inc.; PJM Interconnection,
LLC; Southwest Power Pool.
ITC—International Transmission Company
and Michigan Electric Transmission
Company, LLC.
Integrys—Integrys Energy Services, Inc.
J.Aron, Barclays, Morgan Stanley—J.Aron
& Company, Barclays Capital, and Morgan
Stanley Capital Group Inc.
Joint Consumer Advocates—Ohio
Consumers Counsel; District of Columbia
Office of the People’s Counsel; Pennsylvania
Office of Consumer Advocate; Illinois
Citizens Utility Board; Maryland Office of
People’s Counsel; and New Jersey
Department of the Public Advocate, Division
of Rate Counsel.
Kansas CC—Kansas Corporation
Commission.
LPPC—Large Public Power Council.
Massachusetts AG—Massachusetts
Attorney General.
Mr. McCullough—Robert McCullough.
Midwest ISO—Midwest Independent
Transmission System Operator, Inc.
Midwest ISO TOs—Midwest ISO
Transmission Owners.
Mirant—Mirant Corporation.
NARUC—National Association of
Regulatory Utility Commissions.
National Energy Marketers—National
Energy Marketers Association.
National Grid—National Grid USA.
NEPOOL Participants—NEPOOL
Participants Committee.
New England Conference—New England
Conference of Public Utilities
Commissioners; Connecticut Department of
Public Utility Control; Massachusetts
Department of Public Utilities; Massachusetts
Department of Energy Resources; New
Hampshire Public Utilities Commission;
Rhode Island Public Utilities Commission;
the Vermont Department of Public Service;
and Vermont Public Service Board.
New England Power Generators—New
England Power Generators Association.
New York PSC—New York State Public
Service Commission.
NJBPU—New Jersey Board of Public
Utilities.
NJ BPU Commissioner Bator—New Jersey
Board of Public Utilities Commissioner
Christine V. Bator.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
North Carolina Commission—North
Carolina Utilities Commission; Public Staff—
North Carolina Utilities Commission; and the
Attorney General of the State of North
Carolina.
North Carolina Electric Membership—
North Carolina Electric Membership
Corporation.
Northeast Utilities—Northeast Utilities.
NRECA—National Rural Electric
Cooperative Association.
NRG—NRG Energy, Inc.
NSTAR—NSTAR Electric Company.
NYISO—New York Independent System
Operator Corp.
NY TOs—New York Transmission Owners.
Ohio PUC—Public Utilities Commission of
Ohio.
Old Dominion—Old Dominion Electric
Cooperative.
OMS—Organization of MISO States.
OPSI—Organization of PJM States, Inc.
Otter Tail—Otter Tail Power Company.
Pennsylvania PUC—Pennsylvania Public
Utilities Commission.
Pepco—Pepco Holdings, Inc.; Delmarva
Power & Light Company; Atlantic City
Electric Company; Conectiv Energy Supply
Inc.; and Pepco Energy Services, Inc.
PGC—PGC Electricity Committee.
PG&E—Pacific Gas and Electric Company.
PJM—PJM Interconnection, LLC.
PJM Power Providers—PJM Power
Providers Group.
PJM MMU—Independent Market
Monitoring Unit of PJM.
Portland Cement—Portland Cement
Association.
Portland Cement Association, et al.—
Multiple Intervenors; PJM Industrial
Customer Coalition; Connecticut Industrial
Energy Consumers; Industrial Energy UsersOhio; Mittal Steel USA, Inc.
Potomac Economics—Potomac Economics,
Inc.
Power in Public Interest—Power in the
Public Interest.
PPL Parties—PPL Parties.
PSEG—PSEG Companies: Public Service
Electric and Gas Company; PSEG Power LLC
and PSEG Energy Resources & Trade LLC.
Public Interest Organizations—Center for
Energy Efficiency & Renewable Technologies;
Connecticut Office of Consumer Counsel;
Conservation Law Foundation; Delaware
Division of the Public Advocate;
Environmental Law & Policy Center; Fresh
Energy, Natural Resources Defense Council;
New Hampshire Office of Consumer
Advocate; Office of the Ohio Consumers’
Counsel; Pace Energy Project; Project for
Sustainable FERC Energy Policy; Renewable
Northwest Project; Union of Concerned
Scientists and West Wind Wires.
Reliant—Reliant Energy, Inc.
Safeway—Safeway, Inc.
Silicon Valley Power—Silicon Valley
Power.
SMUD—Sacramento Municipal Utility
District.
SoCal Edison-SDG&E—Southern California
Edison Company and San Diego Gas &
Electric.
SPP—Southwest Power Pool, Inc.
Steel Manufacturers—Steel Manufacturers
Association.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
Steel Producers—Steel Producers.
Strategic Energy—Strategic Energy, LLC.
SUEZ—SUEZ Energy North America, Inc.
TAPS—Transmission Access Policy Study
Group.
The Alliance—The Alliance For Retail
Energy Markets.
Utility Savings—Utility Savings & Refund,
LLC.
Wal-Mart—Wal-Mart Stores, Inc.
Wisconsin Industrial—Wisconsin
Industrial Energy Group.
WSPP—WSPP Inc.
Xcel—Xcel Energy Services, Inc., on behalf
of Northern States Power Company; Northern
States Power Company; Wisconsin, Public
Service Company of Colorado; and
Southwestern Public Service Company.
United States of America Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission
Wholesale Competition in Regions With
Organized Electric Markets—Docket Nos.
RM07–19–000 AD07–7–000
Issued February 22, 2008.
KELLY, Commissioner, concurring in part
and dissenting in part:
I support many of the efforts enumerated
in the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
(NOPR) which requests comment on
proposals to improve the operation of
wholesale electric markets. I believe that it is
extremely important that we ensure that
wholesale markets are competitive thereby
allowing the Commission to fulfill our
statutory mandate to ensure adequate and
reliable non-discriminatory service at just
and reasonable rates. Unfortunately, I am
concerned regarding the potential impact of
several of the proposals related to demand
response, market monitoring, and promoting
regional transmission organization (RTO)/
independent system operator (ISO)
responsiveness.
I continue to be troubled by the NOPR’s
proposal in the Market Rules Governing Price
Formation During Periods of Operating
Reserve Shortage section. This section would
attempt to stimulate demand response by
allowing RTOs/ISOs to implement scarcity
pricing by modifying market power
mitigation rules in organized markets, such
as raising energy supply offer caps and
demand bid caps. I appreciate the efforts
made in the NOPR to address market power
associated with scarcity pricing and to ensure
that there is an adequate record regarding any
scarcity pricing proposal, including soliciting
the views of each RTO/ISO market monitor
on any proposed reform in this area.
However, these positive changes in the NOPR
proposal have not alleviated my concerns
regarding the very real impacts on customers
associated with raising energy supply offer
caps and demand bid caps in emergency
situations.
I believe that absent appropriate resource
adequacy requirements and the necessary
demand response infrastructure to give
consumers the ability to respond to higher
prices, it is not responsible to allow energy
supply offer caps and demand bid caps to
rise without regard to the impacts on
consumers. I do not per se oppose scarcity
pricing. However, I believe that there is a
crucial timing issue that we must consider
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12617
regarding any scarcity pricing proposal. Prior
to implementing scarcity pricing in any
market, we must have resources in place to
meet demand. One essential way to
accomplish this goal is through resource
adequacy requirements. If a market is
resource adequate, then there will be fewer
emergency situations and, when those
emergencies do occur, having demand
response in place will help reduce prices in
times of scarcity. Therefore, resource
adequacy requirements and the ability of
demand response to participate in a market
go hand in hand with protecting consumers
from market power and thereby making
scarcity pricing proposals just and
reasonable.
Some may look at this as a chicken and egg
debate where if we allow energy supply offer
caps and demand bid caps to increase
without restraint this will raise prices
thereby encouraging additional generation
and demand response to enter the market. On
the other hand, what happens in the
meantime to consumers as we allow prices to
rise without restraint and we are still waiting
for these theoretical incentives to building
adequate generation and demand response
infrastructure to kick in? We must never lose
sight of the interests of consumers as we
engage in this kind of philosophical debate
because they will be the ones who will lose
out if we miscalculate. The necessary
generation and demand response
infrastructure must be in place prior to
allowing energy supply offer caps and
demand bid caps to rise or be eliminated.
Unfortunately, this is not the case. As
Commission staff noted in the 2006 FERC
Staff Demand Response Assessment,
advanced metering currently has low market
penetration of less than six percent in the
United States.293 This means that consumers
do not have the tools they need in order to
make choices regarding rising prices and
respond accordingly.
On the issue of market monitoring, I
disagree with the NOPR’s proposal to remove
market monitors from tariff administration,
particularly market power mitigation. I
believe that market monitoring units (MMUs)
should continue to perform mitigation. The
NOPR states that the issue of removing
MMUs from mitigation ‘‘proved to be the
most contentious one in the entire market
monitoring section.’’ 294 This is for good
reason. As Portland Cement noted in its
comments, ‘‘The MMU’s are better positioned
to make determinations regarding the
exercise of market power than are the RTO/
ISO staff members who frequently have long
standing close personal relationships with
the very market participants whose actions at
times need to be mitigated.’’ 295 Further, I
agree with Portland Cement’s statement that
having RTO/ISO staff mitigate creates a much
greater conflict of interest than any incidental
293 Assessment of Demand Response and
Advanced Metering: Staff Report, Docket No.
AD06–2–000, at 26 (2006) (2006 FERC Staff
Demand Response Assessment).
294 Wholesale Competition in Regions with
Organized Electric Markets, Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, 122 FERC ¶ 61,617, at P 202 (2008).
295 Portland Cement Association Aug. 16, 2007
Comments, Docket Nos. AD07–7, RM07–19, at 19.
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
12618
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
conflict created by having the internal MMU
both mitigate and report on the functioning
of the markets.296 The New York
Independent System Operator (NYISO) also
agrees that the concerns expressed in support
of removing the MMU from mitigation are
misplaced.297 NYISO further stated that
‘‘[t]here is no reason to fear that a market
monitor would hesitate to report market
power problems or potential market abuses
just because it was involved in implementing
mitigation measures in that market.’’ 298 BP
Energy asserts that ‘‘shifting the mitigation
responsibility to RTO staff gives rise to a
much larger conflict of interest than exists
with having mitigation responsibility lie with
the independent MMU exclusively.’’ 299
Therefore, I disagree with the NOPR’s
proposal to remove MMUs from mitigation.
Additionally, I would have strengthened
the market monitoring section. For example,
the NOPR proposes to retain existing
provisions regarding the confidentiality of
the progress and results of the Commission’s
own investigations. I believe that, subject to
appropriate confidentiality limitations, the
Commission should provide MMUs with
information on referrals that the MMU
provides to the Commission. I would also
have supported requiring RTOs/ISOs to file
tariff provisions to allow them to take
enforcement action with respect to
objectively identifiable behavior that does
not subject the seller to sanctions or
consequence other than those expressly
approved by the Commission and set forth in
the tariff and with the right of appeal,
consistent with the Policy Statement on
Market Monitoring Units.300
Further, I disagree with the NOPR’s
proposal to promote responsiveness of RTOs/
ISOs by allowing them to adopt hybrid
boards with stakeholder members. Providing
for stakeholder representatives on an RTO/
ISO board is inconsistent with an
independent governing structure. The
Commission has already spoken clearly on
the importance of RTOs/ISOs being
independent of market participants. Having
an independent board is the cornerstone of
RTO/ISO policy. Order Nos. 888 301 and
2000 302 require that an RTO/ISO be
296 Id.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
297 NYISO
Sept. 14, 2007 Comments, Docket Nos.
AD07–7, RM07–19, at 23.
298 Id. at 24 (citation omitted).
299 BP Energy Company Sept. 14, 2007
Comments, Docket Nos. AD07–7, RM07–19, at 31.
300 Policy Statement on Market Monitoring Units,
111 FERC ¶ 61,267, at P 5 (2005) (citation omitted).
301 Promoting Wholesale Competition Through
Open Access Non-Discriminatory Transmission
Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded
Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities,
Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,036 (1996),
order on reh’g, Order No. 888–A, FERC Stats. &
Regs. ¶ 31,048, order on reh’g, Order No. 888–B, 81
FERC ¶ 61,248 (1997), order on reh’g, Order No.
888–C, 82 FERC ¶ 61,046 (1998), aff’d in relevant
part sub nom. Transmission Access Policy Study
Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667 (DC Cir. 2000), aff’d
sub nom. New York v. FERC, 535 U.S. 1 (2002).
302 Regional Transmission Organizations, Order
No. 2000, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089 (1999), order
on reh’g, Order No. 2000–A, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,092 (2000), aff’d sub nom. Pub. Util. Dist. No.
1 of Snohomish County, Washington v. FERC, 272
F.3d 607 (DC Cir. 2001).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
independent from market participants in
order to provide regional transmission and
energy market services on a nondiscriminatory basis. If an RTO or ISO
adopted a hybrid board, I do not believe they
could be categorized as independent.
Additionally, I believe that an RTO or ISO
with a hybrid board jeopardizes the ability of
the Commission to apply the independent
entity variation standard found in Order No.
2003 when considering modifications to such
an RTO or ISO’s pro forma Large Generator
Interconnection Procedures (LGIP) and Large
Generator Interconnection Agreement
(LGIA).303
I also fear that a board with independent
and non-independent members will suffer
from a divisive atmosphere with suspicion as
to whether non-independent board members
were acting in the best interests of the RTO/
ISO and its customers or in the best interest
of the particular market participant
represented by that non-independent board
member. In contrast, I believe that the
NOPR’s proposal to encourage RTOs and
ISOs to establish a stakeholder advisory
committee would meet the NOPR’s goal of
improving RTO/ISO responsiveness without
jeopardizing the fundamental independence
of RTOs/ISOs. I also believe consideration
should be given to the RTO/ISO mission
statement as a tool to respond to any
continuing stakeholder need for more RTO/
ISO accountability.
Finally, I support the long-term power
contracting in organized markets section of
the NOPR. I agree with the NOPR’s
suggestion that RTOs/ISOs conduct forums
on long-term contracts to gather information
and facilitate the exchange of ideas, similar
to the one recently held by PJM. I believe that
such forums will allow for an exchange of
ideas on long-term contracting concerns and
potentially foster solutions to these issues. I
also agree that Commission staff should
perform an analysis of the level of long-term
contracting in organized market regions.
Accordingly, for the reasons stated above,
I concur in part and dissent in part on this
NOPR.
Suedeen G. Kelly.
United States of America Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission
Wholesale Competition in Regions With
Organized Electric Markets—Docket Nos.
RM07–19–000, AD07–7–000
Issued February 22, 2008.
WELLINGHOFF, Commissioner, concurring:
As the Commission states in this Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR), from the
commencement of our first technical
conference in this proceeding one year ago,
our goal has been to identify specific reforms
that can be made to optimize the efficiency
of organized wholesale electric markets for
303 Standardization of Generator Interconnection
Agreements and Procedures, Order No. 2003, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,146, at P 26 (2003), order on
reh’g, Order No. 2003–A, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,160, order on reh’g, Order No. 2003–B, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,171 (2004), order on reh’g, Order
No. 2003–C, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,190 (2005),
aff’d sub nom. Nat’l Ass’n of Regulatory Util.
Comm’rs v. FERC, 475 F.3d 1277 (DC Cir. 2007).
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
the benefit of customers and, ultimately, the
consumers who pay for electricity services.
This NOPR marks an important step toward
that goal, and I am pleased to support its
issuance.
I would like to draw attention to a few
areas of this NOPR, on which I particularly
encourage interested persons to submit
comments.
In this NOPR, the Commission highlights
the importance of demand response to the
organized markets. The Commission states
that demand response helps to reduce prices
in competitive wholesale markets in several
ways, such as by reducing generator market
power and flattening an area’s load profile.
The Commission also recognizes that the
need for, and the focus on, demand response
will continue to increase.
The Commission makes several notable
proposals in this NOPR related to demand
response. One issue on which I encourage
comments is the Commission’s proposal to
require each RTO and ISO to accept bids
from demand response resources, on a basis
comparable to any other resources, for
ancillary services that are acquired in a
competitive bidding process. The
Commission states that this policy would
increase the competitiveness of ancillary
services markets, help reduce the price of
ancillary services, and improve the reliability
of the grid. I am interested in hearing from
interested parties whether our proposals in
this area are adequate to achieve those goals.
The Commission also states that we intend
to direct our staff to convene a technical
conference shortly after we receive comments
on this NOPR to consider critical issues
related to demand response, such as
appropriate compensation for demand
response and potential solutions to
remaining barriers to comparable treatment
of demand response. We also propose to
require each RTO and ISO to submit a study
on these critical issues within six months of
the issuance of a Final Rule in this
proceeding. Those studies would include
proposed solutions along with a timeline for
implementation. I encourage interested
parties to provide comments on this
approach and to identify particular issues or
areas that should be addressed in these RTO
and ISO studies.
In addition, I strongly encourage interested
parties to comment on the Commission’s
proposal in this NOPR concerning market
rules that govern price formation during
periods of operating reserve shortage. It is
important to note that these are infrequent
periods when more resources, both
generation and demand resources, are needed
to maintain reliable electric service to
consumers. I appreciate the extensive
comments that we received on this issue in
response to the ANOPR. I believe that this
proposal in the NOPR is an improvement in
several respects over the discussion in the
ANOPR. Most notably, the Commission
proposes to adopt requirements to ensure
that proposals for pricing during periods of
operating reserve shortage are designed to
protect consumers against the exercise of
market power and are supported by an
adequate factual record. More specifically,
we propose that a primary criterion for
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed Rules
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with PROPOSALS2
approving such pricing proposals would be
an adequate record demonstrating that
provisions exist for mitigating market power
and deterring gaming behavior, including,
but not limited to, use of demand resources
to discipline bidding behavior to competitive
levels during periods of operating reserve
shortage. I am particularly interested in
receiving comments as to whether this and
the other criteria proposed in this NOPR are
appropriate, how the Commission should
apply these criteria if we adopt them in a
Final Rule, and whether there are additional
criteria that we should consider in evaluating
VerDate Aug<31>2005
21:05 Mar 06, 2008
Jkt 214001
an RTO’s or ISO’s proposal for pricing during
a period of operating reserve shortage.
Finally, I would like to note that the
Commission in this NOPR is directing each
RTO or ISO to provide a forum for affected
consumers to voice specific concerns (and to
propose regional solutions) about market
designs in its particular region, including
concerns as to the value to the market of
significant changes to the market rules. We
are also directing our staff to convene a
technical conference on two proposals that
were submitted in comments in this
proceeding. Through these and other steps
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4702
12619
taken in this NOPR, it is my intention for the
Commission to demonstrate how seriously
we take our statement that the proposals in
this NOPR do not represent our final effort
to enhance the efficient functioning of
competitive organized markets for the benefit
of consumers.
Jon Wellinghoff,
Commissioner.
[FR Doc. E8–3984 Filed 3–6–08; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
E:\FR\FM\07MRP2.SGM
07MRP2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 73, Number 46 (Friday, March 7, 2008)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 12576-12619]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E8-3984]
[[Page 12575]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Part IV
Department of Energy
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
18 CFR Part 35
Wholesale Competition in Regions With Organized Electric Markets;
Proposed Rules
Federal Register / Vol. 73, No. 46 / Friday, March 7, 2008 / Proposed
Rules
[[Page 12576]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 35
[Docket Nos. RM07-19-000 and AD07-7-000]
Wholesale Competition in Regions With Organized Electric Markets
Issued February 22, 2008.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) is
proposing to amend its regulations under the Federal Power Act to
improve the operation of organized wholesale electric markets in the
areas of: Demand response and market pricing during a period of
operating reserve shortage; long-term power contracting; market-
monitoring policies; and the responsiveness of regional transmission
organizations (RTOs) and independent system operators (ISOs) to
stakeholders and customers, and ultimately to the consumers who benefit
from and pay for electricity services. The Commission proposes to
require that each RTO and ISO make certain filings that propose
amendments to its tariff, in order to comply with the proposed
requirements in each area, or that demonstrate that its existing tariff
and market design already satisfy the requirements. The Commission
invites all interested persons to submit comments in response to the
regulations proposed herein.
DATES: Comments are due April 21, 2008.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by docket number by any
of the following methods.
Agency Web site: https://ferc.gov. Documents created
electronically using word processing software should be filed in native
applications or print-to-PDF format and not in a scanned format.
Mail/Hand Delivery: Commenters unable to file comments
electronically must mail or hand deliver an original and 14 copies of
their comments to: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Secretary of
the Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
Instructions: For detailed instructions on submitting comments and
additional information on the rulemaking process, see the Comment
Procedures Section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: David Kathan (Technical Information),
Office of Energy Market Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
David.Kathan@ferc.gov, (202) 502-6404.
Tina Ham (Legal Information), Office of the General Counsel,
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426,Tina.Ham@ferc.gov, (202) 502-6224.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Table of Contents
Paragraph
numbers
I. Introduction............................................. 1
II. Background.............................................. 12
III. Proposals To Expand the Scope of the Proceeding........ 16
IV. Discussion.............................................. 26
A. Demand Response and Pricing During Periods of 26
Operating Reserve Shortages in Organized Markets.......
1. Background....................................... 27
a. Importance of Demand Response to Competition 28
in RTO/ISO Areas...............................
b. Prior Commission Actions To Address Demand 32
Response.......................................
2. The Need for Commission Action................... 37
3. Proposed Reforms................................. 46
a. Ancillary Services Provided by Demand 47
Response Resources.............................
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR....... 47
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and 50
Questions..................................
iii. Commission Proposal.................... 56
b. Deviation Charge............................. 65
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR....... 65
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and 67
Questions..................................
iii. Commission Proposal.................... 72
c. Aggregation of Retail Customers.............. 80
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR....... 80
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and 82
Questions..................................
iii. Commission Proposal.................... 86
d. Potential Future Demand Response Reforms..... 94
e. Market Rules Governing Price Formation During 97
Periods of Operating Reserve Shortage..........
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR....... 97
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and 99
Questions..................................
iii. Commission Proposal.................... 107
B. Long-Term Power Contracting in Organized Markets..... 129
1. Background....................................... 130
2. The Need for Commission Action................... 134
3. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR............... 138
4. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions.... 142
5. Proposed Reforms................................. 155
C. Market-Monitoring Policies........................... 162
1. Background....................................... 163
2. Prior Commission Actions Regarding Market 165
Monitoring.........................................
3. The Need for Commission Action................... 169
4. Proposed Reforms................................. 171
a. Independence and Function.................... 172
i. Structure and Tools...................... 173
ii. Oversight............................... 183
[[Page 12577]]
iii. Functions.............................. 191
iv. Mitigation and Operations............... 200
v. Ethics................................... 211
vi. Tariff Provisions....................... 215
b. Information Sharing.......................... 219
i. Enhanced Information Dissemination....... 220
ii. Tailored Requests for Information....... 231
iii. Commission Referrals................... 238
c. Pro Forma Tariff............................. 241
i. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR....... 241
ii. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and 242
Questions..................................
iii. Commission Proposal.................... 243
D. Responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to Stakeholders and 245
Customers..............................................
1. Background....................................... 247
2. Preliminary Proposals in the ANOPR............... 249
3. Comments on the ANOPR Proposals and Questions.... 254
a. Comments on the Hybrid Board Approach........ 255
b. Comments on the Board Advisory Committee 264
Approach.......................................
c. Comments on the Need To Increase Management 268
Responsiveness.................................
d. Comments on Regional Differences............. 270
4. The Need for Commission Action................... 272
5. Proposed Reform.................................. 275
V. Applicability of the Proposed Rule and Compliance 282
Procedures.................................................
VI. Information Collection Statement........................ 286
VII. Environmental Analysis................................. 290
VIII. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification.............. 291
IX. Comment Procedures...................................... 292
X. Document Availability.................................... 296
APPENDIX A: Commenter Acronyms
I. Introduction
1. The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) is
proposing reforms to improve the operation of organized wholesale
electric power markets.\1\ Ensuring the competitiveness of organized
wholesale markets is integral to the Commission fulfilling its
statutory mandate to ensure adequate and reliable non-discriminatory
service at just and reasonable rates. Effective competition protects
consumers by providing greater supply options, encouraging new entry
and innovation, and encouraging demand response and energy efficiency.
In the past several years, the Commission has received both formal and
informal comments from market participants, consumer and industry
organizations, state regulators, and others recommending improvements
to competitive wholesale markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Organized market regions are areas of the country in which a
regional transmission organization (RTO) or independent system
operator (ISO) operates day-ahead and/or real-time energy markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. In response to these comments, the Commission held three public
conferences in 2007 in order to gather more information on competition
at the wholesale level and other related issues. At the first
conference on competition issues, held on February 27, 2007, most
speakers addressed issues affecting the RTO and ISO regions, including
the levels of wholesale prices, the need for long-term power contracts,
the effectiveness of market monitoring, and the lack of adequate demand
response.\2\ On April 5, 2007, the Commission also held a technical
conference on market monitoring policies and heard from interested
commenters on issues such as the development of the concept and
functions of market monitoring and the market monitoring units' (MMU)
role with respect to the Commission, ISOs and RTOs, and various
stakeholders.\3\ The Commission then held a second competition
conference on May 8, 2007, to examine in more detail several specific
concerns and challenges identified in the first conference. This second
conference focused on regions with organized markets administered by
RTOs and ISOs and dealt with: (1) Demand response, including the role
of demand response during a period of operating reserve shortage; (2)
fostering long-term power contracting; and (3) the responsiveness of
RTOs and ISOs to customers and other stakeholders.\4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ See Second Supplemental Notice of Conference, Conference on
Competition in Wholesale Power Markets, Docket No. AD07-7-000 (Feb.
26, 2007).
\3\ See Notice of Agenda for the Conference, Review of Market
Monitoring Policies, Docket No. AD07-8-000 (Mar. 30, 2007).
\4\ See Supplemental Notice of Conference, Conference on
Competition in Wholesale Power Markets, Docket No. AD07-7-000 (Apr.
19, 2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. Based on the record compiled at these three conferences, the
Commission issued an Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (ANOPR) \5\
on June 22, 2007 to identify and implement improvements to specific
aspects of organized wholesale markets. In the ANOPR, the Commission
identified four issues in organized market regions that were not being
adequately addressed or under consideration in other proceedings. These
areas were: (1) The role of demand response in organized markets and
greater use of market prices to elicit demand response during a period
of operating reserve shortage; (2) increasing opportunities for long-
term power contracting; (3) strengthening market monitoring; and (4)
enhancing the responsiveness of RTOs and ISOs to customers and other
stakeholders, and ultimately to the consumers who benefit from and pay
for electricity services.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized Electric
Markets, Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 72 FR 36,276 (July
2, 2007), FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,617 (2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. The Commission received several thousand pages of comments from
over a hundred commenters in response to the ANOPR (a list of
commenters and their abbreviated names the Commission will use for them
in this document appears in Appendix A).\6\ After review of the
comments, and pursuant to our responsibility under
[[Page 12578]]
sections 205 and 206 of the Federal Power Act (FPA) \7\ to ensure that
rates, charges, classifications, and service of public utilities (and
any rule, regulation, practice, or contract affecting any of these) are
just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory, the Commission is
making several proposals in this NOPR designed to ensure just and
reasonable rates and to remedy undue discrimination and preference and
to improve wholesale competition in regions with organized markets.
These proposals reflect the record compiled by the Commission in its
conferences and in comments to the ANOPR. These proposals, along with
background information and a summary of comments received, will be
described in detail in the sections below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ We do not summarize in this NOPR every comment received in
response to the ANOPR. The Commission has reviewed and considered
each comment submitted, however, and appreciates the careful
consideration the commenters have given to this proceeding.
\7\ 16 U.S.C. 824d-824e (2000).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. In proposing the reforms in the four areas described below, the
Commission recognizes that there are differences of opinion on the
appropriate scope of this rulemaking, as well as on the four specific
issues described in the ANOPR. We are therefore guided by the record in
this proceeding and the need to undertake timely and concrete reforms
where the record supports them. From the commencement of our first
technical conference in this proceeding, our goal has been to identify
any specific reforms that can be made to optimize the efficiency of
organized markets for the benefit of customers, and ultimately the
consumers who benefit from and pay for electricity services. As we
explain further below, however, this proceeding does not represent the
final effort to improve the efficiency of competitive markets. Rather,
we will continue to evaluate other specific reforms that may be
necessary.
6. In the area of demand response and the use of market prices to
elicit demand response, the Commission proposes several requirements
for ISOs and RTOs. These proposals include requirements to: (1) Accept
bids from demand response resources in their markets for certain
ancillary services, comparable to any other resources; (2) eliminate,
during a system emergency, a charge to a buyer in the energy market for
taking less electric energy in the real-time market than purchased in
the day-ahead market; (3) permit an aggregator of retail customers
(ARC) to bid demand response on behalf of retail customers directly
into the organized energy market; (4) modify their market rules, as
necessary, to allow the market-clearing price, during periods of
operating reserve shortage, to reach a level that rebalances supply and
demand so as to maintain reliability while providing sufficient
provisions for mitigating market power; and (5) study whether further
reforms are necessary to eliminate barriers to demand response in
organized markets.
7. In the section on long-term power contracting, the Commission
proposes that ISOs and RTOs be required to dedicate a portion of their
Web sites for market participants to post offers to buy or sell power
on a long-term basis. This proposal is designed to promote greater use
of long-term contracts through improving transparency among market
participants.
8. In the area of improving market monitoring, the Commission
proposes that each RTO and ISO provide its MMU with access to market
data, resources and personnel sufficient to carry out its duties, and
that the MMU (or the external MMU in a hybrid structure) report
directly to the RTO or ISO board. In addition, the Commission proposes
to require that the MMU's functions include: (1) Identifying
ineffective market rules and recommending proposed rules and tariff
changes; (2) reviewing and reporting on the performance of the
wholesale markets to the RTO or ISO, the Commission, and other
interested entities; and (3) notifying appropriate Commission staff of
instances in which a market participant's behavior requires
investigation. The Commission also proposes expanding the list of
recipients to receive MMU recommendations regarding rule and tariff
changes, and broadening the scope of behavior to be reported to the
Commission. The Commission further proposes to remove the MMU from
tariff administration, require each RTO and ISO to include ethics
standards for MMU employees in its tariff, and consolidate all its MMU
provisions in one section of its tariff. The Commission also proposes
expanding the dissemination of MMU market information to a broader
constituency, with reports made on a more frequent basis, and reducing
the time period before energy market bid and offer data are released to
the public.
9. Finally, the Commission proposes to establish new criteria
intended to ensure that an RTO or ISO is responsive to its customers
and stakeholders, and ultimately to the consumers who benefit from and
pay for electricity services. These principles will include: (1)
Inclusiveness; (2) fairness in balancing diverse interests; (3)
representation of minority positions; and (4) ongoing responsiveness.
10. In each of these four areas, the Commission will require RTOs
and ISOs to consult with their stakeholders and make a compliance
filing that details why the entity's existing practices comply with the
final rule in this proceeding, or the entity's plans to attain
compliance.
11. Finally, as indicated above, these reforms do not represent our
final effort to improve the functioning of competitive organized
markets for the benefit of consumers. For example, although we are
proposing specific reforms to eliminate barriers to demand response, we
propose to require each RTO or ISO to study whether further reforms are
necessary to eliminate barriers to demand response in organized
markets. Any reforms must ensure that demand response resources are
treated on a comparable basis as other resources. We also are ordering
a staff technical conference on proposals by American Forest and
Portland Cement Association, et al. to modify the design of organized
markets. Finally, we direct, as explained further below, each RTO or
ISO to provide a forum for affected consumers to voice specific
concerns (and to propose regional solutions) on how to improve the
efficient operation of competitive markets. The Commission therefore
will continue to evaluate reforms in this area, but will not allow the
prospect of other reforms to delay the benefits to consumers from those
proposed herein.
II. Background
12. As the Commission noted in the ANOPR, national policy has been,
and continues to be, to foster competition in wholesale electric power
markets.\8\ This policy was embraced in the recent Energy Policy Act of
2005 (EPAct 2005),\9\ and is reflected in Commission policy and
practice. The Commission, in fulfilling its responsibility to ``guard
the consumer from exploitation by non-competitive electric power
companies,'' \10\ relies on both its own regulations and competition to
ensure consumer protection. In doing so, the Commission is aware of the
need to vary the mix of regulation and competition based on the
circumstances of the time, taking into account advances of technology,
changes in economies of scale, and new state and federal laws that
affect the energy industry.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ ANOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,617 at P 4.
\9\ Pub. L. No. 109-58, 119 Stat. 594 (2005).
\10\ Nat'l Ass'n for the Advancement of Colored People v. FPC,
520 F.2d 432, 438 (DC Cir. 1975), aff'd, 425 U.S. 662 (1976).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
13. The Commission has acted over the last few decades to implement
Congressional policy to expand the wholesale electric power markets to
facilitate entry of new generators and to support competitive markets.
Absent a
[[Page 12579]]
single national power market, the development of regional markets is
the best method of facilitating competition within the power industry,
and the Commission has made sustained efforts to recognize and foster
such markets. The Commission acknowledges that significant differences
exist between regions, including differences in industry structure, mix
of ownership, sources for electric generation, population densities,
and weather patterns. Some regions have organized spot markets
administered by an RTO or ISO, and others rely solely on bilateral
contracting between wholesale sellers and buyers. The Commission
recognizes and respects these differences across various regions. At
the same time, wholesale competition can serve customers well in all
regions. The focus of this proceeding is on further improving the
operation of wholesale competitive markets in organized market
regions.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ The following RTOs and ISOs have organized markets: PJM
Interconnection, LLC (PJM), New York Independent System Operator,
Inc. (NYISO), Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator, Inc.
(Midwest ISO), ISO New England, Inc. (ISO-NE), California
Independent Service Operator Corp. (CAISO), and Southwest Power
Pool, Inc. (SPP).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
14. Some perceived challenges in the organized wholesale markets
may be closely related to state retail issues, and the distinction
between wholesale and retail competition challenges is often blurred.
For example, wholesale customers typically have more advanced meters
than retail customers; organized market rates vary with time of day
whereas retail rates typically do not; and retail choice programs,
which tend to be in areas served by organized wholesale markets, may
rely on RTOs or ISOs to provide or arrange for the provision of some
functions previously carried out by vertically integrated utilities.
This has created challenges for wholesale market design. Although the
Commission acknowledges that issues with retail markets are often
intertwined with wholesale market issues, the Commission will not
address retail market issues in this proceeding. This rulemaking is
designed to focus on wholesale markets; issues related to retail
markets will vary by state and are more appropriately considered in
separate proceedings before the affected state(s) or the Commission
where the specific interaction between the retail and wholesale market
can be explored.
15. Comments received on the ANOPR and made during technical
conferences highlight several potential problems with wholesale
competition both inside and outside the organized market regions that
are within the scope of this proceeding. In the ANOPR, the Commission
noted that it was not addressing potential reforms outside the
organized market regions, explaining that many of the important
concerns discussed during the first technical conference (e.g.,
nondiscriminatory access to transmission, nondiscriminatory rules for
power procurement) were already being addressed in other proceedings.
Similarly, the Commission has chosen to limit this proceeding to four
discrete areas involving wholesale competition within organized
markets. As explained further below, however, these are not the final
reforms the Commission may pursue with respect to organized markets;
rather, we will continue to evaluate specific proposals that may serve
to strengthen organized markets.
III. Proposals To Expand the Scope of the Proceeding
16. Several parties propose to expand the scope of this proceeding
beyond the four areas covered in the ANOPR. We received a request from
APPA, in its comments on the ANOPR, and a request from AARP, et al., a
group consisting of 41 entities, for a large-scale investigation of the
workings of organized markets with respect to their ability to produce
just and reasonable rates. APPA and AARP, et al. state that the current
market system allows incumbent sellers (those power suppliers with
older power plants) to make excess profits while disadvantaging certain
power suppliers with new generation. APPA and AARP, et al. argue that
this has resulted in increased cost to consumers without the
corresponding benefit of new generation being built. APPA and AARP, et
al. claim that the Commission has a responsibility under sections 205
and 206 of the FPA to investigate the workings of organized markets
based on their allegations of unjust and unreasonable rates.
17. The Commission acknowledges the concerns of APPA and AARP, et
al.; however, we decline to initiate the broad investigation APPA and
AARP, et al. have requested as part of this proceeding. As noted above,
by listening to the concerns of market participants, and evaluating the
record of this proceeding, we have identified four specific areas in
which reforms can improve wholesale electricity market operations.
Through the competition conferences and the ANOPR process, we have
developed a solid record in favor of making those reforms, and a strong
sense of what the Commission can do to be helpful in these four areas.
It is important that the Commission move forward with regard to the
specific reforms under consideration in this proposed rulemaking to
foster improvements in the near term to the competitive operation of
existing organized markets administered by RTOs and ISOs. Further, we
also note that the approach we are taking in this NOPR is consistent
with the ISO/RTO Council's proposal.\12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ ISO/RTO Council urges the Commission to focus on
determining the appropriate means of addressing issues that are ripe
for this NOPR and which ones might be better considered in existing
forums. It states that existing stakeholder processes provide an
appropriate forum for targeted consideration of various issues,
including the ones raised by APPA and AARP, et al. ISO/RTO Council
at 1, 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
18. In contrast to the specific reforms proposed herein, APPA and
AARP, et al. request a broad, generic inquiry into alleged (but not
specified) market design flaws. Their request not only fails to offer
any specific solutions, but also fails to appreciate the differences in
market design that exist in each region. Over the past five years, the
Commission has undertaken significant market design reforms in most
regions. We have not adopted a standard market design, but rather have
undertaken different reforms, at different times in each region to
reflect the differing characteristics of each market. The Commission
has devoted considerable resources over the years to improving the
market designs in each organized market to ensure that they produce
just and reasonable rates. We summarize some of these efforts below.
19. For example, in response to the California energy crisis of
2000-2001, the Commission worked with CAISO and its stakeholders to
develop a Market Redesign and Technology Upgrade program designed to
improve the efficiency and proper working of the market through
improved modeling and new forward markets,\13\ which the Commission
subsequently approved in part. In 2004, the Commission approved the
Midwest ISO's open access transmission and energy markets tariff, which
provides for terms and conditions necessary to implement a market-based
congestion management program and energy spot markets.\14\ This
includes a day-ahead energy market and a real-time energy market,
[[Page 12580]]
locational marginal pricing, and a market for financial transmission
rights.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ Cal. Indep. Sys. Operator Corp., 116 FERC ] 61,274 (2006),
order on reh'g, 119 FERC ] 61,076 (2007).
\14\ Midwest Indep. Transmission Sys. Operator, Inc., 108 FERC ]
61,163, order on reh'g, 109 FERC ] 61,157 (2004), order on reh'g 111
FERC ] 61,043, reh'g denied, 112 FERC ] 61,086 (2005), aff'd sub
nom. Wisconsin Public Power, Inc. v. FERC, 493 F.3d 239 (DC Cir.
2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
20. The Commission has also acted on proposals developed by
regional entities to ensure that adequate price signals exist in the
market for both short-term and long-term electric power transactions,
by addressing pricing issues during reserve shortages and by approving
forward capacity markets. The Commission has approved a demand curve
for capacity markets in the region operated by NYISO. The Commission
approved PJM's Reliability Pricing Model to provide an auction process
for forward capacity contracting. The Commission also approved a
settlement agreement for ISO-NE to create a transitional forward
capacity market to meet the needs of its stakeholders.\15\ These
actions were designed to minimize the disruption during periods of
operating reserve shortage and encourage new investment in generation,
while accepting variation between regions and allowing for regional
choice.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ Devon Power, LLC, 115 FERC ] 61,340, order on reh'g, 117
FERC ] 61,133 (2006), appeal pending sub nom. Maine Pub. Utils.
Comm'n v. FERC, No. 06-1403 (DC Cir. 2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
21. The Commission has also issued region-specific orders providing
for cost allocation for new transmission investment, removing
uncertainty over the cost responsibility for the development of new
transmission. In Opinion No. 494,\16\ the Commission approved PJM's
policy for determining recovery of transmission costs for existing and
new facilities, providing for region-wide cost sharing for certain new
extra high-voltage transmission facilities. The Commission also
approved the Midwest ISO's transitional pricing scheme, which
incorporates cost sharing for new transmission facilities.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ PJM Interconnection, LLC, 119 FERC ] 61,063 (2007) (Opinion
No. 494), reh'g pending.
\17\ Midwest Indep. Transmission Sys. Operator, Inc., 114 FERC ]
61,106, order on reh'g and technical conference, 117 FERC ] 61,241
(2006), order on reh'g, 118 FERC ] 61,208 (2007), appeal pending sub
nom. Public Service Comm'n of Wisconsin v. FERC, No. 06-1408 (D.C.
Cir., filed Dec. 13, 2006); Midwest Indep. Transmission Sys.
Operator, Inc., 118 FERC ] 61,209, order on reh'g, 120 FERC ] 61,080
(2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. In addition to these region-specific actions, the Commission
has addressed incentives for the building of new generation and
transmission in all regions with organized markets. In Order No.
679,\18\ the Commission allowed parties building transmission to apply
for recovery of prudently incurred costs for construction work in
progress, pre-operations, and abandoned facilities, and it provided for
application for an incentive rate of return on equity for new
transmission investment. As a further means of reducing uncertainty and
spurring investment, the Commission finalized rules for interconnection
for large, small and wind generators. These rules remove barriers to
interconnection by streamlining the process of, and improving
incentives for, building new generation. The Commission has also acted
to improve certainty in the cost of transmission for electric customers
by creating rules for long-term transmission rights in Order Nos. 681
and 681-A.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Promoting Transmission Investment through Pricing Reform,
Order No. 679, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,222, order on reh'g, Order
No. 679-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,236 (2006), order on reh'g, 119
FERC ] 61,062 (2007).
\19\ Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity
Markets, Order No. 681, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,226, order on
reh'g, Order No. 681-A, 117 FERC ] 61,201 (2006).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
23. In Order No. 890, the Commission reformed the open access
transmission tariff (OATT) to ensure that it continues to provide
nondiscriminatory access to transmission service. Among other things,
Order No. 890 requires an open and transparent regional transmission
planning process.\20\ The Commission is now focusing on the compliance
phase of OATT reform to ensure that it is implemented properly.\21\ The
Commission also has been pursuing a cooperative dialogue with the
National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) to
identify and analyze models for competitive power procurement. This
effort is designed to enhance the ability of load-serving entities
(LSEs) to acquire reliable power supplies at competitive prices. As
noted in the ANOPR, the Commission has also acted to investigate demand
response in organized markets, through a Commission report and a recent
technical conference. This conference was designed to examine demand
response resources in markets, grid operations and expansion, and best
practices for the measurement and evaluation of demand response
resources.\22\ The Commission also held a technical conference on
December 11, 2007 to explore issues surrounding the management of
interconnection queues.\23\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ This addresses, in part, concerns raised by some commenters
regarding posting of future transmission constraints and congestion
costs.
\21\ ANOPR, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 32,617 at P 33 (citing
Preventing Undue Discrimination and Preference in Transmission
Service, Order No. 890, 72 FR 12,266 (Mar. 15, 2007), FERC Stats. &
Regs. ] 31,241, order on reh'g, Order No. 890-A, FERC Stats. & Regs.
] 31,261 (2007)).
\22\ Supplemental Notice, Demand Response in Wholesale Markets,
Docket No. AD07-11-000 (April 6, 2007).
\23\ Notice of Technical Conference, Interconnection Queuing
Practices, Docket No. AD08-2-000 (November 2, 2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
24. In recognition of our continuing respect for regional
differences in market design, we believe that, if there are specific
concerns about the market designs in a particular region, they should
be considered, in the first instance, at the regional level. We
therefore direct each RTO or ISO to provide a forum for affected
consumers to voice specific concerns (and to propose regional
solutions) to the issues raised generically by APPA and AARP, et al.
Although most existing stakeholder processes already allow for the
submission of such proposals, we encourage RTOs and ISOs to give
priority to any significant concerns that may be raised on these
issues, including concerns as to the value to the market of significant
changes to the market rules. For example, PJM recently has conducted a
series of forums on long-term contracts to gather information and
facilitate the exchange of ideas on this important issue. We encourage
similar efforts on the concerns raised by APPA and AARP, et al. Any
proposed solutions should be vetted through the stakeholder process and
ultimately considered by the boards of the RTOs or ISOs. Ultimately,
such matters may be brought to the Commission after consideration by
the region. We encourage each region to commence the consideration of
any such issues in the near future and not await the issuance of a
final rule in this proceeding.
25. However, those entities that have such concerns have a
responsibility to propose solutions to address those concerns. For
example, American Forest submitted comments that contained a mechanism,
the Financial Performance Obligation (FPO), to address concerns that
they raised regarding the structure of organized markets. Portland
Cement Association, et al., also included a proposed solution in its
comments to address their concerns regarding the organized markets. We
are encouraged by entities that actually propose solutions rather than
merely identify concerns without proposing any meaningful ways to
address those concerns. While we do not adopt these proposals in this
proceeding, we believe that they warrant additional consideration.
Therefore, as explained below, we direct Staff to convene a technical
conference regarding the American Forest and Portland Cement
Association, et al., proposals so that the Commission and the industry
can learn
[[Page 12581]]
more about the proposals and the merit of adopting such changes where
appropriate.
IV. Discussion
A. Demand Response and Pricing During Periods of Operating Reserve
Shortages in Organized Markets
26. This section of the NOPR proposes several reforms to further
eliminate barriers to demand response in organized energy markets.
These reforms must ensure that demand response is treated comparably to
other resources. The Commission proposes to require RTOs and ISOs to:
(1) Accept bids from demand response resources in their markets for
certain ancillary services, comparable to other resources; (2)
eliminate, during a system emergency, certain charges to buyers in the
energy market for voluntarily reducing demand; and (3) permit ARCs to
bid demand response on behalf of retail customers directly into the
RTO's or ISO's organized markets.\24\ We also propose that RTOs and
ISOs modify their rules governing price formation during periods of
operating reserve shortage. These proposals, if adopted, would require
market rules to ensure that demand response can participate directly
and is treated comparably to supply resources in the organized electric
energy and ancillary services markets. We also propose to require that
each RTO and ISO study further reforms to address any remaining
barriers to ensure that demand response is treated comparably to other
resources and to report to the Commission within six months of the date
of the final rule in this proceeding. In addition, we propose that each
RTO or ISO must adopt reasonable standards necessary for system
operators to call on demand response resources, and mechanisms to
measure, verify, and ensure compliance with any such standards.\25\ As
discussed further below, we intend to direct staff to convene a
technical conference to explore issues that the RTOs and ISOs should
include as part of these studies. The specific reforms being proposed
here are therefore the next step in removing barriers to demand
response, but not the final step.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ We will use the phrase ``aggregation of retail customers''
to refer to parties that aggregate demand response bids (which are
mostly from retail loads), or ARCs.
\25\ We understand that some RTOs and ISOs may already be
developing measurement and verification requirements, as well as
appropriate mechanisms to ensure compliance. It is not our intention
that these programs be delayed based on our proposals here.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
1. Background
27. The Commission has expressed the view on numerous occasions
that the wholesale electric power market works best when demand can
respond to the wholesale price.\26\ Based on the view that the value to
customers of electric power varies,\27\ the Commission's policy is to
eliminate barriers to the participation of demand response in the
organized power markets, in part because demand response helps to hold
down wholesale power prices; increases awareness of energy usage;
provides for more efficient operation of markets; mitigates market
power; enhances reliability; and encourages new technologies that
support the use of renewable energy resources, distributed generation,
and advanced metering. The reforms we propose today would further
facilitate demand response by removing several barriers to demand
response. This will benefit customers of electric energy because
increased demand response will improve price signals and provide for
greater flexibility. We provide background on the benefits of demand
response and prior Commission actions addressing demand response below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ New England Power Pool and ISO New England, Inc., 101 FERC
] 61,344, at P 44-49 (2002), order on reh'g, 103 FERC ] 61,304,
order on reh'g, 105 FERC ] 61,211 (2003); PJM Interconnection, LLC,
95 FERC ] 61,306 (2001); PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ] 61,227
(2002); Southwest Power Pool, Inc., 116 FERC ] 61,289 (2006).
\27\ That is, for two customers at the same time and place, one
customer may prefer to reduce consumption if the price is high, and
the other may be willing to pay a high price to avoid curtailment in
an emergency.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
a. Importance of Demand Response to Competition in RTO/ISO Areas
28. A well-functioning competitive wholesale electric market should
reflect current supply and demand conditions. Enabling demand-side
responses, as well as supply-side resources, improves the economic
operation of electric power markets by aligning prices more closely
with the value customers place on electric power.
29. Demand response helps to reduce prices in competitive wholesale
markets in at least three ways. First, demand response has both a
direct effect and an indirect effect on wholesale demand. The direct
effect occurs when demand response is bid directly into the wholesale
market: lower demand means a lower wholesale price. Demand response at
retail, if not bid directly into the wholesale market by a retail
customer, affects the wholesale market indirectly because it reduces
the need for power by the retail customers' LSE and in turn reduces
that LSE's need to purchase power from the wholesale market.\28\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ See Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Assessment of
Demand Response and Advanced Metering: Staff Report, Docket No.
AD06-2-000, at 11 (August 8, 2006) (2006 FERC Staff Demand Response
Assessment).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
30. Second, demand response tends to flatten an area's load
profile. The combination of reductions in peak demand and a shift of at
least a portion of this peak demand to non-peak periods due to demand
response would tend to make peak and off-peak demand less divergent--a
flatter load profile. A flatter load profile would reduce the need to
use the more costly resources during periods of high demand, which
tends to shift the distribution of resource types toward lower-cost
base load generation and away from higher-cost peaking generation. This
effect tends to lower the overall average cost to produce energy.\29\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
31. Third, demand response can help reduce generator market power.
As more demand response generally is available during peak periods,
power suppliers need to account more for the price responsiveness of
load when they consider submitting higher-price bids. The more demand
response is able to reduce the peak price, the more downward pressure
it places on generator bidding strategies by increasing the risk to a
supplier that it will not be dispatched if it bids too high.\30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ Id. at 12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Prior Commission Actions To Address Demand Response
32. The Commission has issued numerous orders over the last several
years on various aspects of electric demand response in organized
markets. A goal of most of these orders was to remove unnecessary
obstacles to demand response participating in the wholesale power
markets of RTOs and ISOs.\31\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 92 FERC ]
61,073, order on clarification, 92 FERC ] 61,181 (2000), order on
reh'g, 97 FERC ] 61,154 (2001); New England Power Pool and ISO New
England, Inc., 100 FERC ] 61,287, order on reh'g, 101 FERC ] 61,344
(2002), order on reh'g, 103 FERC ] 61,304, order on reh'g, 105 FERC
] 61,211 (2003); PJM Interconnection, LLC, 95 FERC ] 61,306 (2001);
PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ] 61,139 (2002); PJM
Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ] 61,227 (2002).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
33. These orders approved various types of demand response
programs, including programs to allow demand response to be used as a
capacity resource \32\ and as a resource during
[[Page 12582]]
system emergencies,\33\ to allow wholesale buyers and qualifying large
retail buyers to bid demand response directly into the day-ahead and
real-time energy markets and certain ancillary service markets,
particularly as a provider of operating reserves, as well as programs
to accept bids from ARCs.\34\ The Commission also has approved special
demand response applications such as use of demand response for
synchronized reserves and regulation service.\35\ The theme underlying
the Commission's approval of these programs has been to allow demand
response resources to participate in these markets on a basis that is
comparable to other resources.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\32\ See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, LLC, 117 FERC ] 61,331
(2006); Devon Power LLC, 115 FERC ] 61,340, order on reh'g, 117 FERC
] 61,133 (2006), appeal pending sub nom. Maine Pub. Utils. Comm'n v.
FERC, No. 06-1403 (DC Cir. 2007).
\33\ See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 95 FERC ]
61,136 (2001); NSTAR Services Co. v. New England Power Pool, 95 FERC
] 61,250 (2001); New England Power Pool and ISO New England, Inc.,
100 FERC ] 61,287, order on reh'g, 101 FERC ] 61,344 (2002), order
on reh'g, 103 FERC ] 61,304, order on reh'g, 105 FERC ] 61,211
(2003); PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ] 61,139 (2002).
\34\ See, e.g., New York Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 95 FERC ]
61,223 (2001); New England Power Pool and ISO New England, Inc., 100
FERC ] 61,287, order on reh'g, 101 FERC ] 61,344 (2002), order on
reh'g, 103 FERC ] 61,304, order on reh'g, 105 FERC ] 61,211 (2003);
PJM Interconnection, LLC, 99 FERC ] 61,227 (2002).
\35\ See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, LLC, 114 FERC ] 61,201
(2006).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
34. The Commission has approved programs that allow smaller retail
customers--that cannot individually meet the RTO or ISO minimum bid
size threshold--to combine individual demand response into a larger
block for bidding into the organized markets, if permitted by state
law, without having to go through their LSE.\36\ A third-party ARC,
often called a curtailment service provider, typically provides this
aggregation service. The aggregate demand response may be bid directly
into the energy and ancillary services markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\36\ Supra note 34.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
35. In addition, the Commission has explicitly addressed demand
response in its recent Final Rules on OATT Reform (Order No. 890) and
reliability standards (Order No. 693).\37\ Order No. 890 requires any
public utility with an OATT to allow qualified demand response
resources to participate in its regional transmission planning process
on a comparable basis to generation resources and to allow qualified
demand response to provide certain ancillary services. Specifically,
the Commission agreed with Alcoa's request that load resources (i.e.,
demand response) should be permitted to self-supply and sell ancillary
services to third parties.\38\ In doing so, the Commission also made
clear that a transmission provider may use non-generation resources in
meeting its OATT obligation to provide ancillary services, so long as
those resources are capable of providing the service.\39\ Order No. 693
requires the Electricity Reliability Organization to revise its
reliability standards so that all technically feasible resource
options, including demand response and generating resources, may be
employed in the management of grid operations and emergencies.\40\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ See Mandatory Reliability Standards for the Bulk-Power
System, Order No. 693, 72 FR 16,416 (April 4, 2007), FERC Stats. &
Regs. ] 31,242, order on reh'g, Order No. 693-A, 120 FERC ] 61,053
(2007).
\38\ Order No. 890, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,241 at P 887-88.
\39\ E.g., Order No. 890, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,241 at OATT
Schedule 5 (Operating Reserve--Spinning Reserve Service). Order No.
890 does not require transmission providers, however, to purchase
ancillary services from non-generation resources or generation
resources.
\40\ Order No. 693 directed the Electricity Reliability
Organization to develop new versions of its BAL-002, BAL-005, and
EOP-002 reliability standards to allow demand side resources to
provide contingency reserves. Order No. 693, FERC Stats. & Regs. ]
31,242 at P 330-35, 404-06, 573.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
36. The Commission has also worked closely with state regulators to
examine demand response issues. The NARUC-FERC Collaborative Dialogue
on Demand Response began in November 2006 to explore state-federal
coordination of efforts to promote and integrate demand response into
retail and wholesale markets. The Commission has conducted several
technical conferences on demand response over the last several years,
most recently on April 23, 2007.\41\ In addition, as mentioned, in
response to a requirement of EPAct 2005 \42\ to assess demand response
capability nationally, in August 2006 the Commission published a staff
report on demand response and advanced metering.\43\ In September 2007,
the Commission published its second annual staff report on demand
response and advanced metering.\44\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\41\ For example, the Commission conducted a technical
conference on January 25, 2006 to help prepare for a survey and a
staff report on demand response in Docket No. AD06-2-000. See supra
note 28. The April 23, 2007 conference was convened in Docket No.
AD07-11-000.
\42\ Public Law No. 109-58, Sec. 1252(e)(3), 119 Stat. 594, 966
(2005).
\43\ See 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment.
\44\ See Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 2007 Assessment
of Demand Response and Advanced Metering: Staff Report, (September
2007) (2007 FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. The Need for Commission Action
37. While the Commission and the various RTOs and ISOs have done
much to eliminate barriers to demand response in organized power
markets, more needs to be done to ensure comparable treatment of all
resources. The 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment estimated the
total installed demand response capability from existing programs
nationally to be 37,500 MWs, or about five percent of current peak
demand.\45\ Several reports indicate that the potential demand response
capability available in the United States may be much greater.\46\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment at 7.
\46\ See, e.g., Ahmad Faruqui et al., The Brattle Group, The
Power of Five Percent: How Dynamic Pricing Can Save $35 Billion in
Electricity Costs (May 16, 2007), available at https://
www.brattle.com/_documents/UploadLibrary/Upload574.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
38. The Commission's policy is to eliminate barriers to the
participation of demand response in the organized power markets by
ensuring comparable treatment of resources. This position is consistent
with EPAct 2005, which states that demand response shall be encouraged
and unnecessary barriers to demand response participation in energy,
capacity, and ancillary service markets shall be eliminated.\47\ The
Commission can take additional steps to further encourage demand
response to improve the operation of the organized energy and ancillary
services markets by removing several unnecessary barriers to demand
response participation.\48\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\47\ Section 1252(f) of the EPAct 2005 states that, ``[i]t is
the policy of the United States that time-based pricing and other
forms of demand response whereby electricity customers are provided
with electricity price signals and the ability to benefit by
responding to them, shall be encouraged, the deployment of such
technology and devices that enable electricity customers to
participate in such pricing and demand response systems shall be
facilitated, and unnecessary barriers to demand response
participation in energy, capacity, and ancillary service markets
shall be eliminated.''
\48\ We note that while the Commission can remove some obstacles
to demand participation in organized markets, more effective demand
response also requires the action of state commissions. An effective
way for demand to respond to price is at the retail level, through
some form of time-based retail rates (e.g., rates that vary by hour,
such as real-time pricing, or by blocks of time, such as time-of-use
rates or critical peak pricing). Demand response is more effective
when retail rates are tied to current wholesale market-clearing
prices. Effective demand response can be achieved by linking the
wholesale and retail markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
39. The Commission can further eliminate barriers to the
participation of demand response in certain ancillary services markets.
Some forms of demand response are well suited to provide the ancillary
services of spinning reserves, supplemental
[[Page 12583]]
reserves, energy imbalance, and regulation and frequency response.\49\
Because demand is always connected and demand response, in principle,
can always be available, some forms of demand response resources may be
able to provide a rapid, near real-time response.\50\ Nevertheless, not
all RTOs and ISOs allow demand response to participate in ancillary
services markets. ISO-NE, NYISO, and CAISO allow demand response
resources to provide supplemental (non-spinning) reserves. As of mid-
2007, only PJM allows demand response resources to provide synchronized
reserves (PJM's term for spinning reserves) and regulation service.\51\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\49\ See 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment at 51. For
an explanation of each of these ancillary services, see the pro
forma OATT, Schedules 3 through 6, contained in Order No. 890.
\50\ For example, electric-arc steel furnaces have the
capability to adjust their consumption rapidly, and air conditioner
cycling programs can respond within several minutes of execution.
\51\ We note, however, that no resource has yet qualified to
provide this service to PJM.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
40. In Order No. 890, the Commission modified the definitions of
certain ancillary services in the pro forma open access transmission
tariff to clarify that demand response is eligible to supply these
ancillary services on a comparable basis to generation resources. Order
No. 890 concluded, however, that procurement and pricing of ancillary
services--including issues related to competitive procurement--were
beyond the scope of that rulemaking. Though RTOs and ISOs procure
ancillary services through competitive market means, they are not
currently required to accept bids from qualified demand response
providers to provide ancillary services even if those providers are
technically capable of doing so. This hinders the integration of
qualified demand response resources into these RTO and ISO ancillary
services markets.
41. One reason for the lack of participation of demand response in
some ancillary service markets may be that market rules for bidding and
participating in ancillary services markets were developed with
generation in mind and may not accommodate demand response resources.
For example, many demand response resources can respond quickly and at
a low cost if called upon for a short duration, which may make them
well suited for providing operating reserves. If market rules require,
however, that a single bid be made into a joint energy-plus-reserves
market (also known as a ``co-optimized'' market), those seeking to
offer operating reserves risk being dispatched to provide energy or
other ancillary services for which they are not well suited. As a
result, a potential operating reserve provider that does not wish to be
called upon frequently or for a prolonged period in the energy market
may simply decide not to participate in a co-optimized market, and
consequently not be a source for providing demand response resources as
operating reserves. Market rules that do not allow a demand response
provider to limit the frequency and duration of interruption may
thereby create a disincentive for a demand response resource to bid
into the operating reserves market.\52\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\52\ See 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment at 123.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
42. Further, demand response providers need market rules that allow
bids to be flexible and that reflect bidders' willingness to offer
various levels of service depending on the market prices. While the
design of today's organized markets does allow some flexible and some
price-sensitive bidding into day-ahead and real-time energy markets,
the Commission is nevertheless concerned that some market features may
inhibit LSEs and other demand response providers from bidding load
reductions into energy markets. For example, in most organized markets,
if an LSE's actual purchase from the real-time market differs from the
purchase it scheduled in the day-ahead market, it may be assessed an
uplift charge (separate from any imbalance charge). This uplift charge
recovers certain costs of extra generation when day-ahead purchases
exceed real-time purchases. However, these costs may be minimal during
an emergency when there is no extra generation. Further, this uplift
charge may unnecessarily discourage an LSE from urging retail customers
to conserve energy during a system emergency. RTO and ISO tariffs also
do not impose these types of charges on generators that generate more
power during system emergencies than scheduled. Eliminating this uplift
charge for demand response sought by RTOs or ISOs from buyers in an
emergency removes a disincentive for this demand response and promotes
comparable treatment of demand and supply resources.
43. Organized energy market rules also may restrict the type of bid
that a LSE or ARC may submit.\53\ There is usually a minimum bid size
threshold in an RTO or ISO market. Also, it is hard for some demand
response providers to participate if, for example, they are not able to
start and stop frequently or if cycling output up and down produces
excessive stress on their equipment. Aggregation programs can improve
the participation of small retail loads that lack standing as an LSE or
individually cannot meet a requirement that a demand response bid be of
minimum size. These programs allow a larger number of customers to
access demand response programs, which increases the potential market
and reliability benefits realized from demand response in wholesale
markets. The 2006 FERC Staff Demand Response Assessment and comments
that we have received indicate, however, that more needs to be done to
facilitate the direct participation of ARCs in energy markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\53\ In some cases, this may be intended to treat a demand
response resource bid the same as a generation bid, but more often,
bidding features available to generation, such as a guaranteed
minimum price, are not available to demand response resources.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
44. Another factor that may limit participation in demand response
programs is the use of bid caps and price caps in wholesale market
design. Bid caps and price caps in RTO and ISO markets are designed to
limit the opportunity to exercise market power in these markets, but
they also may prevent the markets from expressing prices that are
legitimately high due to a shortage. These caps may not permit buyers
in RTO and ISO wholesale energy markets to see prices high enough to
signal that there is a period of operating reserve shortage and that
reliability is at risk. Moreover, when power is in short supply and
price is high, retail prices remain fixed, and retail customers do not
adjust their demand to react to wholesale price signals. Consequently,
both generation and demand response can be in short supply at once, and
the market-clearing price may not reflect the actual cost of providing
more power or the value to customers of not being interrupted. Further,
as discussed in the long-term contracting section below, capping the
exposure of