Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release Market, 65916-65936 [E7-22952]
Download as PDF
65916
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
TABLE 1.—PRIOR/CONCURRENT REQUIREMENTS—Continued
Describes procedures for these prior or concurrent actions—
For—
Boeing 727 service bulletin—
(2) Airplanes specified as Options III, IV and V
configurations in Boeing Special Attention
Service Bulletin 727–32–0338, Revision 4.
32–79, Revision 1, dated February 27, 1967 ..
Modifying the MLG side strut universal joint.
32–157, dated August 30, 1968 ......................
Replacing the MLG side strut swivel bushing,
incorporating only Parts Kit 65–89855–1,
and not installing the lube fitting in the
lower segment.
Inspecting and modifying the MLG side strut.
(3) Airplanes specified as Option V configuration in Boeing Special Attention Service Bulletin 727–32–0338, Revision 4.
727–32–268, Revision 2, dated February 20,
1981.
727–57–163, dated September 17, 1982 ........
Alternative Methods of Compliance
(AMOCs)
(h)(1) The Manager, Seattle Aircraft
Certification Office (ACO), FAA, has the
authority to approve AMOCs for this AD, if
requested in accordance with the procedures
found in 14 CFR 39.19.
(2) To request a different method of
compliance or a different compliance time
for this AD, follow the procedures in 14 CFR
39.19. Before using any approved AMOC on
any airplane to which the AMOC applies,
notify your appropriate principal inspector
(PI) in the FAA Flight Standards District
Office (FSDO), or lacking a PI, your local
FSDO.
(3) An AMOC that provides an acceptable
level of safety may be used for any repair
required by this AD, if it is approved by an
Authorized Representative for the Boeing
Commercial Airplanes Delegation Option
Authorization Organization who has been
authorized by the Manager, Seattle ACO, to
make those findings. For a repair method to
be approved, the repair must meet the
certification basis of the airplane, and the
approval must specifically refer to this AD.
Issued in Renton, Washington, on
November 13, 2007.
Ali Bahrami,
Manager, Transport Airplane Directorate,
Aircraft Certification Service.
[FR Doc. E7–22939 Filed 11–23–07; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 4910–13–P
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
18 CFR Part 284
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
[Docket No. RM08–1–000]
Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity
Release Market
November 15, 2007.
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, Department of Energy.
ACTION: Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.
AGENCY:
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission is proposing
revisions to its regulations governing
interstate natural gas pipelines to reflect
changes in the market for short-term
transportation services on pipelines and
to improve the efficiency of the
Commission’s capacity release
mechanism. The Commission is
proposing to permit market based
pricing for short-term capacity releases
and to facilitate asset management
arrangements by relaxing the
Commission’s prohibition on tying and
on its bidding requirements for certain
capacity releases.
DATES: Comments are due January 10,
2008.
You may submit comments,
identified by docket number by any of
the following methods:
Agency Web site: https://ferc.gov.
Documents created electronically using
word processing software should be
filed in native applications or print-toPDF format and not in a scanned format.
Mail/Hand Delivery: Commenters
unable to file comments electronically
must mail or hand deliver an original
and 14 copies of their comments to:
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
Secretary of the Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
Instructions: For detailed instructions
on submitting comments and additional
information on the rulemaking process,
see the Comment Procedures section of
this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Robert McLean, Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426,
Robert.McLean@ferc.gov, (202) 502–
8156.
David Maranville, Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426,
ADDRESSES:
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Resolving the interference between the MLG
gear beam and the MLG side strut.
David.Maranville@ferc.gov, (202) 502–
6351.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
Table of Contents
Paragraph
numbers
I. Background ...........................
A. The Capacity Release
Program .............................
B. Petitions and Industry
Comments .........................
II. Removal of Maximum Rate
Ceiling for Short-Term Capacity Release ......................
A. Policies Enhancing Competition ...............................
B. Data on Capacity Release
Transactions ......................
C. Available Pipeline Service
Constrains Market Power
Abuses ...............................
D. Monitoring .........................
E. Requests to Expand Market-Based Rate Authority ..
1. Removal of Price Ceiling
for Long-Term Releases
2. Removal of Price Ceiling
for Pipeline Short-Term
Transactions ..................
III. Asset Management Arrangements ....................................
A. Background ......................
B. Discussion ........................
1. Tying ..............................
2. The Bidding Requirement ...............................
3. Definition of AMAs .........
IV. State Mandated Retail
Choice Programs ..................
V. Shipper Must-Have-Title Requirement ..............................
VI. Regulatory Requirements ...
A. Information Collection
Statement ..........................
B. Environmental Analysis ....
C. Regulatory Flexibility Act ..
D. Comment Procedures ......
E. Document Availability .......
2.
2.
15.
23.
30.
33.
40.
42.
43.
43.
46.
53.
53.
63.
75.
83.
91.
97.
106.
111.
111.
114.
115.
117.
121.
1. In this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, the Commission proposes
to revise its Part 284 regulations
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
concerning the release of firm capacity
by shippers on interstate natural gas
pipelines. First, the Commission
proposes to remove, on a permanent
basis, the rate ceiling on capacity release
transactions of one year or less. Second,
the Commission proposes to modify its
regulations to facilitate the use of asset
management arrangements (AMAs),
under which a capacity holder releases
some or all of its pipeline capacity to an
asset manager who agrees to supply the
gas needs of the capacity holder.
Specifically, the Commission proposes
to exempt capacity releases made as part
of AMAs from the prohibition on tying
and from the bidding requirements of
section 284.8. These proposals are
designed to enhance competition in the
secondary capacity release market and
increase shipper options for how they
obtain gas supplies.
I. Background
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
A. The Capacity Release Program
2. The Commission adopted its
capacity release program as part of the
restructuring of natural gas pipelines
required by Order No. 636.1 In Order
No. 636, the Commission sought to
foster two primary goals. The first goal
was to ensure that all shippers have
meaningful access to the pipeline
transportation grid so that willing
buyers and sellers can meet in a
competitive, national market to transact
the most efficient deals possible. The
second goal was to ensure consumers
have ‘‘access to an adequate supply of
gas at a reasonable price.’’ 2
3. To accomplish these goals, the
Commission sought to maximize the
availability of unbundled firm
transportation service to all participants
in the gas commodity market. The
linchpin of Order No. 636 was the
requirement that pipelines unbundle
their transportation and storage services
from their sales service, so that gas
purchasers could obtain the same high
quality firm transportation service
whether they purchased from the
pipeline or another gas seller. In order
1 Pipeline Service Obligations and Revisions to
Regulations Governing Self-Implementing
Transportation and Regulation of Natural Gas
Pipelines After Partial Wellhead Decontrol, Order
No. 636, 57 FR 13,267 (April 16, 1992), FERC Stats.
and Regs., Regulations Preambles January 1991–
June 1996 ¶ 30,939 (April 8, 1992); order on reh’g,
Order No. 636–A, 57 FR 36,128 (August 12, 1002),
FERC Stats. and Regs., Regulations Preambles
January 1991–June 1996 ¶ 30,950 (August 3, 1992);
order on reh’g, Order No. 636–B, 57 FR 57,911 (Dec.
8, 1992), 61 FERC ¶ 61,272 (1992); notice of denial
of reh’g, 62 FERC ¶ 61,007 (1993); aff’d in part,
vacated and remanded in part, United Dist.
Companies v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105 (D.C. Cir. 1996);
order on remand, Order No. 636–C, 78 FERC ¶
61,186 (1997).
2 Order No. 636 at 30,393 (citations omitted).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
to create a transparent program for the
reallocation of interstate pipeline
capacity to complement the unbundled,
open access environment created by
Order No. 636, the Commission also
adopted a comprehensive capacity
release program to increase the
availability of unbundled firm
transportation capacity by permitting
firm shippers to release their capacity to
others when they were not using it.3
4. The Commission reasoned that the
capacity release program would
promote efficient load management by
the pipeline and its customers and
would, therefore, result in the efficient
use of firm pipeline capacity throughout
the year. It further concluded that,
‘‘because more buyers will be able to
reach more sellers through firm
transportation capacity, capacity
reallocation comports with the goal of
improving nondiscriminatory, open
access transportation to maximize the
benefits of the decontrol of natural gas
at the wellhead and in the field.’’ 4
5. In Order No. 636, the Commission
expressed concerns regarding its ability
to ensure that firm shippers would
reallocate their capacity in a nondiscriminatory manner to those who
placed the highest value on the capacity
up to the maximum rate. The
Commission noted that prior to Order
No. 636, it authorized some pipelines to
permit their shippers to ‘‘broker’’ their
capacity to others. Under such capacity
brokering, firm shippers were permitted
to assign their capacity directly to a
replacement shipper, without any
requirement that the brokering shipper
post the availability of its capacity or
allocate it to the highest bidder.5
However, in Order No. 636, the
Commission found ‘‘there [were] too
many potential assignors of capacity
and too many different programs for the
Commission to oversee capacity
brokering.’’ 6
6. The Commission sought to ensure
that the efficiencies of the secondary
market were not frustrated by unduly
discriminatory access to the market.7
3 In brief, under the Commission’s capacity
release program, a firm shipper (releasing shipper)
sells its capacity by returning its capacity to the
pipeline for reassignment to the buyer (replacement
shipper). The pipeline contracts with, and receives
payment from, the replacement shipper and then
issues a credit to the releasing shipper. The
replacement shipper may pay less than the
pipeline’s maximum tariff rate, but not more. 18
CFR 284.8(e) (2007). The results of all releases are
posted by the pipeline on its Internet Web site and
made available through standardized,
downloadable files.
4 Order No. 636 at 30,418.
5 See Algonquin Gas Transmission Corp., 59
FERC ¶ 61,032 (1992).
6 Order No. 636 at 30,416.
7 Order No. 636–A at 30,554.
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
65917
Therefore, the Commission replaced
capacity brokering with the capacity
release program designed to provide
greater assurance that transfers of
capacity from one shipper to another
were transparent and not unduly
discriminatory. This assurance took the
form of several conditions that the
Commission placed on the transfer of
capacity under its new program.
7. First, the Commission prohibited
private transfers of capacity between
shippers and, instead, required that all
release transactions be conducted
through the pipeline. Therefore, when a
releasing shipper releases its capacity,
the replacement shipper must enter into
a contract directly with the pipeline,
and the pipeline must post information
regarding the contract, including any
special conditions.8 In order to enforce
the prohibition on private transfers of
capacity, the Commission required that
a shipper must have title to any gas that
it ships on the pipeline.9
8. Second, the Commission
determined that the record of the
proceeding that led to Order No. 636 did
not reflect that the market for released
capacity was competitive. The
Commission reasoned that the extent of
competition in the secondary market
may not be sufficient to ensure that the
rates for released capacity will be just
and reasonable. Therefore, the
Commission imposed a ceiling on the
rate that the releasing shipper could
charge for the released capacity.10 This
ceiling was derived from the
Commission’s estimate of the maximum
rates necessary for the pipeline to
8 Order
No. 636 emphasized:
The main difference between capacity brokering
as it now exists and the new capacity release
program is that under capacity brokering, the
brokering customer could enter into and execute its
own deals without involving the pipeline. Under
capacity releasing, all offers must be put on the
pipeline’s electronic bulletin board and contracting
is done directly with the pipeline. Order No. 636
at 30, 420 (emphasis in original).
9 As the Commission subsequently explained in
Order No. 637, ‘‘the capacity release rules were
designed with [the shipper-must-have-title] policy
as their foundation,’’ because, without this
requirement, ‘‘capacity holders could simply
transport gas over the pipeline for another entity.’’
Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services and Regulation of
Interstate Natural Gas Transportation Services,
Order No. 637, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,091 at
31,300, clarified, Order No. 637–A, FERC Stats. &
Regs. ¶ 31,099, reh’g denied, Order No. 637–B, 92
FERC ¶ 61,062 (2000), aff’d in part and remanded
in part sub nom. Interstate Natural Gas Ass’n of
America v. FERC, 285 F.3d 18 (D.C. Cir. 2002),
order on remand, 101 FERC ¶ 61,127 (2002), order
on reh’g, 106 FERC ¶ 61,088 (2004), aff’d sub nom.
American Gas Ass’n v. FERC, 428 F.3d 255 (D.C.
Cir. 2005). See section V below for a further
explanation of the shipper-must-have-title
requirement.
10 Order No. 636 at 30,418; Order No. 636–A at
30,560.
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
65918
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
recover its annual cost-of-service
revenue requirement, which the
Commission prorated over the period of
each release.11
9. Third, the Commission required
that capacity offered for release at less
than the maximum rate must be posted
for bidding, and the pipeline must
allocate the capacity ‘‘to the person
offering the highest rate (not over the
maximum rate).’’ 12 The Commission
permitted the releasing shipper to
choose a pre-arranged replacement
shipper who can retain the capacity by
matching the highest bid rate. The
bidding requirement, however, does not
apply to releases of 31 days or less or
to any release at the maximum rate. But
all releases, whether or not subject to
bidding, must be posted.13
10. Finally, the Commission
prohibited tying the release of capacity
to any extraneous conditions so that the
releasing shippers could not attempt to
add additional terms or conditions to
the release of capacity. The Commission
articulated the prohibition against the
tying of capacity in Order No. 636–A,
where it stated:
The Commission reiterates that all terms
and conditions for capacity release must be
posted and non-discriminatory and must
relate solely to the details of acquiring
transportation on the interstate pipelines.
Release of capacity cannot be tied to any
other conditions. Moreover, the Commission
will not tolerate deals undertaken to avoid
the notice requirements of the regulations.
Order No. 636–A at 30, 559 (emphasis in the
original).
11. Subsequent to the Commission’s
adoption of its capacity release program
in Order No. 636, the Commission
conducted two experimental programs
to provide more flexibility in the
capacity release market. In 1996, the
Commission sought to establish an
experimental program inviting
individual shipper and pipeline
applications to remove price ceilings
related to capacity release.14 The
11 Order
No. 637 at 31,270–71.
CFR §284.8(e) (2007) provides in pertinent
part that ‘‘[t]he pipeline must allocate released
capacity to the person offering the highest rate (not
over the maximum rate) and offering to meet any
other terms or conditions of the release.’’
13 18 CFR § 284.8(h)(1) provides that a release of
capacity for less than 31 days, or for any term at
the maximum rate, need not comply with certain
notification and bidding requirements, but that
such release may not exceed the maximum rate.
Notice of the release ‘‘must be provided on the
pipeline’s electronic bulletin board as soon as
possible, but not later than forty-eight hours, after
the release transaction commences.’’
14 Secondary Market Transactions on Interstate
Natural Gas Pipelines, Proposed Experimental Pilot
Program to Relax the Price Cap for Secondary
Market Transactions, 61 FR 41401 (Aug. 8, 1996),
76 FERC ¶ 61,120, order on reh’g, 77 FERC ¶ 61,183
(1996).
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
12 18
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
Commission recognized that significant
benefits could be realized through
removal of the price ceiling in a
competitive secondary market. Removal
of the ceiling permits more efficient
capacity utilization by permitting prices
to rise to market clearing levels and by
permitting those who place the highest
value on the capacity to obtain it.15
12. In 2000, in Order No. 637, the
Commission conducted a broader
experiment in which the Commission
removed the rate ceiling for short-term
(less than one year) capacity release
transactions for a two-year period
ending September 30, 2002. In contrast
to the experiment that it conducted in
1996, in the Order No. 637 experiment
the Commission granted blanket
authorization in order to permit all firm
shippers on all open access pipelines to
participate. The Commission stated that
it undertook this experiment to improve
shipper options and market efficiency
during peak periods. The Commission
reasoned that during peak periods, the
maximum rate cap on capacity release
transactions inhibits the creation of an
effective transportation market by
preventing capacity from going to those
that value it the most and therefore the
elimination of this rate ceiling would
eliminate this inefficiency and enhance
shipper options in the short-term
marketplace.16
13. Upon an examination of pricing
data on basis differentials between
points,17 the Commission found that the
price ceiling on capacity release
transactions limited the capacity
options of short-term shippers because
firm capacity holders were able to avoid
price ceilings on released capacity by
substituting bundled sales transactions
15 77
FERC ¶ 61,183 (1996) at 61,699.
No. 637 at 31,263. The Commission also
explained why it was lifting the price cap on an
experimental basis, instead of permanently, stating:
While the removal of the price cap is justified
based on the record in this rulemaking, the
Commission recognizes that this is a significant
regulatory change that should be subject to ongoing
review by the Commission and the industry. No
matter how good the data suggesting that a
regulatory change should be made, there is no
substitute for reviewing the actual results of a
regulatory action. The two year waiver will provide
an opportunity for such a review after sufficient
information is obtained to validly assess the results.
Due to the variation between years in winter
temperatures, the waiver will provide the
Commission and the industry with two winter’s
worth of data with which to examine the effects of
this policy change and determine whether changes
or modifications may be needed prior to the
expiration of the waiver. Order No. 637 at 31,279.
17 Among other things, the data showed that the
value of pipeline capacity, as shown by basis
differentials, was generally less than the pipelines’
maximum interruptible transportation rates, except
during the coldest days of the year, and capacity
release prices also averaged somewhat less than
pipelines’ maximum interruptible rates.
16 Order
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
at market prices (where the market place
value of transportation is an implicit
component of the delivered price). As a
consequence, the Commission
determined that the price ceilings did
not limit the prices paid by shippers in
the short-term market as much as the
ceilings limit transportation options for
shippers. In short, the Commission
found that the rate ceiling worked
against the interests of short-term
shippers, because with the rate ceilings
in place, a shipper looking for shortterm capacity on a peak day who was
willing to offer a higher price in order
to obtain it, could not legally do so; this
reduced its options for procuring shortterm transportation at the times that it
needed it most.18 Throughout this
experiment, the Commission retained
the rate ceiling for firm and
interruptible capacity available from the
pipeline as well as long-term capacity
release transactions.
14. On April 5, 2002, the United
States Court of Appeals for the District
of Columbia Circuit, in Interstate
Natural Gas Association of America v.
FERC,19 upheld the Commission’s
experimental price ceiling program for
short-term capacity release transactions
as set forth in Order No. 637.20 The
court found that the Commission’s
‘‘light handed’’ approach to the
regulation of capacity release prices
was, given the safeguards that the
Commission had imposed, consistent
with the criteria set forth in Farmers
Union Cent. Exch. v. FERC.21 The court
found that the Commission made a
substantial record for the proposition
that market rates would not materially
exceed the ‘‘zone of reasonableness’’
required by Farmers Union. The court
also found that the Commission’s
inference of competition in the capacity
release market was well founded, that
the price spikes shown in the
Commission’s data were consistent with
competition and reflected scarcity of
supply rather than monopoly power,
and that outside of such price spikes,
the rates were well below the estimated
regulated price.22
18 Order
No. 637 at 31,282.
F.3d 18 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (INGAA).
20 Specifically, the court found that: ‘‘[g]iven the
substantial showing that in this context competition
has every reasonable prospect of preventing
seriously monopolistic pricing, together with the
non-cost advantages cited by the Commission and
the experimental nature of this particular
‘‘lighthanded’’ regulation, we find the
Commission’s decision neither a violation of the
NGA, nor arbitrary or capricious.’’ INGAA at 35.
21 734 F.2d 1486 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (Farmers Union).
22 Id. at 33.
19 285
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
B. Petitions and Industry Comments
15. In August 2006, Pacific Gas and
Electric Co. (PG&E) and Southwest Gas
Corp. (Southwest) filed a petition
requesting the Commission to amend
sections 284.8(e) and (h)(1) of its
regulations to remove the maximum rate
cap on capacity release transactions.23
They stated that removing the price
ceiling would improve the efficiency of
the capacity market by giving releasing
shippers a greater incentive to release
their capacity during periods of
constraint. They asserted that this
would allow shippers who value the
capacity the most to obtain it, provide
more accurate price signals concerning
the value of capacity, and provide
greater potential cost mitigation to
holders of long-term firm capacity. They
also pointed out that the Commission
now permits pipelines to negotiate rates
with individual customers using basis
differentials (i.e., the difference between
natural gas commodity prices at two
trading points, such as a supply basin
and a city gate delivery point) and such
negotiated rates may exceed the
pipeline’s recourse maximum rate.
PG&E and Southwest assert that
releasing shippers must have greater
pricing flexibility in order to compete
with such negotiated rate deals offered
by the pipelines.
16. In October 2006, a group of large
natural gas marketers 24 (Marketer
Petitioners) requested clarification of
the operation of the Commission’s
capacity release rules in the context of
asset (or portfolio) management
services.25 An AMA is an agreement
under which a capacity holder releases,
on a pre-arranged basis, all or some of
its pipeline capacity, along with
associated gas purchase contracts, to an
asset or portfolio manager. The asset
manager uses the capacity to satisfy the
gas supply needs of the releasing
shipper, and, when the capacity is not
needed to serve the releasing shipper,
the asset manager uses it to make gas
sales or re-releases the capacity to third
parties.
17. The Marketer Petitioners state that
Order No. 636 adopted the capacity
release program as a means for shippers
to transfer unneeded capacity to other
23 Docket No. RM06–21–000. PG&E subsequently
clarified that it only seeks removal of the price cap
for capacity releases of less than a year.
24 Coral Energy Resources, LP; ConocoPhillips
Co.; Chevron USA, Inc.; Constellation Energy
Commodities Group, Inc.; Tenaska Marketing
Ventures; Merrill Lynch Commodities, Inc.; Nexen
Marketing USA, Inc.; and UBS Energy LLC.
25 The Marketer Petitioners originally filed their
petition in Docket Nos. RM91–11–009 and RM98–
10–013. However, the Commission has re-docketed
the petition in Docket No. RM07–4–000.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
entities who desired it. However, the
Marketer Petitioners state, today many
local distribution companies (LDCs) and
others desire to release their capacity to
a replacement shipper (asset manager)
with greater market expertise, who will
continue to use the capacity to provide
gas supplies to the releasing shipper and
will be better able to maximize the value
of the released capacity when it is not
needed to serve the releasing shipper.
The Marketer Petitioners state that the
Commission’s current capacity release
rules may interfere with marketers
providing efficient asset management
services. They also assert that they are
not seeking to remove the capacity
release rate cap, but acknowledge that if
the Commission took such action, it
would eliminate some of their problems.
18. On January 3, 2007, the
Commission issued a request for
comments on the current operation of
the Commission’s capacity release
program and whether changes in any of
its capacity release policies would
improve the efficiency of the natural gas
market.26 The Commission’s request for
comments was in part in response to the
petitions discussed above. In addition to
the issues raised by the petitions, the
Commission also included in its request
for comments a series of questions
asking whether the Commission should
lift the price ceiling, remove its capacity
release bidding requirements, modify its
prohibition on tying arrangements, and/
or remove the shipper-must-have-title
requirement.
19. In response to the price ceiling
issues, commenting LDCs and pipelines
both advocate lifting the ceiling, subject
to different conditions. The LDCs favor
lifting the ceiling only if it would still
apply to the pipeline’s direct sales of
capacity because, among other things,
the pipelines have negotiated rate
authority that is not available to
releasing shippers.27 The pipelines
advocate the removal of the cap only if
the Commission removes the cap from
the entire capacity marketplace;
otherwise, they argue, it will create a
26 Pacific Gas & Electric Co., 118 FERC ¶ 61,005
(2007).
27 Under the negotiated rate program, a pipeline
may charge rates different from those set forth in
its open access tariff, as long as the shipper has
recourse to taking service at the maximum tariff
rate. See, Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ¶
61,076, reh’g denied, 75 FERC ¶ 61,024 (1996),
petitions for review denied sub nom., Burlington
Resources Oil & Gas Co. v. FERC, 172 F.3d 918
(D.C. Cir. 1998). See also Natural Gas Pipelines
Negotiated Rate Policies and Practices;
Modification of Negotiated Rate Policy, 104 FERC
¶ 61,134 (2003), order on reh’g and clarification,
114 FERC ¶ 61,042, dismissing reh’g and denying
clarification, 114 FERC ¶ 61,304 (2006).
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
65919
bifurcated market and an uneven
playing field.
20. Producers and industrial
customers generally oppose lifting the
price ceiling on a permanent basis,
arguing that the Commission must first
develop new data to support such action
and that it cannot rely on the results of
the Order No. 637 experiment that
terminated five years ago. Certain
producers, however, would
countenance a new experiment
conducted by the Commission to gather
new data related to the lifting of the
price ceiling. Additionally, certain
marketers and the American Public Gas
Association (APGA) argue that the
Commission cannot remove the ceiling
unless there is a finding of lack of
market power.
21. In response to the request for
comments on whether the Commission
should consider adjusting the capacity
release regulations to foster AMAs,
numerous commenters responded that
AMAs are beneficial to the market place
and that the Commission should do
something to facilitate their use. A vast
majority of the commenters assert that
AMAs provide substantial benefits,
including more load responsive use of
gas supply, greater liquidity, increased
use of transportation capacity, cost
effective procurement vehicles for LDCs
and other end users, and the
enhancement of competition. They state
that AMAs also relieve LDCs from
management of their daily gas supply
and capacity needs. Others comment
that AMAs benefit all parties involved:
The releasing shipper reduces its costs
through use of its capacity entitlements
to facilitate third party sales; the third
parties benefit from receiving a bundled
product at an acceptable price; and the
asset manager receives whatever profits
are not passed on to the releasing
shipper.
22. In particular, the Marketer
Petitioners and other commenters
request that the Commission clarify that
the different payments made between
parties in an AMA do not constitute
prohibited above maximum rate
transactions or below maximum rate
transactions that thus require posting
and bidding. They also request that the
Commission revisit its prohibition on
tying to allow the packaging of gas
supply contracts and pipeline or storage
capacity, or multiple segments of
capacity, as part of an AMA. Certain
commenters also suggest changes to the
Commission’s notice and bidding
requirements for capacity releases. A
number of LDCs and marketers request
that the bidding requirement be
eliminated altogether or that the
regulations be revised to eliminate
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
65920
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
bidding for capacity releases made to
implement an AMA.
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
II. Removal of Maximum Rate Ceiling
for Short-Term Capacity Release
23. Based upon its review of the
petitions, comments and available data,
the Commission proposes to lift the
price ceiling for short-term capacity
release transactions of one year or less.
The Commission’s capacity release
program has created a successful
secondary market for capacity.28
Commenters from disparate segments of
the natural gas industry agree that the
capacity release program has been
beneficial to the industry in creating a
competitive secondary market for
natural gas transportation.29
24. As the comments point out,
shippers and potential shippers are
looking for greater flexibility in the use
of capacity. They seek to better integrate
capacity with the underlying gas
transactions, and are looking for more
flexible methods of pricing capacity to
better reflect the value of that capacity
as revealed by the market price of gas
at different trading points. Pipelines, for
example, have been using their
negotiated rate authority to sell their
own capacity based on market-derived
basis differentials reflective of the
difference in gas prices between two
points. The Commission recently
clarified that pipelines may use such
basis differential pricing as a part of
negotiated rate transactions even when
those prices exceed maximum tariff
rates.30 Under the Commission’s
regulations, releasing shippers also may
28 As the Commission observed in 2005, the
‘‘capacity release program together with the
Commission’s policies on segmentation, and
flexible point rights, has been successful in creating
a robust secondary market where pipelines must
compete on price.’’ Policy for Selective Discounting
by Natural Gas Pipelines, 111 FERC ¶ 61,309 at P
39–41) (2005), order on reh’g, 113 FERC ¶ 61,173
(2005).
29 See e.g., PG&E and Southwest Gas Petition at
10 (‘‘There is reason to believe that the secondary
market is more competitive today than it was six
years ago.’’); Market Petitioners at 3 (‘‘The
Commission’s capacity release program has proven
to be a critical initiative in opening U.S. natural gas
markets to competition.’’); AGA Comments at 3
(‘‘The Commission’s regulations have permitted the
development of an open and active secondary
market for pipeline capacity that has provided
significant benefits to natural gas consumers.’’);
INGAA Comments at 12 (‘‘The current market for
short-term transportation capacity is large and
highly competitive.’’); and NGSA Comments at 2
(‘‘The basic structure of the Commission’s policies
is still providing the benefits intended of
transparent, nondiscriminatory, efficient allocation
of capacity.’’).
30 Natural Gas Pipelines Negotiated Rate Policies
and Practices; Modification of Negotiated Rate
Policy, 104 FERC ¶ 61,134 (2003), order on reh’g
and clarification, 114 FERC ¶ 61,042, dismissing
reh’g and denying clarification, 114 FERC ¶ 61,304
(2006).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
enter into capacity release transactions
based on basis differentials, but such
releases cannot exceed the maximum
rate.31 In their comments, releasing
shippers request the ability to release at
above the maximum rate so that they
may offer potential buyers rates
competitive with pipeline negotiated
rate transactions.32
25. As the Commission recognized in
Order No. 637,33 the traditional cost-ofservice price ceilings in pipeline tariffs,
which are based on average yearly rates,
are not well suited to the short-term
capacity release market.34 Removal of
the price ceiling will enable releasing
shippers to offer competitively-priced
alternatives to the pipelines’ negotiated
rate offerings. Removal of the ceiling
also permits more efficient utilization of
capacity by permitting prices to rise to
market clearing levels, thereby
permitting those who place the highest
value on the capacity to obtain it.
Removal of the price ceiling also will
provide potential customers with
additional opportunities to acquire
capacity. The price ceiling reduces the
firm capacity holders’ incentive to
release capacity during times of scarcity,
because they cannot obtain the market
value of the capacity.
26. Further, the elimination of the
price ceiling for short-term capacity
releases will provide more accurate
price signals concerning the market
value of pipeline capacity. More
accurate price signals will promote the
efficient construction of new capacity
by highlighting the location, frequency,
and severity of transportation
constraints. Correct capacity pricing
information will also provide
transparent market values that will
better enable pipelines and their lenders
to calculate the potential profitability
and associated risk of additional
construction designed to alleviate
transportation constraints.
27. Moreover, removing the price
ceiling on short-term capacity releases
should not harm, and may benefit, the
‘‘primary intended beneficiaries of the
NGA—the ‘captive’ shippers.’’ 35 Those
shippers typically have long-term firm
contracts with the pipeline, and
31 See
Standards for Business Practices for
Interstate Natural Gas Pipelines and for Public
Utilities, Order No. 698, 72 FR 38757 (July 16,
2007), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,251 (June 25, 2007).
32 See, e.g., PG&E and Southwest Gas Petition at
10–11.
33 Order No. 637 at 31,271–75.
34 While the Commission offered pipelines the
opportunity to propose other types of rate designs,
such as seasonal and term-differentiated rates, only
a very few pipelines have sought to make such rate
design changes, although virtually all pipelines
have taken advantage of negotiated rate authority.
35 INGAA at 33.
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
therefore will ‘‘continue to receive
whatever benefits the rate ceilings
generally provide,’’ while also ‘‘reaping
the benefits of [the] new rule, in the
form of higher payments for their
releases of surplus capacity.’’ 36
28. As the court stated in INGAA, the
Commission may depart from cost of
service ratemaking upon:
A showing that * * * the goals and
purposes of the statute will be accomplished
‘through the proposed changes.’ To satisfy
that standard, we demanded that the
resulting rates be expected to fall within a
‘zone of reasonableness, where [they] are
neither less than compensatory nor
excessive.’ [citation omitted]. While the
expected rates’ proximity to cost was a
starting point for this inquiry into
reasonableness, [citation omitted], we were
quite explicit that ‘non-cost factors may
legitimate a departure from a rigid cost-based
approach,’ [citation omitted]. Finally, we said
that FERC must retain some general oversight
over the system, to see if competition in fact
drives rates into the zone of reasonableness
‘or to check rates if it does not.’ 37
29. Many of the changes effected in
Order Nos. 636 and 637 have enhanced
competition between releasing shippers
as well as between releasing shippers
and the pipeline. As discussed below,
the data obtained by the Commission
both during the Order No. 637
experiment and more recently confirms
the finding made in Order No. 637 that
short-term release prices are reflective of
market prices as revealed by basis
differentials, rather than reflecting the
exercise of market power. Moreover,
shippers purchasing capacity will be
adequately protected because the
pipeline’s firm and interruptible
services will provide just and
reasonable recourse rates limiting the
ability of releasing shippers to exercise
market power. Finally, the reporting
requirements in Order No. 637 and the
Commission’s implementation of the
Energy Policy Act of 2005, specifically
with respect to market manipulation,
provide the Commission with enhanced
ability to monitor the market and detect
and deter abuses.
A. Policies Enhancing Competition
30. In Order No. 636 and, as expanded
in Order No. 637, the Commission
instituted a number of policy revisions
designed to enhance competition and
improve efficiency across the pipeline
grid. These revisions provide shippers
with enhanced market mechanisms that
will help ensure a more competitive
market and mitigate the potential for the
exercise of market power.
36 Id.
37 Id.
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
at 31.
26NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
31. The Commission required
pipelines to permit releasing shippers to
use flexible point rights and to fully
segment their pipeline capacity.
Flexible point rights enable shippers to
use any points within their capacity
path on a secondary basis, which
enables shippers to compete effectively
on release transactions with other
shippers. Segmentation further
enhances the ability to compete because
it enables the releasing shipper to retain
the portion of the pipeline capacity it
needs while releasing the unneeded
portion. Effective segmentation will
make more capacity available and
enhance competition. As the
Commission explained in Order No.
637:
The combination of flexible point rights
and segmentation increases the alternatives
available to shippers looking for capacity. In
the example,38 a shipper in Atlanta looking
for capacity has multiple choices. It can
purchase available capacity from the
pipeline. It can obtain capacity from a
shipper with firm delivery rights at Atlanta
or from any shipper with delivery point
rights downstream of Atlanta. The ability to
segment capacity enhances options further.
The shipper in New York does not have to
forgo deliveries of gas to New York in order
to release capacity to the shipper seeking to
deliver gas in Atlanta. The New York shipper
can both sell capacity to the shipper in
Atlanta and retain the right to inject gas
downstream of Atlanta to serve its New York
market.39
32. In addition to enhancing competition
through expansion of flexible point rights
and segmentation, the Commission in Order
No. 637 also required pipelines to provide
shippers with scheduling equal to that
provided by the pipeline, so that replacement
shippers can submit a nomination at the first
available opportunity after consummation of
the capacity release transaction. The change
makes capacity release more competitive
with pipeline services and increases
competition between capacity releasers by
enabling replacement shippers to schedule
the use of capacity obtained through release
transactions quickly rather than having to
wait until the next day.
65921
B. Data on Capacity Release
Transactions
33. The data accumulated by the
Commission during the Order No. 637
experiment, as well as review of more
recent data, show that capacity release
prices reflect competitive conditions in
the industry. On May 30, 2002, the
Commission issued a notice of staff
paper presenting data on capacity
release transactions during the
experimental period when the capacity
release ceiling price was waived.40 The
staff paper provided analysis of capacity
release transactions on 34 pipelines
during the 22-month period from March
2000 to December 2001.41
34. In brief, the data gathered during
the 33-month period show that without
the price ceiling, prices exceeded the
maximum rate only during short time
periods and appear to be reflective of
competitive conditions in the industry.
The following table shows the
distribution of above ceiling price
releases among the pipelines studied.
TABLE I.—ABOVE CAP RELEASES BY PIPELINE
[Releases awarded between March 26, 2000 and December 31, 2001]
Releases
above max
rate
(Number of
transactions)
Pipeline
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
Algonquin .........................................................................................................
ANR Pipeline ...................................................................................................
CIG ...................................................................................................................
Dominion (CNGT) ............................................................................................
Columbia Gas ..................................................................................................
Columbia Gulf ..................................................................................................
East Tennessee ...............................................................................................
El Paso ............................................................................................................
Florida Gas ......................................................................................................
Great Lakes .....................................................................................................
Iroquois ............................................................................................................
Kern River ........................................................................................................
KMI (KNEnergy) ...............................................................................................
Gulf South (Koch) ............................................................................................
Midwestern .......................................................................................................
Mississippi River ..............................................................................................
Mojave Pipeline Co ..........................................................................................
Natural Gas Pipeline Co ..................................................................................
Reliant (Noram) ...............................................................................................
Northern Border ...............................................................................................
Northern Natural ..............................................................................................
Northwest Pipeline ...........................................................................................
Paiute Pipeline .................................................................................................
Panhandle Eastern ..........................................................................................
Southern Natural ..............................................................................................
Tennessee Gas ...............................................................................................
TETCO .............................................................................................................
38 In the example used in Order No. 636, a
shipper holding firm capacity from a primary
receipt point in the Gulf of Mexico to primary
delivery points in New York could release that
capacity to a replacement shipper moving gas from
the Gulf to Atlanta while the New York releasing
shipper could inject gas downstream of Atlanta and
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
Frm 00033
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Releases
quantity above
max rate
(MMBtu/day)
% of total
release quantity
1
1
19
21
101
0.1
0.1
6.5
1.0
4.4
18,453
30,000
109,984
65,789
374,727
0.2
0.2
4.4
0.7
2.7
135
25
3
13.3
1.7
1.3
631,683
43,526
15,000
12.5
1.4
0.6
2
3
3.9
1.0
55,000
1,409
2.5
0.0
1
0.6
50,000
2.3
1
16
2.6
3.2
40,000
270,489
4.7
2.3
12
24
1.6
1.8
23,273
139,850
0.5
4.1
1
7
11
122
0.4
0.3
0.4
3.8
1,000
24,101
36,421
645,856
0.1
0.2
0.2
3.3
use the remainder of the capacity to deliver the gas
to New York.
39 Order No. 637 at 31,300.
40 On May 30, 2002, a Staff Paper was posted on
the Commission’s Web site presenting, and
analyzing data on capacity release transactions
relating to the experimental period when the rate
ceiling on short-term released capacity was waived.
PO 00000
% of total
releases
41 Many of these release transactions would have
occurred prior to completion of the pipeline’s Order
No. 637 compliance proceedings and the
implementation of the changes to flexible point
rights, segmentation and scheduling described
above.
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
65922
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
TABLE I.—ABOVE CAP RELEASES BY PIPELINE—Continued
[Releases awarded between March 26, 2000 and December 31, 2001]
Releases
above max
rate
(Number of
transactions)
Pipeline
% of total
releases
Releases
quantity above
max rate
(MMBtu/day)
% of total
release quantity
Texas Gas .......................................................................................................
Trailblazer ........................................................................................................
Transco ............................................................................................................
Transwestern ...................................................................................................
Trunkline ..........................................................................................................
Williams ............................................................................................................
Williston Basin .................................................................................................
6
3
183
11
0.5
25.0
3.3
4.5
103,237
15,000
1,540,885
64,058
1.0
10.0
4.1
6.5
4
0.4
16,500
0.3
Total ..........................................................................................................
713
2.2
4,316,241
2.1
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
42 INGAA
at 32.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
36. Several commenters argue that the
data gathered by the Commission is too
stale to support the instant proposal to
remove the price ceiling on short-term
capacity releases. However, these
commenters fail to produce any
evidence to support specific concerns
existing today that did not exist during
the experimental period. Moreover, the
Commission has gathered additional
current data and has replicated the
evidence presented in Order No. 637.
The current data shows that the
conditions that existed at the time of
Order No. 637 and during the past
experimental period continue in today’s
marketplace.
37. Figure 1 illustrates the
fluctuations in the market value of
transportation service, as shown by the
basis differentials between Louisiana
and New York City. This graph
compares the daily difference in gas
prices between Louisiana and New York
City to Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line
Corporation’s maximum interruptible
transportation rate, including fuel
retainage, during the 12 months ending
July 31, 2007. This graph shows that for
most of the year, the value of
transportation service, as indicated by
the basis differentials, is less than the
maximum transportation rate. However,
during brief, peak demand periods, the
value of transportation service is
measurably greater than the maximum
transportation rate. For example, on
February 5, 2007, the basis differential
between Louisiana and New York City
was in excess of $27.00 per MMBtu,
while the maximum tariff rate plus the
cost of fuel was approximately $1.08 per
MMBtu.43
43 In Order No. 637, the Commission presented
similar data in figure 6 showing the implicit
35. These data show that during
periods without capacity constraints,
prices remained at or below the
maximum rate. The staff paper does
identify 713 releases above the ceiling
price, representing an average total
capacity release contract volume of 4.3
billion cubic feet (Bcf) per day.
However, the staff paper reflects that
these above-ceiling price releases
represented only a small portion of the
total releases on these pipelines,
comprising approximately two percent
of total transactions on the pipelines
studied for the entire period, and two
percent of gas volumes. Further, above
ceiling releases accounted for no more
than six or seven percent of transactions
during any given month of the period.
As one would expect, the percentages of
releases occurring above the ceiling
increased during peak periods.
However, average release rates were
higher by only one cent per MMBtu per
day or five and one-half percent higher
than they would have been with the
price ceiling in place. Of the 34
pipelines in the study, 10 reported no
releases above the ceiling price, and 20
pipelines reported fewer than 25 above-
transportation value between South Louisiana and
Chicago. Order No. 637 at 31,274.
ceiling price releases. The data gathered
during this 22-month period reflects the
Commission’s expectations and affirms
the Commission’s findings in the Order
No. 637 proceeding. As the court stated
in INGAA:
The data represented in the graph [] do
support the Commission’s view that the
capacity release market enjoys considerable
competition. The brief spikes in moments of
extreme exigency are completely consistent
with competition, reflecting scarcity rather
than monopoly. * * * [citation omitted] A
surge in the price of candles during a power
outage is no evidence of monopoly in the
candle market.42
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
Basin and the California border,
respectively, these figures show that for
most of the year, the value of
transportation service is less than the
maximum transportation rate of Natural
Gas Pipeline Company of America and
El Paso Natural Gas Company,
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
respectively. However, similar to figure
1, these figures also reflect that during
brief, peak-demand periods, the value of
transportation service is measurably
greater than the maximum
transportation rate.
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
EP26NO07.004
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
38. Figures 2 and 3 below reflect that
a similar pattern of transportation value
is evident in other areas of the country.
Focusing on fluctuations in the market
value of transportation service as shown
by basis differentials between Louisiana
and Chicago and between the Permian
65923
VerDate Aug<31>2005
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4725
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
EP26NO07.005 EP26NO07.006
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
65924
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
39. The data in all three of the above
figures reflect similar market conditions
to the data that the Commission relied
upon in lifting the price ceiling for
short-term capacity releases in Order
No. 637, with the market value of
capacity generally below the pipeline’s
maximum rate except for relatively brief
price spikes.44 In affirming the
Commission’s actions, the court in
INGAA found that the data presented by
the Commission constituted a
substantial basis for the conclusion that
a considerable amount of competition
existed in the capacity release market.
Further, the INGAA court concluded
that the price spikes reflected in the
data were consistent with competition
and that such spikes reflected scarcity
rather than monopoly. 45
C. Available Pipeline Service Constrains
Market Power Abuses
40. The Commission envisions that
under the instant proposal the
pipeline’s open access transportation
maximum tariff rates (recourse rates)
will serve as additional protection
against possible abuses of market power
by releasing shippers. The Commission
requires pipelines to sell all their
available capacity to shippers willing to
pay the pipeline’s maximum recourse
rate.46 Under their negotiated rate
authority, pipelines are free to negotiate
individualized rates with particular
shippers that may be above the
maximum tariff rate, subject to several
conditions including the availability of
the maximum tariff rate as a recourse
rate for potential firm shippers.47 As the
Commission explained in its negotiated
rate policy statement, ‘‘[t]he availability
of a recourse service would prevent
pipelines from exercising market power
by assuring that the customer can fall
back to traditional cost-based service if
the pipeline unilaterally demands
excessive prices or withholds
service.’’ 48
44 Order
No. 637 at 31,273–75.
at 32.
46 Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 91 FERC ¶ 61,053
(2002), reh’g denied, 94 FERC ¶ 61,097 (2001),
petitions for review denied sub nom., Process Gas
Consumers Group v. FERC, 292 F.3d 831, 837 (D.C.
Cir. 2002).
47 See, Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC
¶ 61,076, reh’g denied, 75 FERC ¶ 61,024 (1996),
petitions for review denied sub nom., Burlington
Resources Oil & Gas Co. v. FERC, 172 F.3d 918
(D.C. Cir. 1998). See also Natural Gas Pipelines
Negotiated Rate Policies and Practices;
Modification of Negotiated Rate Policy, 104 FERC
¶ 61,134 (2003), order on reh’g and clarification,
114 FERC ¶ 61,042, dismissing reh’g and denying
clarification, 114 FERC ¶ 61,304 (2006).
48 Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC
¶ 61,076 at 61,240 (1996).
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
45 INGAA
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
41. The court in INGAA recognized
the value of the pipeline’s recourse rate
protecting against possible abuses of
market power by releasing shippers
stating that,
[i]f holders of firm capacity do not use or
sell all of their entitlement, the pipelines are
required to sell the idle capacity as
interruptible service to any taker at no more
than the maximum rate—which is still
applicable to the pipelines.49
Removing the price ceiling for shortterm capacity release transactions will
enable releasing shippers to offer
negotiated rate transactions similar to
those offered by the pipelines.
Moreover, the same pipeline open
access service will protect against the
possibility that a releasing shipper will
attempt to exercise market power by
withholding capacity. For example,
should a releasing shipper attempt to
charge a price above competitive levels,
the potential purchaser could seek to
negotiate a more acceptable rate with
the pipeline. Even when the pipeline’s
firm service is not available, a cost
based interruptible rate is always
available as an alternative when a
releasing shipper attempts to withhold
capacity.
D. Monitoring
42. Order No. 637 improved the
Commission’s and the industry’s ability
to monitor capacity release transactions
by requiring daily posting of these
transactions on pipeline Web sites.50
This has increased the information
available to buyers while at the same
time making it easier for the
Commission to identify situations in
which shippers are abusing their market
power.51 Further, the Commission will
entertain complaints and respond to
specific allegations of market power on
a case-by-case basis if necessary.
Furthermore, the Commission will
direct staff to monitor the capacity
release program and, using all available
information, issue a report on the
general performance of the capacity
release program, within six months after
two years of experience under the new
rules.
E. Requests to Expand Market-Based
Rate Authority
1. Removal of Price Ceiling for LongTerm Releases
43. Several commenters request that
the Commission remove the price
ceiling on long-term capacity releases in
addition to eliminating the price ceiling
49 INGAA
at 32.
CFR 284.8 (2007).
51 Order No. 637 at 31,283; Order No. 637–A at
31,558.
50 18
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
65925
on short-term capacity releases. The
Commission declines to make such an
adjustment to its policies at this time for
several reasons. As discussed above, by
lifting the price ceiling for short-term
capacity releases, the Commission seeks
to provide releasing shippers the
flexibility to price their capacity in a
manner consistent with the short-term
price variations in transportation
capacity market values. This action will
ameliorate restrictions on the efficient
allocation of capacity during the shortterm periods when demand drives the
value of transportation capacity above
the current maximum rate.
44. Limiting the removal of the release
ceiling to short-term transactions will
also serve as additional protection for
potential replacement shippers. Such a
limit will ensure that a replacement
shipper cannot be locked into a
transaction that is not protected by the
maximum rate ceiling for more than one
year. The expiration of such a shortterm transaction would give the
replacement shipper an opportunity to
explore other options for satisfying its
capacity needs. The replacement
shipper could seek to negotiate a
different price with its current releasing
shipper or to obtain capacity from
another releasing shipper or directly
from the pipeline.52 Any transaction in
which the parties want to continue the
release past one year would have to be
re-posted for bidding to ensure that the
capacity is allocated to the highest
valued use. This bidding process could
provide an opportunity for redetermining the current market value of
the capacity.
45. Finally, because any such release
of a year or less would have to be reposted for bidding upon its expiration,
the second release would be a new
release separate from the first release,
and thus such a second release of a year
or less would also not be subject to the
price ceiling. The Commission,
however, requests comment on whether
there should be any limit on the ability
of releasing shippers to make multiple,
consecutive short-term releases not
subject to the price ceiling.
2. Removal of Price Ceiling for Pipeline
Short-Term Transactions
46. Pipelines request that the
Commission remove the price ceiling for
primary pipeline capacity whether firm
52 Releasing and replacement shippers cannot
simply roll over a short-term release transaction in
order to extend the release beyond one year. The
Commission’s current regulations do not permit
rollovers or extensions of capacity releases made at
less than maximum rate or for less than 31 days
without re-posting and bidding of that capacity. 18
CFR Section 284.8(h) (2007).
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
65926
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
or interruptible. In sum, they argue that
because the transportation of gas on
pipelines has become sufficiently
competitive, and because released
capacity competes directly with primary
short-term firm, interruptible
transportation and storage services
provided by interstate pipelines, the
Commission should lift the rate ceiling
on the entire short-term capacity
market, not just on capacity releases.
Further, they assert that because shortterm firm and interruptible services
compete directly with capacity release,
the same market liquidity
considerations that warrant lifting the
ceiling on short-term releases support
lifting the price ceiling in the primary
market. The pipelines assert that the
Commission should treat all holders of
capacity equally, whether they are
pipelines or releasing shippers.
47. The pipelines also assert that
removing the price ceiling only on
short-term capacity releases would
bifurcate the single marketplace for
natural gas transportation services. They
argue that if prices for some of the
capacity in the marketplace remain
subject to a price ceiling while the price
ceiling is removed for other forms of
capacity, then once the capped capacity
has been fully utilized, prices for the
uncapped capacity will be higher than
they would have been without any price
ceiling at all. They assert that in
affirming the Commission’s experiment
in removing the price ceiling for shortterm capacity releases, the court in
INGAA recognized this economic cost
and labeled it as a ‘‘cost of
gradualism.’’ 53
48. The Commission is not proposing
to remove the price ceiling for primary
pipeline capacity. Pipelines already
have significant ability to use market
based pricing. Unlike capacity release
transactions, pipelines, as discussed
above, currently can enter into
negotiated rate transactions above the
maximum rate. Pipelines also may seek
market based rates by making a filing
with the Commission establishing that
they lack market power in the markets
they serve.54 In addition, pipelines have
the ability to propose seasonal rates for
their systems, and therefore, recover
more of their annual revenue
requirement in peak seasons.55
49. Moreover, the Commission is
concerned about removing rate ceilings
for all pipeline transactions without the
showings required above in order to
53 INGAA
at 36.
to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines and
Regulation of Negotiated Transportation Services of
Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ¶ 61,076 (1996).
55 See Order No. 637 at 31,574–31, 581.
54 Alternatives
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
protect against the possible exercise of
market power. First, as discussed above,
the price ceilings on pipeline capacity
serve as an effective recourse rate for
both pipeline negotiated rate
transactions and capacity release
transactions to prevent pipelines and
releasing shippers from withholding
capacity.56 Second, pipeline capacity is
not identical to release capacity,
because ownership of the pipeline
capacity is likely to be more
concentrated than capacity held by
shippers for release.57 Third, the
Commission has found that it needs to
regulate primary pipeline capacity to
ensure that pipelines do not withhold
capacity in the long-term by not
constructing additional facilities.
Because pipelines are in the best
position to expand their own systems,
cost-of-service rate ceilings help to
ensure that pipelines have appropriate
incentives to construct new facilities
when needed. As the Commission
found, ‘‘the only way a pipeline [can]
create scarcity to force shippers to
accept longer term contracts would be to
refuse to build additional capacity when
demand requires it.’’ 58 As long as costof-service rate ceilings apply, however,
‘‘pipelines [will] have a greater
incentive to build new capacity to serve
all the demand for their service, than to
withhold capacity, since the only way
the pipeline could increase current
revenues and profits would be to invest
in additional facilities to serve the
increased demand.’’ 59 Similarly, as long
as pipeline short-term services are
subject to a cost of service rate, the
pipelines will not limit their
construction of new capacity to meet
demand in order to create scarcity that
increases short-term prices. Indeed,
56 In Order No. 890, the Commission retained
price ceilings on transportation capacity for
transmission owners to provide similar recourse
rate protection. Preventing Undue Discrimination
and Preference in Transmission Service, Order No.
890, 72 FR 12,266 (March 15, 2007), 12366, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,241 at P 808–09 (2007).
57 As the INGAA court stated:
In fact the Commission’s distinction is not
unreasonable. Despite the absence of HerfindahlHirschman indices for non pipeline capacity
holders, there seems every reason to suppose that
their ownership of such capacity (in any given
market) is not so concentrated as that of the
pipelines themselves—the concentration that
prompted Congress to impose rate regulation in the
first place.
INGAA at 23–24, citing, FPC v. Texaco, 417 U.S.
380, 398 n.8 (1974).
58 Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services, 101 FERC ¶ 61,127, at P
12 (2002), aff’d, American Gas Ass’n v. FERC, 428
F.3d 255 (D.C. Cir. 2005). See also Tennessee Gas
Pipeline Co., 91 FERC ¶ 61,053 (2000), reh’g denied,
94 FERC ¶ 61,097 (2001), aff’d, 292 F.3d 831 (D.C.
Cir. 2002).
59 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
releases at above the maximum rate will
indicate that pipeline capacity is
constrained and demonstrate that
constructing additional capacity could
be profitable.
50. The pipelines also maintain that
not removing the price ceiling for their
capacity that competes with released
capacity will bifurcate the market,
resulting in possibly higher prices for
the uncapped release market. They
argue that where a portion of the supply
of a good or service is subject to price
controls, and demand exceeds (the
price-controlled) supply at the fixed
price, the market-clearing price in the
uncontrolled segment will normally be
higher than if no price controls were
imposed on any of the supply.
Purchasers placing a lower value on the
good may nevertheless be able to
purchase the price-controlled supply,
thereby ‘‘using up’’ some of the
aggregate supply that would otherwise
be available to purchasers placing a
higher value on the good. This alters the
demand-supply ratio in the
uncontrolled market, leading to a higher
market clearing price in that market.
51. Because of the nature of the
pipeline short-term capacity, we do not
think that retaining the cost of service
recourse rates for that capacity will
create such pricing distortions. The
premise of the pipelines’ argument is
that continued price controls on the
pipeline’s sales of short-term capacity
will enable shippers placing a lower
value on the capacity to ‘‘use up’’ some
of the supply, thereby reducing the
amount of capacity available for
purchase by shippers placing a higher
value on the capacity. This premise is
incorrect. Short-term pipeline capacity
is sold as interruptible transportation;
therefore, firm capacity held by shippers
will have scheduling priority over the
pipeline’s interruptible capacity. In
essence, pipeline interruptible service is
derived from existing shippers’ decision
not to use or release their firm capacity
or from unsold pipeline capacity. Thus,
even if a shipper placing a relatively
low value on the capacity has a higher
position on the pipeline’s queue for
price-controlled interruptible
transportation, it is not guaranteed that
it can acquire (or ‘‘use up’’) that
capacity, leading to the supposed higher
market clearing price. A firm shipper
could always release its unused firm
capacity to a replacement shipper who
places a higher value on that capacity,
thereby displacing the lower-value
interruptible shipper.60
60 For example, assume the maximum rate is
$1.00 and there are several shippers. One shipper
is willing to pay up to $1.00 for capacity, while the
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
52. Moreover, even in the context of
firm short-term pipeline capacity, the
scenario posited by the pipelines would
not result in higher market clearing
prices as long as arbitrage exists. Any
shipper with a higher queue position
that acquires the pipeline capacity at the
lower capped rate would have an
incentive to resell that capacity to
another shipper who places a higher
value on the capacity, thus ensuring that
the market clearing price will reflect all
relevant demand.61
III. Asset Management Arrangements
A. Background
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
53. In general, AMAs are contractual
relationships where a party agrees to
manage gas supply and delivery
arrangements, including transportation
and storage capacity, for another party.
Typically a shipper holding firm
transportation and/or storage capacity
on a pipeline or multiple pipelines
temporarily releases all or a portion of
that capacity along with associated gas
production and gas purchase
agreements to an asset manager
(commonly a marketer). The asset
manager uses that capacity to serve the
gas supply requirements of the releasing
shipper, and, when the capacity is not
needed for that purpose, uses the
capacity to make releases or bundled
sales to third parties.
54. While AMAs may be fashioned in
a myriad of ways, there are several
common components of these
arrangements. First, the releasing
shipper generally enters into a prearranged capacity release to an asset
manager ostensibly at the maximum rate
in order to avoid the bidding
requirement. Second, the releasing
shipper makes payments to the asset
manager for the gas supply service
performed by the asset manager for the
releasing shipper. These payments may
include the releasing shipper paying the
other shippers are willing to pay much higher rates.
Even if the shipper placing the lowest value on the
capacity was the highest on the pipeline’s
interruptible queue, it would not be able to acquire
capacity at the $1.00 rate, because the other
shippers could acquire released capacity by bidding
above the maximum rate, thereby preventing the
allocation of any interruptible service.
61 The pipelines rely on an example in Order No.
637–B that was cited by the court in INGAA for the
proposition that capping one part of the market will
result in overall higher prices. But that example was
in a very different context, a situation in which a
releasing shipper in a retail access state provided
released capacity at a preferential rate to one set of
marketers that were obligated to serve retail load,
while selling at an uncapped rate to other
marketers. In the first place, this situation did not
involve interruptible capacity. Moreover, unlike the
case with pipeline capacity, the favored marketer
could not arbitrage its lower price because it was
committed to serving retail load.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
asset manager: (1) The full cost of the
released capacity (e.g., maximum rate)
on the theory that the asset manager is
using the released capacity to transport
the releasing shipper’s gas supplies, (2)
a management fee for transportationrelated tasks (e.g. nominations,
scheduling, storage injections, etc.)
associated with the asset manager’s
obligation to provide gas supplies to the
releasing shipper, and (3) the asset
manager’s cost of purchasing gas
supplies for the releasing shipper.
Third, the asset manager generally
shares with the releasing shipper the
value it is able to obtain from the
releasing shipper’s capacity and supply
contracts when those assets are not
needed to supply the releasing shipper’s
gas needs. The asset manager obtains
such value either by re-releasing the
capacity or by using it to make bundled
sales to third parties. The asset manager
may share that value by: (1) Paying a
fixed ‘‘optimization’’ fee to the releasing
shipper, (2) sharing profits pursuant to
an agreed-upon formula, or (3) making
its gas sales to the releasing shipper at
a lower price.
55. In many instances the asset
manager is chosen through a request for
proposal (RFP) process. The RFP
describes the details and terms and
conditions of the proposed deal and
seeks bids from service providers
willing to provide the requested
services. The methodology for choosing
a winning bidder under an RFP often
reflects many different factors,
including price, creditworthiness,
experience, reliability, and flexibility,
and it is clear that price is not always
the determining factor. Some RFP
procedures are state mandated, and
thus, in those situations, the LDC must
get approval from the state for the final
agreement.
56. There are several ways in which
the AMAs described above implicate the
Commission’s current regulations. The
first relates to the Commission’s
prohibition against the ‘‘tying’’ of
release capacity to any condition. As
discussed above, the Commission
instituted the prohibition against the
tying of capacity in response to
concerns that releasing shippers would
attempt to add terms and conditions
that would ‘‘tie the release of capacity
to other compensation paid to the
releasing shipper.’’ 62 A critical
component of many AMAs is that the
releasing shipper wants to be able to
require the replacement shipper (asset
manager) to satisfy the supply needs of
the releasing shipper and take
assignment of the releasing shipper’s gas
62 Order
PO 00000
supply agreements as a condition of
obtaining the released capacity.
57. AMAs also have implications for
the rate cap and bidding regulations. As
noted, in an AMA, the releasing shipper
typically enters into a prearranged deal
to release all of its pipeline capacity at
the maximum rate to the marketer. It is
reasonable to surmise that the main
reason for the maximum release rate is
so the release will qualify for the
exemption from bidding of all
maximum rate prearranged capacity
releases.63 By avoiding the requirement
to post the release for bidding, the
releasing shipper can ensure that the
capacity will go to the asset manager
whom the releasing shipper has
determined will provide the most
effective asset management services.
58. As described above, however, the
releasing shipper may agree to rebate
some or all of the demand charge to the
marketer so that the marketer’s actual
cost of obtaining the capacity is
something less than the maximum
rate.64 The Commission has held that
such rebates render the release to be at
less than the maximum rate, thereby
requiring that the prearranged release be
posted for bidding.65
63 18 CFR 284.8 (c)–(e). The Commission stated in
Order No. 636–A that releasing shippers may
include in their offers to release capacity reasonable
and non-discriminatory terms and conditions to
accommodate individual release situations,
including provisions for evaluating bids. All such
terms and conditions applicable to the release must
be posted on the pipeline’s electronic bulletin board
and must be objectively stated, applicable to all
potential bidders, and non-discriminatory. For
example, the terms and conditions could not favor
one set of buyers, such as end users of an LDC, or
grant price preferences or credits to certain buyers.
The pipeline’s tariff also must require that all terms
and conditions included in offers to release
capacity be objectively stated, applicable to all
potential bidders, and non-discriminatory. Order
No. 636–A at 30,557.
64 Typically, the releasing shipper first releases its
upstream assets, including pipeline capacity,
storage, and gas supply, to the asset manager at cost.
During the remaining term of the deal the releasing
shipper purchases delivered gas at the agreed upon
rate, which is usually the transportation and storage
costs plus the market price of gas, plus fees and less
whatever sharing of efficiency gains the asset
manager is able to achieve. Sometimes fees and
shared efficiency gains are reflected in some agreed
upon reduction in the price of delivered gas. (The
details are subject to negotiation and vary
tremendously.) Because the mechanics of capacity
releases often require the releasing shipper to
release pipeline capacity at the maximum rate,
rather than a discounted rate that the releasing
shipper may actually pay to the pipeline, some
other consideration must be worked into the
transaction to balance the difference between the
discounted rate and the maximum rate at which the
release is set.
65 In Louis Dreyfus Energy Services, L.P., 114
FERC ¶ 61,246 (2006), the Commission stated that:
[t]he Commission has held that any consideration
paid by the releasing shipper to a prearranged
replacement shipper must be taken into account in
No. 636–A at 30,559.
Frm 00039
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
65927
Continued
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
65928
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
59. Moreover, as described above,
some AMAs may require the asset
manager (replacement shipper) to pay
fees to the releasing shipper. The
Commission has ruled that if the
prearranged release is at the maximum
rate, such additional payments violate
the maximum rate ceiling on capacity
releases.66
60. Many commenters consider the
applications of the Commission’s
policies and regulations described above
as obstacles to fashioning AMAs. They
request clarification of, or revisions to,
the current policies and regulations to
allow releasing shippers to release a
package of transportation or storage
capacity and gas supply contracts to a
willing party who will sell the gas to the
releasing shipper and take assignment of
the gas purchase contracts without
running afoul of the prohibition against
tying. Some commenters also request
that the Commission clarify that
packaging gas supply and pipeline
capacity, or multiple segments of
capacity, as part of an asset management
arrangement, would not violate the
Commission’s prohibition against tying.
Others suggest that the tying prohibition
should be eliminated altogether or that
bundling of pipeline capacity and gas
commodity should be allowed as long as
there is a legitimate business purpose.
61. A large number of commenters
advocate elimination of the bidding
requirement discussed above,
particularly in the AMA context. These
parties argue that there is no need for
posting and bidding of capacity release
transactions and state that it is unduly
burdensome, makes it difficult to
respond quickly to market opportunities
to release, and no longer makes sense in
terms of the arrangements being made in
today’s AMAs. Others contend that the
bidding requirement is redundant in
instances where states require that asset
managers be selected in an RFP process,
which results in a chosen asset manager
and one or more pre-arranged capacity
determining whether the prearranged release is at
the maximum rate. For instance, where the
replacement shipper agrees to pay the pipeline the
maximum rate for the released capacity, but the
releasing shipper agrees to make a payment to the
replacement shipper, the release must be treated as
a release at less than the maximum rate to which
the posting and bidding requirements of sections
284.8(c) through (e) apply. Id. at P 15, citing, Pacific
Gas Transmission Co. and Southern California
Edison Co., 82 FERC ¶ 61,227 (1998).
66 See Consumers Energy Co., 82 FERC ¶ 61,284,
order approving, 84 FERC ¶ 61,240 (1998). See also
Order No. 636–A at 30,561, where the Commission
stated that capacity cannot be ‘‘resold at a rate
including the pipeline marketing fee. The marketing
fee is not part of the cost of transportation being
released and the replacement shipper should not
pay more than the maximum transportation rate for
the capacity it is acquiring.’’
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
release transactions. They argue that a
further bidding requirement
compromises the integrity and
efficiency of the RFP process at the state
level. Commenters also argue that there
should be no bidding in the AMA
context because those transactions are
not suited to a single auction
methodology.
62. Below, we discuss the
Commission’s proposal to revise the
Commission’s capacity release policies
to give releasing shippers greater
flexibility to negotiate and implement
efficient AMAs. The proposal has two
main parts: (1) Modifications to the
current prohibition against tying
releases to other conditions; and, (2)
modifications to current bidding
requirements.
B. Discussion
63. The Commission proposes
revisions to its prohibition on tying of
release capacity and to section 284.8 of
its regulations in order to facilitate the
use of AMAs. Specifically, as discussed
below, the Commission proposes two
revisions to its capacity release policy
and regulations to facilitate the use of
AMAs. First, the Commission proposes
to exempt AMAs from the prohibition
against tying in order to permit a
releasing shipper to require that the
replacement shipper agree to supply the
releasing shipper’s gas requirements and
to require the replacement shipper to
take assignment of the releasing
shipper’s various gas supply
arrangements, in addition to the
released capacity. Second, the
Commission proposes to eliminate the
current bidding requirement for AMAs
only, such that all releases to an asset
manager, made in order to implement
an AMA between the releasing shipper
and the asset manager, are exempt from
bidding. This would exempt from
bidding all such releases, including
those of less than one year for which we
are proposing to remove the price
ceiling and those of a year or more that
are at rates below the continuing
maximum rate for long-term capacity
releases. Both of the exemptions above
would also be limited to pre-arranged
releases.
64. Gas markets in general, and the
secondary release market in particular,
have undergone significant
development and change since the
inception of the Commission’s capacity
release program. The Commission
adopted the capacity release program in
Order No. 636 ‘‘so that shippers can
reallocate unneeded firm capacity’’ to
those who do need it.67 The bidding
67 Order
PO 00000
No. 636 at 30,418.
Frm 00040
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
requirement and the prohibition against
tying the release to extraneous
conditions were all part of the
Commission’s fundamental goal of
ensuring that such unneeded capacity
would be reallocated to the person who
values it the most. The Commission
found that such ‘‘capacity reallocation
will promote efficient load management
by the pipeline and its customers and,
therefore, efficient use of pipeline
capacity on a firm basis throughout the
year.’’ 68
65. Thus, the Commission developed
its capacity release policies and
regulations based on the assumption
that shippers would release their
capacity only when they were not using
the capacity to serve their own needs.
For example, the Commission
envisioned that LDCs with long-term
contracts for firm transportation service
up to the peak needs of their retail
customers would, during off-peak
periods, release that portion of capacity
not needed to serve the lower off-peak
demand of its retail customers.
However, this basic assumption
underlying the capacity release program
does not hold true in the context of
AMAs, a relatively recent development
in the capacity release market that the
Commission had not anticipated.
66. In the AMA context, the releasing
shipper is not releasing unneeded
capacity, but capacity that is needed to
serve its own supply function and will
be so used during the term of the
release. Releasing shippers in the AMA
context are releasing capacity for the
primary purpose of transferring the
capacity to entities that they perceive
have greater skill and expertise both in
purchasing low cost gas supplies, and in
maximizing the value of the capacity
when it is not needed to meet the
releasing shipper’s gas supply needs. In
short, AMAs entail the releasing shipper
transferring its capacity to another
entity which will perform the functions
the Commission expected releasing
shippers would do for themselves—
purchase their own gas supplies and
release capacity or make bundled sales
when the releasing shipper does not
need the capacity to satisfy its own
needs. The goal of the changes proposed
by the Commission herein is to make
the capacity release program more
efficient by bringing it in line with the
realities of today’s secondary gas
markets.
67. The Commission finds that AMAs
provide significant benefits to many
participants in the natural gas and
electric marketplaces and to the
secondary natural gas market itself. The
68 Id.
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
American Gas Association (AGA), for
example, notes that AMAs are an
important mechanism used by LDCs to
enhance their participation in the
secondary market, and states that the
growth and development of AMAs may
represent the largest change since the
Commission’s market review in the
Order No. 637 proceeding.69 AMAs
allow LDCs to increase the utilization of
facilities and lower gas costs. They also
provide the needed flexibility to
customize arrangements to meet unique
customer needs.70 One important
benefit of AMAs is that they allow for
the maximization of the value of
capacity though the synergy of interstate
capacity and natural gas as a
commodity. As expressed by AGA:
[AMAs] are widely utilized and provide
considerable benefits, i.e. lower gas supply
costs generated from offsets to pipeline
capacity costs and gas supply arrangements
more carefully tailored to the specific
requirements of the market. These benefits
are generated by assembling innovative
arrangements in which the unbundled
components—capacity, gas supply and other
services—are combined in a manner such
that the total value created by the
arrangement exceeds the value of the
individual parts.71
68. AMAs are also beneficial because
they provide a mechanism for capacity
holders to use third party experts to
manage their gas supply arrangements,
an opportunity the LDCs did not have
prior to Order No. 636. The time,
expense and expertise involved with
managing gas supply arrangements is
considerable and thus many capacity
holders, and LDCs in particular, have
come to rely on more sophisticated
marketers to take on their
requirements.72 This results in benefits
to the LDCs by allowing an entity with
more expertise to manage their gas
supply. The ability of LDCs to use
AMAs as a means of relieving the
burdens of administering their capacity
or supply needs on a daily basis also
works to the benefit of the entire market
because that burden may at times result
in LDCs not releasing unused
capacity.73
69. AMAs also provide LDCs and
their customers a mechanism for
offsetting their upstream transportation
costs. AMAs often allow an LDC to
reduce reservation costs that it normally
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
69 See
Comments of AGA at 21.
e.g., Comments of New Jersey Natural Gas
Company at 9.
71 AGA Comments at 14.
72 See, e.g., Comments of BG Energy Merchants,
LLC at 3–4; APGA Comments at 2–3; Comments of
BG Energy Merchants, LLC at 8; Comments of the
Marketer Petitioners at 11; and Comments of FPL
Energy LLC at 10.
73 See Comments of Marketer Petitioners at 11.
70 See
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
passes on to its customers. They also
foster market efficiency by allowing the
releasing shipper to reduce its costs to
the extent that its capacity is used to
facilitate a third party sale that also
benefits that third party (who gets a
bundled product at a price acceptable to
it).
70. LDCs are not the only entities that
benefit from AMAs. Many other large
gas purchasers, including electric
generators and industrial users may
desire to enter into such arrangements.74
For example, AMAs increase the ability
of wholesale electric generators to
provide customer benefits through
superior management of fuel supply
risk, allow generators to focus their
attention on the electric market, and
eliminate administrative burdens
relating to multiple suppliers,
overheads, capital requirements and the
risks associated with marketing excess
gas and pipeline imbalances.75
71. More importantly, AMAs provide
broad benefits to the marketplace in
general. They bring diversity to the mix
of capacity holders and customers that
are served through the capacity release
program, thus enhancing liquidity and
diversity for natural gas products and
services. AMAs result in an overall
increase in the use of interstate pipeline
capacity, as well as facilitating the use
of capacity by different types of
customers in addition to LDCs.76 AMAs
benefit the natural gas market by
creating efficiencies as a result of more
load responsive gas supply, and an
increased utilization of transportation
capacity.
72. AMAs further bring benefits to
consumers, mostly through reductions
in consumer costs. AMAs provide in
general for lower gas supply costs,
resulting in ultimate savings for end use
customers. The overall market benefits
described above also inure to
consumers. These benefits have been
recognized by state commissions and
74 As noted by New Jersey Natural Gas Company
(NJNG), ‘‘in addition to LDCs, there are many other
types of large natural gas purchasers, such as
electric generation facilities and large gas process
industrial users, who face the same challenges with
managing and optimizing their natural gas
portfolios. These customers, whose core business
lies outside the natural gas industry—are also likely
consumers of third party portfolio management
services.’’ NJNG Comments at 9, n. 9.
75 EPSA Comments at 4–5.
76 With regard to the advantages of diversity
among shippers, the EPSA provides as an example
the situation where an LDC looking to shed
underutilized summer capacity may not have the
capability to identify and contract with an electric
generator that needs summer gas, whereas an asset
manager would likely be much better equipped to
handling the logistics and risks associated with
such an off system sale by the LDC.
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
65929
the National Regulatory Research
Institute.77
73. The Interstate Natural Gas
Association of America (INGAA) agrees
with the Marketer Petitioners and others
that the Commission ‘‘should adapt its
regulations to facilitate efficient and
innovative marketing of capacity that
have developed since Order No. 636,’’
provided the Commission remains
guided by the ‘‘principle of full
transparency of the terms of such
capacity release arrangements.’’ 78
74. Based on this industry-wide
support, the Commission believes that
AMAs are in the public interest because
they are beneficial to numerous market
participants and the market in general.
Accordingly, the Commission is
proposing changes to its policies and
regulations to facilitate the utilization
and implementation of AMAs.
1. Tying
75. As noted above, in Order No. 636–
A, the Commission established a
prohibition against the tying of capacity
release to conditions unrelated to
acquiring transportation capacity, where
it stated that:
[t]he Commission reiterates that all terms
and conditions for capacity release must be
posted and non-discriminatory and must
relate solely to the details of acquiring
transportation on the interstate pipelines.
Release of capacity cannot be tied to any
other conditions. Moreover, the Commission
will not tolerate deals undertaken to avoid
the notice requirements of the regulations.
Order No. 636–A at 30, 559.
76. The Commission established the
prohibition against tying in response to
commenters’ concerns that releasing
shippers would attempt to add terms
and conditions that would ‘‘tie the
release of capacity to other
compensation paid to the releasing
shipper.’’ The examples of illicit tying
given by the commenters included an
LDC requiring a potential replacement
shipper to pay a certain price for local
gas transportation service or a producer
conditioning the release of capacity on
the purchase of the producer’s gas.79
Since then, the Commission has granted
several waivers of the prohibition
against tying,80 but only where an entity
sought the waiver to exit the natural gas
transportation business.81
77 See
Comments of BG Energy Merchants, LLC at
8–9.
78 INGAA
Comments at 3.
No. 636–A at 30,559.
80 Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 113 FERC ¶ 61,106
(2005); Northwest Pipeline Corp. and Duke Energy
Trading and Marketing, 109 FERC ¶ 61,044 (2004).
81 See Louis Dreyfus Energy Services, L.P., 114
FERC ¶ 61,246 at 61,780 (2006), denying a waiver
request.
79 Order
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
65930
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
77. Some commenting parties claim
that the Commission’s recent orders
waiving certain of its capacity release
requirements in specific situations have
increased uncertainty regarding the use
of pre-arranged capacity release
transactions to implement portfolio
management services. They state that
the language in these orders suggests
that combining gas supply and pipeline
capacity, or packaging multiple
segments of capacity together, violates
the prohibition against tying, absent a
prior waiver of the Commission’s
capacity release rules.
78. The Commission recognizes that
the broad language in Order No. 636-A
setting forth the prohibition against
tying, as well as the Commission’s
subsequent rulings in individual cases,
have raised a concern that the types of
transactions proponents of AMAs want
to implement may run afoul of the
current policy. For example, capacity
releases made for the purpose of
implementing an AMA generally
include a condition that the asset
manager taking the release will supply
the gas requirements of the releasing
shipper. The release may also require
the asset manager to take assignment of
the releasing shipper’s gas supply
contracts. However, such conditions
could be considered to go beyond ‘‘the
details of acquiring transportation on
the interstate pipelines,’’ because these
conditions relate to the purchase and
sale of the gas commodity.
79. The Commission thus proposes a
partial exemption of AMAs from the
prohibition against tying in order to
permit a releasing shipper in a prearranged release to require that the
replacement shipper (1) agree to supply
the releasing shipper’s gas requirements
and (2) take assignment of the releasing
shipper’s gas supply contracts, as well
as released transportation capacity on
one or more pipelines 82 and storage
capacity with the gas currently in
storage. This exemption would allow
firm shippers to pre-arrange releases of
capacity to an asset manager
(replacement shipper) along with
upstream assets and gas purchase
agreements in a bundled transaction
where the capacity being released will
be used to meet that party’s gas supply
requirements. In addition, the proposed
exemption would be limited to releases
to an asset manager as part of
establishing an AMA. Thus, the asset
manager would be subject to the policy
against tying when it makes subsequent
82 Commission policy already permits a releasing
shipper to require a replacement shipper to take a
release of aggregated capacity contracts on one or
more pipelines, at least in some circumstances. See
Order No. 636–A at 30,558 and n. 144.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
re-releases to third parties during the
term of the AMA. For purposes of this
exemption and the proposed exemption
from bidding discussed in the next
section, a release transaction made in
the context of implementing an AMA
will be any pre-arranged capacity
release that includes a condition that
the releasing shipper may, on any day,
call upon the replacement shipper to
deliver a volume of gas equal to the
daily contract demand of the released
capacity. This proposed definition is
discussed further below.
80. As discussed above, AMAs
provide recognizable benefits to market
participants and the marketplace overall
in terms of more load-responsive use of
gas supply, greater liquidity, increased
utilization of transportation capacity
and the overall efficiencies these
arrangements bring to the marketplace.
However, AMAs require that the
releasing shipper be able to release both
its capacity and its natural gas supply
arrangements in a single package. The
very purpose of the transaction is
frustrated if the releasing shipper cannot
combine the supply and capacity
components of the deal. This tying is
meant to ensure that the released
capacity will continue to be used to
support the releasing shipper’s
acquisition of needed gas supplies.
Based on the fact that AMAs provide
benefits to the market, and that tying of
capacity and supply is necessary to
implement beneficial AMAs, it seems
reasonable to allow the tying conditions
discussed above in the AMA context in
order to foster and facilitate the use and
implementation of such arrangements.
The partial exemption of AMAs
proposed here will foster maximization
of the interstate pipeline grid and
enhance competition.
81. While the Commission is
proposing changes to its prohibition
against tying in order to facilitate
AMAs, the Commission is not adopting
the proposals of some commenters that
the restriction against tying be
eliminated altogether.83 The
Commission’s primary goal in
establishing the capacity release
program was to ensure that transfers of
interstate pipeline capacity from one
shipper to another are made in a not
unduly discriminatory or preferential
manner to the person placing the
highest value on the pipeline capacity.
If a shipper ties a release of unneeded
83 See e.g., Comments of Nstar at 7 (LDCs should
be allowed to link capacity to whatever it wants to
make an ‘‘effective’’ package); Comments of Direct
Energy Services, LLC at 6 (Commission should
permit market participants to offer whatever
bundled transactions they perceive to be in their
best interests).
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
capacity to matters that are unrelated to
the details of acquiring that
transportation capacity, the capacity
may not go to the person who values it
the most. The comments on this issue
have not persuaded the Commission
that, outside the AMA context, release
conditions unrelated to the details of
acquiring transportation service provide
significant benefits to the natural gas
market as a whole similar to those
provided by AMAs. Therefore, when a
shipper releases excess capacity that it
does not need for the purpose for which
it was originally acquired, the
Commission’s original concerns
underlying the prohibition against tying
still apply. The Commission continues
to believe that such excess capacity
should be allocated to the shipper who
values it the most, regardless of whether
the releasing shipper has some private
business reason why it might prefer the
replacement shipper to use its unneeded
capacity in some particular manner.
Thus, based on the distinguishing and
mitigating factors of AMAs as related to
the reasons underlying the prohibition
against tying, the Commission is only
proposing to modify its prohibition
against tying with respect to prearranged releases to implement AMAs,
and not all capacity releases.
82. However, the Commission
requests comment on whether it should
clarify its prohibition concerning tying
in one additional circumstance, which
is not related to the AMA context. Some
commenters assert that the Commission
should facilitate the release of storage
capacity by permitting a releasing
shipper to (1) require a replacement
shipper to take assignment of any gas
that remains in the released storage
capacity at the time the release takes
effect and/or (2) require a replacement
shipper to return the storage capacity to
the releasing shipper at the end of the
release with a specified amount of gas
in storage.84 For example, some LDC
commenters point out that they rely on
having a certain level of gas in storage
by the end of the off-peak summer
injection season in order to be able to
serve their customers during the peak
winter season.85 Therefore, while they
may desire to release storage capacity at
times during the off-peak summer
period, gas must be injected into the
storage capacity at a rate that will
permit the LDC to have its required
amount of gas in storage by the end of
the injection period. If an LDC could
require the replacement shipper to
return the storage capacity with the
required amount of gas in storage at the
84 See
85 Id.
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
e.g. Comments of AGA at 24.
See also Comments of Keyspan at 36.
26NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
end of the release, it would be able to
release more storage capacity than it can
currently. The Commission requests
comment on whether it should clarify
its prohibition on tying to allow a
releasing shipper to include conditions
in a storage release concerning the sale
and/or repurchase of gas in storage
inventory.
2. The Bidding Requirement
83. The Commission’s current
regulations require capacity release
transactions to be posted for competitive
bidding, unless the transactions are at
the maximum rate or are for 31 days or
less.86 The Commission’s principal goal
in requiring release transactions to be
posted for bidding was to ensure that
interstate transportation capacity would
be allocated to those placing the highest
value on obtaining that capacity and to
prevent discriminatory allocation of
interstate capacity at prices below the
market price. The regulations also allow
the releasing shipper to enter into a
‘‘pre-arranged’’ release with a
designated replacement shipper before
any posting for bidding.87 Prearranged
releases are subject to the same bidding
requirements as other releases; however,
the prearranged replacement shipper
will receive the capacity if it matches
the highest bid submitted by any other
bidder.88 In Order 636–A, the
Commission rejected requests for a
general exception to the bidding process
for all pre-arranged deals.89
84. As noted, the Commission has
received a number of comments
suggesting that it eliminate the
requirement for competitive bidding for
capacity releases, especially in the AMA
context. LDCs in particular comment
that bidding is unduly burdensome and
often results in time consuming
procedures that have little practical
benefit. They maintain that bidding
adds uncertainty to the process because
it creates a risk for the replacement
shipper that it will be unable to acquire
capacity at the price it expected, and
thus bidding can prevent parties from
negotiating mutually beneficial
transactions. Others comment that the
delay caused by bidding makes it
difficult to respond to market
opportunities to release, and thus
bidding no longer makes sense in
today’s marketplace. Some claim that
given the development of the natural gas
market and the natural economic
incentive to release at the highest price,
the competitive bidding requirement is
90 For the purposes of this exemption the
Commission will use the same definition as
discussed in the tying section above, and explained
more fully below, for identifying releases eligible
for the exemption.
86 18
CFR § 284.8(h).
CFR § 284.8(b).
88 18 CFR § 284.8(e).
89 Order No. 636–A at 30, 555.
87 18
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
no longer necessary to achieve
allocative efficiency.
85. Commenters assert that the
inefficiencies of the bidding process
pose substantial obstacles to successful
releases to implement AMAs. Bidding
and matching often prevent timely
closing of AMA transactions involving
aggregation of capacity and supply or
aggregation of capacity on multiple
pipelines. This can result in preventing
willing buyers and sellers attempting to
reach agreements that are in their
respective best interests from
consummating deals. Commenters also
note that AMAs usually involve
complex contractual structures with a
variety of valued pieces. These deals are
often negotiated at arms’ length, and
thus, requiring that they be made
subject to bidding creates a risk that one
aspect of the deal could be lost thus
dooming the entire transaction. Because
AMAs often involve extensive
negotiations that lead to pre-arranged
deals, the releasing party wants to be
sure that the replacement shipper with
whom it struck the deal is the one to get
it, on the terms discussed during
negotiations. Again, a bidding
requirement puts that goal at risk.
86. Proponents of eliminating bidding
for AMAs also point out that when an
entity wishes to use a asset manager in
the interest of efficient use of gas supply
and pipeline capacity assets, it is often
required by state regulation to select the
asset manager though a competitive RFP
process. This process allows entities
that are interested in managing the
assets to submit a bid to do so, subject
to the terms and conditions of the RFP.
This process results in a chosen asset
manager for one or more pre-arranged
capacity releases. The commenters state
that, if this same pre-arranged deal is
subject to a further bidding process
under the Commission’s regulations,
then that second process is redundant,
and compromises the integrity and
efficiency of the state mandated
competitive process that has already
been completed.
87. The Commission proposes to
exempt pre-arranged releases to
implement AMAs from the bidding
requirements of section 284.8 of its
regulations, such that pre-arranged
releases made to asset managers in order
to implement AMAs will not be subject
to competitive bidding.90 In light of its
experience with capacity releases and
the comments discussed above, the
Commission has reconsidered the need
Jkt 214001
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
65931
for bidding in the AMA context. It
appears that at least in the AMA
context, the bidding requirement creates
an unwarranted obstacle to the efficient
management of pipeline capacity and
supply assets.
88. All capacity releases made to
implement AMAs are pre-arranged
because it is important that a releasing
shipper be able to use the asset manager
of its choice to effectuate the
components of the agreement. Unlike a
normal capacity release where the
releasing shipper is often shedding
excess capacity and has no intention of
an ongoing relationship with the
replacement shipper, in the AMA
context the identity of the replacement
shipper is often critical because it will
manage the releasing shipper’s portfolio
for some time into the future. During the
process of choosing an asset manager
(often an RFP process), the releasing
shipper considers a number of factors,
including experience in managing
capacity and gas sales, experience with
a particular pipeline or area of the
country, flexibility, creditworthiness
and price. Because the asset manager
will manage the releasing shipper’s gas
supply operations on an ongoing basis,
it is critical that the releasing shipper be
able to release the capacity to its chosen
asset manager. Requiring releases made
in order to implement an AMA to be
posted for bidding would thus interfere
with the negotiation of beneficial
AMAs, by potentially preventing the
releasing shipper from releasing the
capacity to its chosen asset manager.
The Commission concludes that the
benefits of facilitating AMAs outweigh
any disadvantages in exempting such
releases from bidding.
89. While the Commission is
proposing to exempt AMAs from the
capacity release bidding requirements,
AMAs will remain subject to all existing
posting and reporting requirements.
Pipelines will still be obligated to
provide notice of the release pursuant to
18 CFR 284.8(d). The details of the
release transaction must also be posted
on the pipeline’s Internet Web site
under 18 CFR 284.13(b), including any
special terms and conditions applicable
to the capacity release transaction.
Moreover, the pipeline’s index of
customers must include the name of any
agent or asset manager managing a
shipper’s transportation service and
whether that agent or asset manager is
an affiliate of the releasing shipper.91
Therefore, the Commission’s goals of
disclosure and transparency will still be
met.
91 18
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
CFR 284.13(c)(2)(viii) and 284.13(c)(2)(ix).
26NOP1
65932
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
90. The Commission is not proposing
at this time to modify its existing
bidding requirements with respect to
capacity releases made outside the AMA
context (including releases the asset
manager makes to third parties). As
discussed, the Commission originally
adopted the bidding requirements in
order to ensure that releases are made in
a non-discriminatory manner to the
person placing the highest value on the
capacity. The comments received by the
Commission show broad support from
all segments of the industry for
modifying the bidding requirements in
order to facilitate AMAs, which most
commenters believe provide significant
benefits to the natural gas market.
However, the comments do not reflect a
similar level of support for removing the
bidding requirements altogether. In
addition, there has been no showing
that non-AMA prearranged releases
provide benefits of the type we have
found justify exempting AMA releases
from bidding. Moreover, in the typical
non-AMA pre-arranged release, price is
the primary factor, and therefore the
releasing shipper should generally be
indifferent as to the identity of the
replacement shipper so long as it
receives the highest possible price for its
release. Therefore, the Commission does
not presently have information showing
that, outside the AMA context, the
existing bidding requirements hinder
beneficial developments in the market
or no longer serve their original
purpose.
3. Definition of AMAs
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
91. In light of the proposed
exemptions for AMAs discussed above,
the Commission proposes to define a
capacity release that is made as part of
an AMA, and thus would qualify for the
exemptions, to be: Any pre-arranged
release that contains a condition that the
releasing shipper may, on any day, call
upon the replacement shipper to deliver
to the releasing shipper a volume of gas
equal to the daily contract demand of
the released transportation capacity.92 If
the capacity release is a release of
storage capacity, the asset manager’s
delivery obligation need only equal the
daily contract demand under the release
for storage withdrawals.
92 It is the Commission’s intention that with
regard to an AMA involving several separate
releases to the asset manager, the delivery
obligation would be applied separately to each
release, not on cumulative basis to the whole AMA.
For example if an LDC has capacity of 100,000 Dth
on both upstream Pipeline A and downstream
Pipeline B, the asset manager could comply with
the proposed delivery condition by shipping the
same 100,000 Dth over both Pipeline A and
Pipeline B.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
92. In developing a definition of AMA
releases, the Commission seeks to
balance two concerns. First, because the
Commission is proposing that the
exemptions from bidding and the
prohibition against tying apply only in
the context of AMAs, the Commission
seeks a definition of the eligible releases
that is limited to those releases that are
made as part of a bona fide AMA. On
the other hand, because the purpose of
the proposed exemption is to facilitate
AMAs, the Commission wants to avoid
a definition that is so narrow it would
limit the types of AMAs which shippers
and asset managers may negotiate and
thus discourage efficient and innovative
arrangements.
93. The proposed definition focuses
on what the Commission understands to
be the fundamental purpose of AMAs:
That the asset manager will use the
released capacity to deliver gas supplies
to the releasing shipper. The
Commission believes that the
requirement that the replacement
shipper contractually commit itself to
deliver to the releasing shipper, on any
day, gas supplies equal to the daily
contract demand of the released
capacity should achieve the goal of
exempting only AMA transactions from
bidding and the prohibition against
tying. Further, because all AMAs are
done as pre-arranged deals, the
proposed definition requires that the
release be pre-arranged. The
Commission requests comment on
whether other conditions should be
imposed on the eligible releases in order
to ensure that the proposed exemptions
are limited to AMAs.
94. The Commission also believes that
the proposed definition is sufficiently
flexible that it should not interfere with
the development of efficient and
beneficial AMAs. The Commission
recognizes that a shipper may desire to
enter into an AMA for the purpose of
obtaining only a portion of its required
gas supplies. Or it may desire to enter
into multiple AMAs with different asset
managers. The proposed definition does
not prevent such arrangements, since it
contains no requirement that the
releasing shipper obtain any particular
percentage of its gas supplies pursuant
to a particular AMA. The only
requirement is that the asset manager
commits itself to providing gas supplies
up to the contract demand of the
released contract. In addition, while the
Commission expects that the released
capacity will be used by the asset
manager to ship gas supplies to the
releasing shipper, the proposed
definition does not require that the asset
manager make all its deliveries to the
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
releasing shipper over the released
capacity.
95. The Commission also is not
proposing to limit the types of entities
that can use AMAs and take advantage
of the exemptions from bidding and the
prohibition against tying, provided the
criteria stated above are met. The
Commission recognizes that electric
generators and industrial end-users may
make use of AMAs, and thus the
exemption is not limited to LDCs
utilizing AMAs.
96. Finally, the Marketer Petitioners,
in their original request for clarification,
suggested that gas sellers may desire to
use AMAs. However, as proposed, the
definition of AMA does not include
such arrangements, unless the
replacement shipper has an obligation
to re-sell to the releasing shipper
equivalent quantities of natural gas. The
Commission requests comments on
whether it should expand the definition
of AMAs eligible for the partial
exemptions from the prohibition on
tying and bidding to include gas
marketing AMAs. Commenters should
also address the question of how the
Commission would distinguish a gas
marketing AMA eligible for such an
exemption from other release
transactions.
IV. State Mandated Retail Choice
Programs
97. Section 284.8(h)(1) of the
Commission’s current capacity release
regulations exempt prearranged releases
of more than 31 days from bidding only
if they are at the ‘‘maximum tariff rate
applicable to the release.’’ States with
retail open access gas programs (in
which customers can buy gas from
marketers rather than LDCs) have relied
on this ‘‘safe harbor’’ exemption from
bidding in structuring their programs.
Specifically, a key component of most
such programs is a provision for the
LDC to make periodic releases, at the
maximum rate, of its interstate pipeline
capacity to the marketers participating
in the program. The marketers then use
the released capacity to transport the gas
supplies that they sell to their retail
customers. The exemption from bidding
ensures that the LDC’s capacity is
transferred only to the marketers
participating in the state retail
unbundling program and is not obtained
by non-participating third parties.
98. However, the Commission’s
proposal to lift the price ceiling for
releases of one year or less would have
the effect of eliminating the bidding
exemption for releases with terms of
between 31 days and one year. That is
because there would no longer be a
maximum tariff rate applicable to such
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
releases. Moreover, in this NOPR, the
Commission is proposing an additional
exemption from bidding only for
releases made in the context of an AMA,
and releases made as part of a retail
unbundling program would not qualify
for that exemption as it is currently
proposed. As a result, absent some
additional modification of the
regulations concerning bidding, LDCs
would have to post for bidding all
releases of between 31 days and one
year that are made as part of a state
retail unbundling program. This would
mean that the marketers participating in
the program could only obtain the
capacity if they matched any third party
bid for the capacity.
99. In Order Nos. 637–A and 637–B,93
the Commission denied the request by
LDCs for a blanket exemption from
bidding of all capacity releases made as
part of state retail unbundling program.
The Commission explained that, with
the price ceiling removed, posting and
bidding was necessary to protect against
undue discrimination and ensure that
the capacity is properly allocated to the
shipper placing the greatest value on the
capacity. The Commission nevertheless
sought to accommodate the state retail
access programs by providing that, if an
LDC considered an exemption from
bidding essential to further a state retail
unbundling program, the LDC, together
with its state regulatory agency, could
request a waiver of the bidding
regulation to allow the LDC to
consummate pre-arranged capacity
release deals at the maximum rate.
However, the Commission stated that, if
the LDC made such a request, it had to
be prepared to have all its capacity
release transactions, including those not
made as part of the state retail
unbundling program, subject to the
maximum rate.
100. On appeal of Order No. 637, the
court in INGAA affirmed the
Commission’s refusal to grant a blanket
waiver of the bidding requirement for
releases made as part of a state retail
unbundling program. The court stated
that, absent a showing that the retail
unbundling programs are structured as
largely to moot the Commission’s
concern about discrimination, the
Commission’s caution in granting a
blanket waiver was reasonable.
However, the court remanded the issue
of the reasonableness of the condition
that an LDC seeking a waiver must agree
to subject all its releases to the
maximum rate. The court stated that the
requirement of state regulatory
endorsement of the requested waiver
93 Order No. 637–A at 31,569; Order No. 637–B,
92 FERC at 61,163.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
15:37 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
seemed to give the Commission an
avenue to verify the discrimination risk.
The Commission did not address this
issue in its order on remand, because
the price ceiling had been re-imposed
by the time of the remand order, thus
rendering the issue moot.
101. Several commenters in the
instant proceeding again assert that, if
the Commission removes the price
ceiling on capacity release, the
Commission should exempt all capacity
releases to retail choice providers, that
is, releases that are part of a state
approved unbundling program, from the
Commission’s bidding requirements.
AGA and several individual member
LDCs, for example, contend that the
Commission recognized the value of
retail choice programs to the
development of a competitive natural
gas market by providing a waiver
procedure for such releases in Order No.
637–A. AGA argues that the
Commission should now take the next
step to allow an LDC to release capacity
to a retail choice provider at the rate
paid by the LDC without bidding and
without the need to seek a waiver from
the Commission, particularly if the
Commission removes the price ceiling
on capacity release.94 It reasons that
releases to retail choice providers are
not releases of excess capacity but of
capacity needed to better serve their
core markets or to comply with state
requirements. The capacity is still being
used for the purpose it was purchased
and the intention is to allow the LDC’s
retail customers to obtain the benefit of
the LDCs firm pipeline entitlements and
rates. AGA and other LDC commenters
assert that requiring the LDCs to seek a
waiver, as the Commission did in Order
No. 637, adds a cumbersome layer of
regulation.
102. Because the state programs
generally allow choice providers to step
into the shoes of the LDC, commenters
suggest that there is little chance for
undue discrimination or exercise of
market power. Moreover, in order for
retail customers to benefit from the
discounted or negotiated rates that the
LDC may have been able to obtain from
the pipeline, the LDC needs to be able
to release it to the retail choice provider
at that rate. According to the AGA, if a
shipper obtained capacity in the
primary market under conditions that
do not support the pipeline’s maximum
rate, the Commission’s goal of
maximizing allocative efficiency is
hampered by requiring LDCs to sell at
maximum rate to retail choice
providers.
94 See
PO 00000
AGA Comments at 47.
Frm 00045
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
65933
103. The Commission proposes to
address the issue of bidding on releases
of a year or less by LDCs participating
in a state retail unbundling program in
a manner consistent with its actions in
Order No. 637, that is, the Commission
will permit such LDCs to request a
waiver of the bidding regulation to
allow the LDC to consummate shortterm pre-arranged capacity release deals
necessary to implement retail access at
the maximum rate without bidding.
Allowing this limited waiver of the
bidding requirement for capacity
releases made as part of a state
unbundling program would enable retail
access programs to continue to operate
with the same exemption from bidding
which they now have. Adopting the
more cautious approach of case-by-case
waivers, rather than granting a blanket
waiver, is reasonable in light of the
court’s finding that even with state
unbundling programs the potential for
discrimination still exists.
104. As part of this proposal,
however, the Commission will not
require that an LDC seeking such a
waiver agree to subject all of its shortterm capacity releases to the applicable
maximum rate. Any of an LDC’s
capacity releases that are outside of its
state-approved retail choice program
(and not made as part of an AMA as
discussed in the previous section) will
remain subject to bidding, which should
provide adequate protection against
discrimination. Further, it is reasonable
to allow different treatment of releases
made to an approved retail choice
provider, because the capacity released
for that purpose will continue to be
used to serve the LDC’s customers for
whom the capacity was originally
contracted to serve. The Commission’s
proposal here would also remedy the
court’s concern in INGAA with the
requirement that LDCs seeking waivers
agree to subject all of their releases to
the maximum rate.
105. While the Commission is not
proposing a blanket exemption from
bidding for releases made by LDCs
under state retail choice programs, the
Commission requests comment on
whether such releases should be treated
as similar to releases made as part of an
AMA and thus accorded the same full
exemption from bidding. As with
releases in the AMA context, LDC
releases in the retail unbundling context
are not releases of excess capacity to the
open market but of capacity needed to
serve the original customers for whom
the LDC purchased the capacity. In the
state unbundling context, the LDC must
release and allocate capacity to a
marketer that an end use customer may
choose as its supplier. Thus, the
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
65934
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
capacity may be treated as still being
used for the purpose it was purchased
and as it was originally intended.
However, the Commission seeks
comment on whether such releases
should be exempt from the bidding
requirement. Should the Commission
find that such releases provide similar
benefits to the market as releases which
are made as part of establishing an
AMA? Do such releases entail a greater
potential for undue discrimination than
releases made as part of establishing an
AMA?
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
V. Shipper-Must-Have-Title
Requirement
106. The Commission will retain its
shipper-must-have-title requirement.
While the shipper-must-have-title
requirement had its original roots in
individual pipeline proceedings to
implement Order No. 436 nondiscriminatory open-access
transportation, it has become the
foundation for the Commission’s
capacity release program.95 The purpose
of the shipper-must-have-title
requirement is to require that all
transfers of capacity from one shipper to
another take place through the capacity
release program. Without the shippermust-have-title requirement, ‘‘capacity
holders could simply transport gas over
the pipeline for another entity,’’ 96
without complying with any of the
requirements of the capacity release
program. Thus, the capacity holder
could charge the other entity any rate it
desired for this service, and the capacity
holder would not need to post the
arrangement with the other entity for
bidding to permit others to obtain the
service at a higher rate.
107. By contrast, under the shippermust-have-title requirement, an
assignment of capacity from one shipper
to another may only be accomplished
through the capacity release program.
As discussed above, under the capacity
release program, any release must
comply with any applicable price
ceiling and bidding requirements. In
addition, the replacement shipper must
contract with the pipeline, and section
284.8(d) of the Commission’s
regulations requires the pipeline to post
information regarding the replacement
shipper’s contract, including any special
terms and conditions. This provides
transparency in the secondary market by
95 As the Commission explained in Order No.
637–A, ‘‘the capacity release rules were designed
with [the shipper-must-have-title] policy as their
foundation,’’ because without this requirement
‘‘capacity holders could simply transport gas over
the pipeline for another entity.’’ Order No. 637 at
31,300.
96 Order No. 637 at 31,300.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
enabling the Commission and all
interested parties to monitor the
capacity release market.
108. The shipper-must-have-title
requirement remains an important
transparency tool given the proposals
discussed above and the Commission’s
decision to maintain the price ceiling
for long-term capacity releases and to
require bidding for capacity releases
outside the context of AMAs. If the
Commission were to eliminate the
shipper-must-have-title requirement,
shippers could easily evade the
continuing requirements of the capacity
release program in the manner
discussed above. In essence,
participation in the capacity release
program would become voluntary and
shippers desiring to make long-term
releases at more than the maximum rate
or to make prearranged non-maximum
rate deals without bidding could simply
make private arrangements outside of
the capacity release program.
109. The shipper-must-have-title
requirement ensures transparency in the
capacity market. Because replacement
shippers must in all instances enter into
contracts with the pipeline, the
Commission can ensure transparency by
requiring the pipelines to report the
essential terms of the replacement
shippers’ contracts. Without the rule,
the Commission would have to develop
separate reporting requirements for
shippers who make private
arrangements to ship gas for other
entities. It is more efficient for the
Commission and the marketplace to
monitor and enforce the reporting
requirements on the one hundred or so
interstate pipelines rather than to
enforce them on thousands of shippers.
110. Finally, in the Commission’s
opinion, the shipper-must-have-title
requirement does not cause undue
administrative burdens. Through the
Commission’s adoption of the North
American Energy Standards Board’s
(NAESB) standards, all pipelines must
provide a title transfer tracking service
at no charge as part of their nomination
process, so that any title transfers
required by the shipper-must-have-title
requirement are easily accomplished.97
VI. Regulatory Requirements
A. Information Collection Statement
111. Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) regulations require OMB
to approve certain information
collection requirements imposed by
97 In this context the shipper-must-have-title
requirement accomplishes on the gas side much the
same purpose as ‘‘e-tagging’’ title transfers on the
electric side.
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
agency rule.98 Comments are solicited
on the Commission’s need for this
information, whether the information
will have practical utility, the accuracy
of provided burden estimates, ways to
enhance the quality, utility and clarity
of the information to be collected, and
any suggested methods for minimizing
respondents’ burden, including the use
of automated information techniques.
Title: FERC–549B, Gas Pipeline Rates:
Capacity Information.
Action: Proposed Information
Collection.
OMB Control No.: 1902–0169B.
112. The applicant shall not be
penalized for failure to respond to this
collection of information unless the
collection of information displays a
valid OMB control number.
Respondents: Business or other for
profit.
Frequency of Responses: On occasion.
Necessity of Information: The
proposed rule would permit market
based pricing for short-term capacity
releases and facilitate AMAs by relaxing
the Commission’s prohibition on tying
and its bidding requirements for certain
capacity releases. As noted earlier in the
NOPR, elimination of the price ceiling
for short-term capacity releases will
provide more accurate price signals
concerning the market value of pipeline
capacity. Further, implementation of
AMAs will make the capacity release
program more efficient as releasing
shippers can transfer their capacity to
entities with greater expertise both in
purchasing low cost gas supplies, and in
maximizing the value of the capacity
when it is not needed to meet the
releasing shipper’s gas supply needs.
Such arrangements free up the time,
expense and expertise involved with
managing gas supply arrangements and
serve as a means of relieving the
burdens of administering their capacity
or supply needs.
113. Although the Commission is
taking the steps to enhance competition
in the secondary capacity release market
and increase shipper options, it is not
modifying its existing reporting
requirements in section 284.13 of its
regulations. The current burden
estimates for FERC–549B will be
unaffected by this rule and for that
reason, the Commission will send a
copy of this proposed rule to OMB for
informational purposes only.
B. Environmental Analysis
114. The Commission is required to
prepare an Environmental Assessment
or an Environmental Impact Statement
for any action that may have a
98 5
CFR 1320.11.
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
significant adverse effect on the human
environment.99 The Commission has
categorically excluded certain actions
from these requirements as not having a
significant effect on the human
environment.100 The actions proposed
to be taken here fall within categorical
exclusions in the Commission’s
regulations for rules that are corrective,
clarifying or procedural, for information
gathering, analysis, and dissemination,
and for sales, exchange, and
transportation of natural gas that
requires no construction of facilities.101
Therefore an environmental review is
unnecessary and has not been prepared
in this rulemaking.
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
C. Regulatory Flexibility Act
115. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 (RFA) 102 generally requires a
description and analysis of final rules
that will have significant economic
impact on a substantial number of small
entities. The Commission is not
required to make such an analysis if
proposed regulations would not have
such an effect.103 Under the industry
standards used for purposes of the RFA,
a natural gas pipeline company qualifies
as ‘‘a small entity’’ if it has annual
revenues of $6.5 million or less. Most
companies regulated by the Commission
do not fall within the RFA’s definition
of a small entity.104
116. The procedural modifications
proposed herein should have no
significant negative impact on those
entities, be they large or small, subject
to the Commission’s regulatory
jurisdiction under the NGA. As
previously noted in the NOPR, removal
of the price ceiling will enable releasing
shippers to offer competitively-priced
alternatives to the pipelines’ negotiated
rate offerings. A small entity that
participates in the market will no longer
be constrained by a ceiling price for its
unused capacity. Further, removal of the
ceiling also permits more efficient
utilization of capacity by permitting
prices to rise to market clearing levels,
allowing those entities that place the
highest value on the capacity to obtain
it. Accordingly, the Commission
certifies that this notice’s proposed
99 Order No. 486, Regulations Implementing the
National Environmental Policy Act, 52 FR 47897
(Dec. 17, 1987), FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulation
Preambles 1986–1990 ¶ 30,783 (1987).
100 18 CFR 380.4 (2007).
101 See 18 CFR 380.4(a)(2)(ii), 380.4(a)(5) and
380.4(a)(27) (2007).
102 5 U.S.C. 601–612.
103 5 U.S.C. 605(b)(2000).
104 5 U.S.C. 601(3), citing to Section 3 of the Small
Business Act, 15 U.S.C. 623 (2000). Section 3
defines a ‘‘small-business concern’’ as a business
which is independently owned and operated and
which is not dominant in its field of operation.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
regulations, if promulgated, will not
have a significant economic impact on
a substantial number of small entities.
D. Comment Procedures
117. The Commission invites
interested persons to submit comments
on the matters and issues proposed in
this notice to be adopted, including any
related matters or alternative proposals
that commenters may wish to discuss.
Comments are due 45 days from
publication in the Federal Register.
Comments must refer to Docket No.
RM08–1–000, and must include the
commenter’s name, the organization
they represent, if applicable, and their
address in their comments.
118. The Commission encourages
comments to be filed electronically via
the eFiling link on the Commission’s
Web site at https://www.ferc.gov. The
Commission accepts most standard
word processing formats. Documents
created electronically using word
processing software should be filed in
native applications or print-to-PDF
format and not in a scanned format.
Commenters filing electronically do not
need to make a paper filing.
119. Commenters that are not able to
file comments electronically must send
an original and 14 copies of their
comments to: Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, Secretary of the
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426.
120. All comments will be placed in
the Commission’s public files and may
be viewed, printed, or downloaded
remotely as described in the Document
Availability section below. Commenters
on this proposal are not required to
serve copies of their comments on other
commenters.
E. Document Availability
121. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through
FERC’s Home Page (https://www.ferc.gov)
and in FERC’s Public Reference Room
during normal business hours (8:30 a.m.
to 5 p.m. Eastern time) at 888 First
Street, NE., Room 2A, Washington, DC
20426.
122. From FERC’s Home Page on the
Internet, this information is available on
eLibrary. The full text of this document
is available on eLibrary in PDF and
Microsoft Word format for viewing,
printing, and/or downloading. To access
this document in eLibrary, type the
docket number excluding the last three
digits of this document in the docket
number field.
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
65935
123. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the FERC’s Web site during
normal business hours from FERC
Online Support at 202–502–6652 (toll
free at 1–866–208–3676) or e-mail at
ferconlinesupport@ferc.gov, or the
Public Reference Room at (202) 502–
8371, TTY (202)502–8659. E-mail the
Public Reference Room at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 284
Incorporation by reference, Natural
gas, Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements.
By direction of the Commission.
Nathaniel J. Davis, Sr.,
Deputy Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission proposes to amend part
284, Chapter I, Title 18, Code of Federal
Regulations, to read as follows:
PART 284—CERTAIN SALES AND
TRANSPORTATION OF NATURAL GAS
UNDER THE NATURAL GAS POLICY
ACT OF 1978 AND RELATED
AUTHORITIES
1. The authority citation for part 284
continues to read as follows:
Authority: 15 U.S.C. 717–717w, 3301–
3432; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352; 43 U.S.C. 1331–
1356.
2. Amend § 284.8 as follows:
a. In paragraph (e), remove the words
‘‘(not over the maximum rate)’’.
b. Remove paragraph (i).
c. Add two sentences to the end of
paragraph (b) and revise paragraph (h)
to read as follows.
§ 284.8 Release of firm capacity on
interstate pipelines.
*
*
*
*
*
(b) * * * The rate charged the
replacement shipper for a release of
capacity for more than one year may not
exceed the applicable maximum rate.
No rate limitation applies to the release
of capacity for a period of one year or
less.
*
*
*
*
*
(h)(1) A release of capacity by a firm
shipper to a replacement shipper for any
period of 31 days or less, a release of
capacity for more than one year at the
maximum tariff rate, or a release to an
asset manager as defined in paragraph
(h)(3) of this section need not comply
with the notification and bidding
requirements of paragraphs (c) through
(e) of this section. Notice of a firm
release under this paragraph must be
provided on the pipeline’s electronic
bulletin board as soon as possible, but
not later than forty-eight hours, after the
release transaction commences.
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
65936
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 226 / Monday, November 26, 2007 / Proposed Rules
ebenthall on PROD1PC69 with PROPOSALS
(2) When a release of capacity for 31
days or less is exempt from bidding
requirements under paragraph (h)(1) of
this section, a firm shipper may not rollover, extend, or in any way continue the
release without complying with the
requirements of paragraphs (c) through
(e) of this section, and may not rerelease to the same replacement shipper
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:18 Nov 23, 2007
Jkt 214001
under this paragraph at less than the
maximum tariff rate until 28 days after
the first release period has ended.
(3) A release to an asset manager
exempt from bidding requirements
under paragraph (h)(1) of this section is
any prearranged capacity release that
contains a condition that the releasing
shipper may, on any day, call upon the
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
replacement shipper to deliver to the
releasing shipper a volume of gas equal
to the daily contract demand of the
released transportation capacity or the
daily contract demand for storage
withdrawals.
[FR Doc. E7–22952 Filed 11–23–07; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
E:\FR\FM\26NOP1.SGM
26NOP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 72, Number 226 (Monday, November 26, 2007)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 65916-65936]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E7-22952]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 284
[Docket No. RM08-1-000]
Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release Market
November 15, 2007.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Department of Energy.
ACTION: Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission is proposing
revisions to its regulations governing interstate natural gas pipelines
to reflect changes in the market for short-term transportation services
on pipelines and to improve the efficiency of the Commission's capacity
release mechanism. The Commission is proposing to permit market based
pricing for short-term capacity releases and to facilitate asset
management arrangements by relaxing the Commission's prohibition on
tying and on its bidding requirements for certain capacity releases.
DATES: Comments are due January 10, 2008.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by docket number by any
of the following methods:
Agency Web site: https://ferc.gov. Documents created electronically
using word processing software should be filed in native applications
or print-to-PDF format and not in a scanned format.
Mail/Hand Delivery: Commenters unable to file comments
electronically must mail or hand deliver an original and 14 copies of
their comments to: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Secretary of
the Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
Instructions: For detailed instructions on submitting comments and
additional information on the rulemaking process, see the Comment
Procedures section of this document.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Robert McLean, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
Robert.McLean@ferc.gov, (202) 502-8156.
David Maranville, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
David.Maranville@ferc.gov, (202) 502-6351.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
Table of Contents
Paragraph
numbers
I. Background.............................................. 2.
A. The Capacity Release Program.......................... 2.
B. Petitions and Industry Comments....................... 15.
II. Removal of Maximum Rate Ceiling for Short-Term Capacity 23.
Release...................................................
A. Policies Enhancing Competition........................ 30.
B. Data on Capacity Release Transactions................. 33.
C. Available Pipeline Service Constrains Market Power 40.
Abuses..................................................
D. Monitoring............................................ 42.
E. Requests to Expand Market-Based Rate Authority........ 43.
1. Removal of Price Ceiling for Long-Term Releases..... 43.
2. Removal of Price Ceiling for Pipeline Short-Term 46.
Transactions..........................................
III. Asset Management Arrangements......................... 53.
A. Background............................................ 53.
B. Discussion............................................ 63.
1. Tying............................................... 75.
2. The Bidding Requirement............................. 83.
3. Definition of AMAs.................................. 91.
IV. State Mandated Retail Choice Programs.................. 97.
V. Shipper Must-Have-Title Requirement..................... 106.
VI. Regulatory Requirements................................ 111.
A. Information Collection Statement...................... 111.
B. Environmental Analysis................................ 114.
C. Regulatory Flexibility Act............................ 115.
D. Comment Procedures.................................... 117.
E. Document Availability................................. 121.
1. In this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, the Commission proposes
to revise its Part 284 regulations
[[Page 65917]]
concerning the release of firm capacity by shippers on interstate
natural gas pipelines. First, the Commission proposes to remove, on a
permanent basis, the rate ceiling on capacity release transactions of
one year or less. Second, the Commission proposes to modify its
regulations to facilitate the use of asset management arrangements
(AMAs), under which a capacity holder releases some or all of its
pipeline capacity to an asset manager who agrees to supply the gas
needs of the capacity holder. Specifically, the Commission proposes to
exempt capacity releases made as part of AMAs from the prohibition on
tying and from the bidding requirements of section 284.8. These
proposals are designed to enhance competition in the secondary capacity
release market and increase shipper options for how they obtain gas
supplies.
I. Background
A. The Capacity Release Program
2. The Commission adopted its capacity release program as part of
the restructuring of natural gas pipelines required by Order No.
636.\1\ In Order No. 636, the Commission sought to foster two primary
goals. The first goal was to ensure that all shippers have meaningful
access to the pipeline transportation grid so that willing buyers and
sellers can meet in a competitive, national market to transact the most
efficient deals possible. The second goal was to ensure consumers have
``access to an adequate supply of gas at a reasonable price.'' \2\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Pipeline Service Obligations and Revisions to Regulations
Governing Self-Implementing Transportation and Regulation of Natural
Gas Pipelines After Partial Wellhead Decontrol, Order No. 636, 57 FR
13,267 (April 16, 1992), FERC Stats. and Regs., Regulations
Preambles January 1991-June 1996 ] 30,939 (April 8, 1992); order on
reh'g, Order No. 636-A, 57 FR 36,128 (August 12, 1002), FERC Stats.
and Regs., Regulations Preambles January 1991-June 1996 ] 30,950
(August 3, 1992); order on reh'g, Order No. 636-B, 57 FR 57,911
(Dec. 8, 1992), 61 FERC ] 61,272 (1992); notice of denial of reh'g,
62 FERC ] 61,007 (1993); aff'd in part, vacated and remanded in
part, United Dist. Companies v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105 (D.C. Cir. 1996);
order on remand, Order No. 636-C, 78 FERC ] 61,186 (1997).
\2\ Order No. 636 at 30,393 (citations omitted).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. To accomplish these goals, the Commission sought to maximize the
availability of unbundled firm transportation service to all
participants in the gas commodity market. The linchpin of Order No. 636
was the requirement that pipelines unbundle their transportation and
storage services from their sales service, so that gas purchasers could
obtain the same high quality firm transportation service whether they
purchased from the pipeline or another gas seller. In order to create a
transparent program for the reallocation of interstate pipeline
capacity to complement the unbundled, open access environment created
by Order No. 636, the Commission also adopted a comprehensive capacity
release program to increase the availability of unbundled firm
transportation capacity by permitting firm shippers to release their
capacity to others when they were not using it.\3\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ In brief, under the Commission's capacity release program, a
firm shipper (releasing shipper) sells its capacity by returning its
capacity to the pipeline for reassignment to the buyer (replacement
shipper). The pipeline contracts with, and receives payment from,
the replacement shipper and then issues a credit to the releasing
shipper. The replacement shipper may pay less than the pipeline's
maximum tariff rate, but not more. 18 CFR 284.8(e) (2007). The
results of all releases are posted by the pipeline on its Internet
Web site and made available through standardized, downloadable
files.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. The Commission reasoned that the capacity release program would
promote efficient load management by the pipeline and its customers and
would, therefore, result in the efficient use of firm pipeline capacity
throughout the year. It further concluded that, ``because more buyers
will be able to reach more sellers through firm transportation
capacity, capacity reallocation comports with the goal of improving
nondiscriminatory, open access transportation to maximize the benefits
of the decontrol of natural gas at the wellhead and in the field.'' \4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ Order No. 636 at 30,418.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. In Order No. 636, the Commission expressed concerns regarding
its ability to ensure that firm shippers would reallocate their
capacity in a non-discriminatory manner to those who placed the highest
value on the capacity up to the maximum rate. The Commission noted that
prior to Order No. 636, it authorized some pipelines to permit their
shippers to ``broker'' their capacity to others. Under such capacity
brokering, firm shippers were permitted to assign their capacity
directly to a replacement shipper, without any requirement that the
brokering shipper post the availability of its capacity or allocate it
to the highest bidder.\5\ However, in Order No. 636, the Commission
found ``there [were] too many potential assignors of capacity and too
many different programs for the Commission to oversee capacity
brokering.'' \6\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ See Algonquin Gas Transmission Corp., 59 FERC ] 61,032
(1992).
\6\ Order No. 636 at 30,416.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
6. The Commission sought to ensure that the efficiencies of the
secondary market were not frustrated by unduly discriminatory access to
the market.\7\ Therefore, the Commission replaced capacity brokering
with the capacity release program designed to provide greater assurance
that transfers of capacity from one shipper to another were transparent
and not unduly discriminatory. This assurance took the form of several
conditions that the Commission placed on the transfer of capacity under
its new program.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ Order No. 636-A at 30,554.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
7. First, the Commission prohibited private transfers of capacity
between shippers and, instead, required that all release transactions
be conducted through the pipeline. Therefore, when a releasing shipper
releases its capacity, the replacement shipper must enter into a
contract directly with the pipeline, and the pipeline must post
information regarding the contract, including any special
conditions.\8\ In order to enforce the prohibition on private transfers
of capacity, the Commission required that a shipper must have title to
any gas that it ships on the pipeline.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ Order No. 636 emphasized:
The main difference between capacity brokering as it now exists
and the new capacity release program is that under capacity
brokering, the brokering customer could enter into and execute its
own deals without involving the pipeline. Under capacity releasing,
all offers must be put on the pipeline's electronic bulletin board
and contracting is done directly with the pipeline. Order No. 636 at
30, 420 (emphasis in original).
\9\ As the Commission subsequently explained in Order No. 637,
``the capacity release rules were designed with [the shipper-must-
have-title] policy as their foundation,'' because, without this
requirement, ``capacity holders could simply transport gas over the
pipeline for another entity.'' Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services and Regulation of Interstate Natural Gas
Transportation Services, Order No. 637, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,091
at 31,300, clarified, Order No. 637-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,099,
reh'g denied, Order No. 637-B, 92 FERC ] 61,062 (2000), aff'd in
part and remanded in part sub nom. Interstate Natural Gas Ass'n of
America v. FERC, 285 F.3d 18 (D.C. Cir. 2002), order on remand, 101
FERC ] 61,127 (2002), order on reh'g, 106 FERC ] 61,088 (2004),
aff'd sub nom. American Gas Ass'n v. FERC, 428 F.3d 255 (D.C. Cir.
2005). See section V below for a further explanation of the shipper-
must-have-title requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
8. Second, the Commission determined that the record of the
proceeding that led to Order No. 636 did not reflect that the market
for released capacity was competitive. The Commission reasoned that the
extent of competition in the secondary market may not be sufficient to
ensure that the rates for released capacity will be just and
reasonable. Therefore, the Commission imposed a ceiling on the rate
that the releasing shipper could charge for the released capacity.\10\
This ceiling was derived from the Commission's estimate of the maximum
rates necessary for the pipeline to
[[Page 65918]]
recover its annual cost-of-service revenue requirement, which the
Commission prorated over the period of each release.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ Order No. 636 at 30,418; Order No. 636-A at 30,560.f
\11\ Order No. 637 at 31,270-71.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
9. Third, the Commission required that capacity offered for release
at less than the maximum rate must be posted for bidding, and the
pipeline must allocate the capacity ``to the person offering the
highest rate (not over the maximum rate).'' \12\ The Commission
permitted the releasing shipper to choose a pre-arranged replacement
shipper who can retain the capacity by matching the highest bid rate.
The bidding requirement, however, does not apply to releases of 31 days
or less or to any release at the maximum rate. But all releases,
whether or not subject to bidding, must be posted.\13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ 18 CFR Sec. 284.8(e) (2007) provides in pertinent part that
``[t]he pipeline must allocate released capacity to the person
offering the highest rate (not over the maximum rate) and offering
to meet any other terms or conditions of the release.''
\13\ 18 CFR Sec. 284.8(h)(1) provides that a release of
capacity for less than 31 days, or for any term at the maximum rate,
need not comply with certain notification and bidding requirements,
but that such release may not exceed the maximum rate. Notice of the
release ``must be provided on the pipeline's electronic bulletin
board as soon as possible, but not later than forty-eight hours,
after the release transaction commences.''
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
10. Finally, the Commission prohibited tying the release of
capacity to any extraneous conditions so that the releasing shippers
could not attempt to add additional terms or conditions to the release
of capacity. The Commission articulated the prohibition against the
tying of capacity in Order No. 636-A, where it stated:
The Commission reiterates that all terms and conditions for
capacity release must be posted and non-discriminatory and must
relate solely to the details of acquiring transportation on the
interstate pipelines. Release of capacity cannot be tied to any
other conditions. Moreover, the Commission will not tolerate deals
undertaken to avoid the notice requirements of the regulations.
Order No. 636-A at 30, 559 (emphasis in the original).
11. Subsequent to the Commission's adoption of its capacity release
program in Order No. 636, the Commission conducted two experimental
programs to provide more flexibility in the capacity release market. In
1996, the Commission sought to establish an experimental program
inviting individual shipper and pipeline applications to remove price
ceilings related to capacity release.\14\ The Commission recognized
that significant benefits could be realized through removal of the
price ceiling in a competitive secondary market. Removal of the ceiling
permits more efficient capacity utilization by permitting prices to
rise to market clearing levels and by permitting those who place the
highest value on the capacity to obtain it.\15\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ Secondary Market Transactions on Interstate Natural Gas
Pipelines, Proposed Experimental Pilot Program to Relax the Price
Cap for Secondary Market Transactions, 61 FR 41401 (Aug. 8, 1996),
76 FERC ] 61,120, order on reh'g, 77 FERC ] 61,183 (1996).
\15\ 77 FERC ] 61,183 (1996) at 61,699.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. In 2000, in Order No. 637, the Commission conducted a broader
experiment in which the Commission removed the rate ceiling for short-
term (less than one year) capacity release transactions for a two-year
period ending September 30, 2002. In contrast to the experiment that it
conducted in 1996, in the Order No. 637 experiment the Commission
granted blanket authorization in order to permit all firm shippers on
all open access pipelines to participate. The Commission stated that it
undertook this experiment to improve shipper options and market
efficiency during peak periods. The Commission reasoned that during
peak periods, the maximum rate cap on capacity release transactions
inhibits the creation of an effective transportation market by
preventing capacity from going to those that value it the most and
therefore the elimination of this rate ceiling would eliminate this
inefficiency and enhance shipper options in the short-term
marketplace.\16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ Order No. 637 at 31,263. The Commission also explained why
it was lifting the price cap on an experimental basis, instead of
permanently, stating:
While the removal of the price cap is justified based on the
record in this rulemaking, the Commission recognizes that this is a
significant regulatory change that should be subject to ongoing
review by the Commission and the industry. No matter how good the
data suggesting that a regulatory change should be made, there is no
substitute for reviewing the actual results of a regulatory action.
The two year waiver will provide an opportunity for such a review
after sufficient information is obtained to validly assess the
results. Due to the variation between years in winter temperatures,
the waiver will provide the Commission and the industry with two
winter's worth of data with which to examine the effects of this
policy change and determine whether changes or modifications may be
needed prior to the expiration of the waiver. Order No. 637 at
31,279.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
13. Upon an examination of pricing data on basis differentials
between points,\17\ the Commission found that the price ceiling on
capacity release transactions limited the capacity options of short-
term shippers because firm capacity holders were able to avoid price
ceilings on released capacity by substituting bundled sales
transactions at market prices (where the market place value of
transportation is an implicit component of the delivered price). As a
consequence, the Commission determined that the price ceilings did not
limit the prices paid by shippers in the short-term market as much as
the ceilings limit transportation options for shippers. In short, the
Commission found that the rate ceiling worked against the interests of
short-term shippers, because with the rate ceilings in place, a shipper
looking for short-term capacity on a peak day who was willing to offer
a higher price in order to obtain it, could not legally do so; this
reduced its options for procuring short-term transportation at the
times that it needed it most.\18\ Throughout this experiment, the
Commission retained the rate ceiling for firm and interruptible
capacity available from the pipeline as well as long-term capacity
release transactions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ Among other things, the data showed that the value of
pipeline capacity, as shown by basis differentials, was generally
less than the pipelines' maximum interruptible transportation rates,
except during the coldest days of the year, and capacity release
prices also averaged somewhat less than pipelines' maximum
interruptible rates.
\18\ Order No. 637 at 31,282.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
14. On April 5, 2002, the United States Court of Appeals for the
District of Columbia Circuit, in Interstate Natural Gas Association of
America v. FERC,\19\ upheld the Commission's experimental price ceiling
program for short-term capacity release transactions as set forth in
Order No. 637.\20\ The court found that the Commission's ``light
handed'' approach to the regulation of capacity release prices was,
given the safeguards that the Commission had imposed, consistent with
the criteria set forth in Farmers Union Cent. Exch. v. FERC.\21\ The
court found that the Commission made a substantial record for the
proposition that market rates would not materially exceed the ``zone of
reasonableness'' required by Farmers Union. The court also found that
the Commission's inference of competition in the capacity release
market was well founded, that the price spikes shown in the
Commission's data were consistent with competition and reflected
scarcity of supply rather than monopoly power, and that outside of such
price spikes, the rates were well below the estimated regulated
price.\22\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ 285 F.3d 18 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (INGAA).
\20\ Specifically, the court found that: ``[g]iven the
substantial showing that in this context competition has every
reasonable prospect of preventing seriously monopolistic pricing,
together with the non-cost advantages cited by the Commission and
the experimental nature of this particular ``lighthanded''
regulation, we find the Commission's decision neither a violation of
the NGA, nor arbitrary or capricious.'' INGAA at 35.
\21\ 734 F.2d 1486 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (Farmers Union).
\22\ Id. at 33.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 65919]]
B. Petitions and Industry Comments
15. In August 2006, Pacific Gas and Electric Co. (PG&E) and
Southwest Gas Corp. (Southwest) filed a petition requesting the
Commission to amend sections 284.8(e) and (h)(1) of its regulations to
remove the maximum rate cap on capacity release transactions.\23\ They
stated that removing the price ceiling would improve the efficiency of
the capacity market by giving releasing shippers a greater incentive to
release their capacity during periods of constraint. They asserted that
this would allow shippers who value the capacity the most to obtain it,
provide more accurate price signals concerning the value of capacity,
and provide greater potential cost mitigation to holders of long-term
firm capacity. They also pointed out that the Commission now permits
pipelines to negotiate rates with individual customers using basis
differentials (i.e., the difference between natural gas commodity
prices at two trading points, such as a supply basin and a city gate
delivery point) and such negotiated rates may exceed the pipeline's
recourse maximum rate. PG&E and Southwest assert that releasing
shippers must have greater pricing flexibility in order to compete with
such negotiated rate deals offered by the pipelines.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ Docket No. RM06-21-000. PG&E subsequently clarified that it
only seeks removal of the price cap for capacity releases of less
than a year.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
16. In October 2006, a group of large natural gas marketers \24\
(Marketer Petitioners) requested clarification of the operation of the
Commission's capacity release rules in the context of asset (or
portfolio) management services.\25\ An AMA is an agreement under which
a capacity holder releases, on a pre-arranged basis, all or some of its
pipeline capacity, along with associated gas purchase contracts, to an
asset or portfolio manager. The asset manager uses the capacity to
satisfy the gas supply needs of the releasing shipper, and, when the
capacity is not needed to serve the releasing shipper, the asset
manager uses it to make gas sales or re-releases the capacity to third
parties.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ Coral Energy Resources, LP; ConocoPhillips Co.; Chevron
USA, Inc.; Constellation Energy Commodities Group, Inc.; Tenaska
Marketing Ventures; Merrill Lynch Commodities, Inc.; Nexen Marketing
USA, Inc.; and UBS Energy LLC.
\25\ The Marketer Petitioners originally filed their petition in
Docket Nos. RM91-11-009 and RM98-10-013. However, the Commission has
re-docketed the petition in Docket No. RM07-4-000.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
17. The Marketer Petitioners state that Order No. 636 adopted the
capacity release program as a means for shippers to transfer unneeded
capacity to other entities who desired it. However, the Marketer
Petitioners state, today many local distribution companies (LDCs) and
others desire to release their capacity to a replacement shipper (asset
manager) with greater market expertise, who will continue to use the
capacity to provide gas supplies to the releasing shipper and will be
better able to maximize the value of the released capacity when it is
not needed to serve the releasing shipper. The Marketer Petitioners
state that the Commission's current capacity release rules may
interfere with marketers providing efficient asset management services.
They also assert that they are not seeking to remove the capacity
release rate cap, but acknowledge that if the Commission took such
action, it would eliminate some of their problems.
18. On January 3, 2007, the Commission issued a request for
comments on the current operation of the Commission's capacity release
program and whether changes in any of its capacity release policies
would improve the efficiency of the natural gas market.\26\ The
Commission's request for comments was in part in response to the
petitions discussed above. In addition to the issues raised by the
petitions, the Commission also included in its request for comments a
series of questions asking whether the Commission should lift the price
ceiling, remove its capacity release bidding requirements, modify its
prohibition on tying arrangements, and/or remove the shipper-must-have-
title requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ Pacific Gas & Electric Co., 118 FERC ] 61,005 (2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
19. In response to the price ceiling issues, commenting LDCs and
pipelines both advocate lifting the ceiling, subject to different
conditions. The LDCs favor lifting the ceiling only if it would still
apply to the pipeline's direct sales of capacity because, among other
things, the pipelines have negotiated rate authority that is not
available to releasing shippers.\27\ The pipelines advocate the removal
of the cap only if the Commission removes the cap from the entire
capacity marketplace; otherwise, they argue, it will create a
bifurcated market and an uneven playing field.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ Under the negotiated rate program, a pipeline may charge
rates different from those set forth in its open access tariff, as
long as the shipper has recourse to taking service at the maximum
tariff rate. See, Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ] 61,076, reh'g
denied, 75 FERC ] 61,024 (1996), petitions for review denied sub
nom., Burlington Resources Oil & Gas Co. v. FERC, 172 F.3d 918 (D.C.
Cir. 1998). See also Natural Gas Pipelines Negotiated Rate Policies
and Practices; Modification of Negotiated Rate Policy, 104 FERC ]
61,134 (2003), order on reh'g and clarification, 114 FERC ] 61,042,
dismissing reh'g and denying clarification, 114 FERC ] 61,304
(2006).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
20. Producers and industrial customers generally oppose lifting the
price ceiling on a permanent basis, arguing that the Commission must
first develop new data to support such action and that it cannot rely
on the results of the Order No. 637 experiment that terminated five
years ago. Certain producers, however, would countenance a new
experiment conducted by the Commission to gather new data related to
the lifting of the price ceiling. Additionally, certain marketers and
the American Public Gas Association (APGA) argue that the Commission
cannot remove the ceiling unless there is a finding of lack of market
power.
21. In response to the request for comments on whether the
Commission should consider adjusting the capacity release regulations
to foster AMAs, numerous commenters responded that AMAs are beneficial
to the market place and that the Commission should do something to
facilitate their use. A vast majority of the commenters assert that
AMAs provide substantial benefits, including more load responsive use
of gas supply, greater liquidity, increased use of transportation
capacity, cost effective procurement vehicles for LDCs and other end
users, and the enhancement of competition. They state that AMAs also
relieve LDCs from management of their daily gas supply and capacity
needs. Others comment that AMAs benefit all parties involved: The
releasing shipper reduces its costs through use of its capacity
entitlements to facilitate third party sales; the third parties benefit
from receiving a bundled product at an acceptable price; and the asset
manager receives whatever profits are not passed on to the releasing
shipper.
22. In particular, the Marketer Petitioners and other commenters
request that the Commission clarify that the different payments made
between parties in an AMA do not constitute prohibited above maximum
rate transactions or below maximum rate transactions that thus require
posting and bidding. They also request that the Commission revisit its
prohibition on tying to allow the packaging of gas supply contracts and
pipeline or storage capacity, or multiple segments of capacity, as part
of an AMA. Certain commenters also suggest changes to the Commission's
notice and bidding requirements for capacity releases. A number of LDCs
and marketers request that the bidding requirement be eliminated
altogether or that the regulations be revised to eliminate
[[Page 65920]]
bidding for capacity releases made to implement an AMA.
II. Removal of Maximum Rate Ceiling for Short-Term Capacity Release
23. Based upon its review of the petitions, comments and available
data, the Commission proposes to lift the price ceiling for short-term
capacity release transactions of one year or less. The Commission's
capacity release program has created a successful secondary market for
capacity.\28\ Commenters from disparate segments of the natural gas
industry agree that the capacity release program has been beneficial to
the industry in creating a competitive secondary market for natural gas
transportation.\29\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ As the Commission observed in 2005, the ``capacity release
program together with the Commission's policies on segmentation, and
flexible point rights, has been successful in creating a robust
secondary market where pipelines must compete on price.'' Policy for
Selective Discounting by Natural Gas Pipelines, 111 FERC ] 61,309 at
P 39-41) (2005), order on reh'g, 113 FERC ] 61,173 (2005).
\29\ See e.g., PG&E and Southwest Gas Petition at 10 (``There is
reason to believe that the secondary market is more competitive
today than it was six years ago.''); Market Petitioners at 3 (``The
Commission's capacity release program has proven to be a critical
initiative in opening U.S. natural gas markets to competition.'');
AGA Comments at 3 (``The Commission's regulations have permitted the
development of an open and active secondary market for pipeline
capacity that has provided significant benefits to natural gas
consumers.''); INGAA Comments at 12 (``The current market for short-
term transportation capacity is large and highly competitive.'');
and NGSA Comments at 2 (``The basic structure of the Commission's
policies is still providing the benefits intended of transparent,
nondiscriminatory, efficient allocation of capacity.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
24. As the comments point out, shippers and potential shippers are
looking for greater flexibility in the use of capacity. They seek to
better integrate capacity with the underlying gas transactions, and are
looking for more flexible methods of pricing capacity to better reflect
the value of that capacity as revealed by the market price of gas at
different trading points. Pipelines, for example, have been using their
negotiated rate authority to sell their own capacity based on market-
derived basis differentials reflective of the difference in gas prices
between two points. The Commission recently clarified that pipelines
may use such basis differential pricing as a part of negotiated rate
transactions even when those prices exceed maximum tariff rates.\30\
Under the Commission's regulations, releasing shippers also may enter
into capacity release transactions based on basis differentials, but
such releases cannot exceed the maximum rate.\31\ In their comments,
releasing shippers request the ability to release at above the maximum
rate so that they may offer potential buyers rates competitive with
pipeline negotiated rate transactions.\32\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ Natural Gas Pipelines Negotiated Rate Policies and
Practices; Modification of Negotiated Rate Policy, 104 FERC ] 61,134
(2003), order on reh'g and clarification, 114 FERC ] 61,042,
dismissing reh'g and denying clarification, 114 FERC ] 61,304
(2006).
\31\ See Standards for Business Practices for Interstate Natural
Gas Pipelines and for Public Utilities, Order No. 698, 72 FR 38757
(July 16, 2007), FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,251 (June 25, 2007).
\32\ See, e.g., PG&E and Southwest Gas Petition at 10-11.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. As the Commission recognized in Order No. 637,\33\ the
traditional cost-of-service price ceilings in pipeline tariffs, which
are based on average yearly rates, are not well suited to the short-
term capacity release market.\34\ Removal of the price ceiling will
enable releasing shippers to offer competitively-priced alternatives to
the pipelines' negotiated rate offerings. Removal of the ceiling also
permits more efficient utilization of capacity by permitting prices to
rise to market clearing levels, thereby permitting those who place the
highest value on the capacity to obtain it. Removal of the price
ceiling also will provide potential customers with additional
opportunities to acquire capacity. The price ceiling reduces the firm
capacity holders' incentive to release capacity during times of
scarcity, because they cannot obtain the market value of the capacity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ Order No. 637 at 31,271-75.
\34\ While the Commission offered pipelines the opportunity to
propose other types of rate designs, such as seasonal and term-
differentiated rates, only a very few pipelines have sought to make
such rate design changes, although virtually all pipelines have
taken advantage of negotiated rate authority.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
26. Further, the elimination of the price ceiling for short-term
capacity releases will provide more accurate price signals concerning
the market value of pipeline capacity. More accurate price signals will
promote the efficient construction of new capacity by highlighting the
location, frequency, and severity of transportation constraints.
Correct capacity pricing information will also provide transparent
market values that will better enable pipelines and their lenders to
calculate the potential profitability and associated risk of additional
construction designed to alleviate transportation constraints.
27. Moreover, removing the price ceiling on short-term capacity
releases should not harm, and may benefit, the ``primary intended
beneficiaries of the NGA--the `captive' shippers.'' \35\ Those shippers
typically have long-term firm contracts with the pipeline, and
therefore will ``continue to receive whatever benefits the rate
ceilings generally provide,'' while also ``reaping the benefits of
[the] new rule, in the form of higher payments for their releases of
surplus capacity.'' \36\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\35\ INGAA at 33.
\36\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
28. As the court stated in INGAA, the Commission may depart from
cost of service ratemaking upon:
A showing that * * * the goals and purposes of the statute will
be accomplished `through the proposed changes.' To satisfy that
standard, we demanded that the resulting rates be expected to fall
within a `zone of reasonableness, where [they] are neither less than
compensatory nor excessive.' [citation omitted]. While the expected
rates' proximity to cost was a starting point for this inquiry into
reasonableness, [citation omitted], we were quite explicit that
`non-cost factors may legitimate a departure from a rigid cost-based
approach,' [citation omitted]. Finally, we said that FERC must
retain some general oversight over the system, to see if competition
in fact drives rates into the zone of reasonableness `or to check
rates if it does not.' \37\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ Id. at 31.
29. Many of the changes effected in Order Nos. 636 and 637 have
enhanced competition between releasing shippers as well as between
releasing shippers and the pipeline. As discussed below, the data
obtained by the Commission both during the Order No. 637 experiment and
more recently confirms the finding made in Order No. 637 that short-
term release prices are reflective of market prices as revealed by
basis differentials, rather than reflecting the exercise of market
power. Moreover, shippers purchasing capacity will be adequately
protected because the pipeline's firm and interruptible services will
provide just and reasonable recourse rates limiting the ability of
releasing shippers to exercise market power. Finally, the reporting
requirements in Order No. 637 and the Commission's implementation of
the Energy Policy Act of 2005, specifically with respect to market
manipulation, provide the Commission with enhanced ability to monitor
the market and detect and deter abuses.
A. Policies Enhancing Competition
30. In Order No. 636 and, as expanded in Order No. 637, the
Commission instituted a number of policy revisions designed to enhance
competition and improve efficiency across the pipeline grid. These
revisions provide shippers with enhanced market mechanisms that will
help ensure a more competitive market and mitigate the potential for
the exercise of market power.
[[Page 65921]]
31. The Commission required pipelines to permit releasing shippers
to use flexible point rights and to fully segment their pipeline
capacity. Flexible point rights enable shippers to use any points
within their capacity path on a secondary basis, which enables shippers
to compete effectively on release transactions with other shippers.
Segmentation further enhances the ability to compete because it enables
the releasing shipper to retain the portion of the pipeline capacity it
needs while releasing the unneeded portion. Effective segmentation will
make more capacity available and enhance competition. As the Commission
explained in Order No. 637:
The combination of flexible point rights and segmentation
increases the alternatives available to shippers looking for
capacity. In the example,\38\ a shipper in Atlanta looking for
capacity has multiple choices. It can purchase available capacity
from the pipeline. It can obtain capacity from a shipper with firm
delivery rights at Atlanta or from any shipper with delivery point
rights downstream of Atlanta. The ability to segment capacity
enhances options further. The shipper in New York does not have to
forgo deliveries of gas to New York in order to release capacity to
the shipper seeking to deliver gas in Atlanta. The New York shipper
can both sell capacity to the shipper in Atlanta and retain the
right to inject gas downstream of Atlanta to serve its New York
market.\39\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\38\ In the example used in Order No. 636, a shipper holding
firm capacity from a primary receipt point in the Gulf of Mexico to
primary delivery points in New York could release that capacity to a
replacement shipper moving gas from the Gulf to Atlanta while the
New York releasing shipper could inject gas downstream of Atlanta
and use the remainder of the capacity to deliver the gas to New
York.
\39\ Order No. 637 at 31,300.
32. In addition to enhancing competition through expansion of
flexible point rights and segmentation, the Commission in Order No.
637 also required pipelines to provide shippers with scheduling
equal to that provided by the pipeline, so that replacement shippers
can submit a nomination at the first available opportunity after
consummation of the capacity release transaction. The change makes
capacity release more competitive with pipeline services and
increases competition between capacity releasers by enabling
replacement shippers to schedule the use of capacity obtained
through release transactions quickly rather than having to wait
until the next day.
B. Data on Capacity Release Transactions
33. The data accumulated by the Commission during the Order No. 637
experiment, as well as review of more recent data, show that capacity
release prices reflect competitive conditions in the industry. On May
30, 2002, the Commission issued a notice of staff paper presenting data
on capacity release transactions during the experimental period when
the capacity release ceiling price was waived.\40\ The staff paper
provided analysis of capacity release transactions on 34 pipelines
during the 22-month period from March 2000 to December 2001.\41\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\40\ On May 30, 2002, a Staff Paper was posted on the
Commission's Web site presenting, and analyzing data on capacity
release transactions relating to the experimental period when the
rate ceiling on short-term released capacity was waived.
\41\ Many of these release transactions would have occurred
prior to completion of the pipeline's Order No. 637 compliance
proceedings and the implementation of the changes to flexible point
rights, segmentation and scheduling described above.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
34. In brief, the data gathered during the 33-month period show
that without the price ceiling, prices exceeded the maximum rate only
during short time periods and appear to be reflective of competitive
conditions in the industry. The following table shows the distribution
of above ceiling price releases among the pipelines studied.
Table I.--Above Cap Releases by Pipeline
[Releases awarded between March 26, 2000 and December 31, 2001]
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Releases above Releases
max rate % of total quantity above % of total
Pipeline (Number of releases max rate release
transactions) (MMBtu/day) quantity
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Algonquin....................................... 1 0.1 18,453 0.2
ANR Pipeline.................................... 1 0.1 30,000 0.2
CIG............................................. 19 6.5 109,984 4.4
Dominion (CNGT)................................. 21 1.0 65,789 0.7
Columbia Gas.................................... 101 4.4 374,727 2.7
Columbia Gulf................................... ..............
East Tennessee.................................. ..............
El Paso......................................... 135 13.3 631,683 12.5
Florida Gas..................................... 25 1.7 43,526 1.4
Great Lakes..................................... 3 1.3 15,000 0.6
Iroquois........................................ ..............
Kern River...................................... 2 3.9 55,000 2.5
KMI (KNEnergy).................................. 3 1.0 1,409 0.0
Gulf South (Koch)............................... ..............
Midwestern...................................... 1 0.6 50,000 2.3
Mississippi River............................... ..............
Mojave Pipeline Co.............................. 1 2.6 40,000 4.7
Natural Gas Pipeline Co......................... 16 3.2 270,489 2.3
Reliant (Noram)................................. ..............
Northern Border................................. ..............
Northern Natural................................ 12 1.6 23,273 0.5
Northwest Pipeline.............................. 24 1.8 139,850 4.1
Paiute Pipeline................................. ..............
Panhandle Eastern............................... 1 0.4 1,000 0.1
Southern Natural................................ 7 0.3 24,101 0.2
Tennessee Gas................................... 11 0.4 36,421 0.2
TETCO........................................... 122 3.8 645,856 3.3
[[Page 65922]]
Texas Gas....................................... 6 0.5 103,237 1.0
Trailblazer..................................... 3 25.0 15,000 10.0
Transco......................................... 183 3.3 1,540,885 4.1
Transwestern.................................... 11 4.5 64,058 6.5
Trunkline....................................... ..............
Williams........................................ 4 0.4 16,500 0.3
Williston Basin................................. .............. .............. .............. ..............
---------------------------------------------------------------
Total....................................... 713 2.2 4,316,241 2.1
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
35. These data show that during periods without capacity
constraints, prices remained at or below the maximum rate. The staff
paper does identify 713 releases above the ceiling price, representing
an average total capacity release contract volume of 4.3 billion cubic
feet (Bcf) per day. However, the staff paper reflects that these above-
ceiling price releases represented only a small portion of the total
releases on these pipelines, comprising approximately two percent of
total transactions on the pipelines studied for the entire period, and
two percent of gas volumes. Further, above ceiling releases accounted
for no more than six or seven percent of transactions during any given
month of the period. As one would expect, the percentages of releases
occurring above the ceiling increased during peak periods. However,
average release rates were higher by only one cent per MMBtu per day or
five and one-half percent higher than they would have been with the
price ceiling in place. Of the 34 pipelines in the study, 10 reported
no releases above the ceiling price, and 20 pipelines reported fewer
than 25 above-ceiling price releases. The data gathered during this 22-
month period reflects the Commission's expectations and affirms the
Commission's findings in the Order No. 637 proceeding. As the court
stated in INGAA:
The data represented in the graph [] do support the Commission's
view that the capacity release market enjoys considerable
competition. The brief spikes in moments of extreme exigency are
completely consistent with competition, reflecting scarcity rather
than monopoly. * * * [citation omitted] A surge in the price of
candles during a power outage is no evidence of monopoly in the
candle market.\42\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\42\ INGAA at 32.
36. Several commenters argue that the data gathered by the
Commission is too stale to support the instant proposal to remove the
price ceiling on short-term capacity releases. However, these
commenters fail to produce any evidence to support specific concerns
existing today that did not exist during the experimental period.
Moreover, the Commission has gathered additional current data and has
replicated the evidence presented in Order No. 637. The current data
shows that the conditions that existed at the time of Order No. 637 and
during the past experimental period continue in today's marketplace.
37. Figure 1 illustrates the fluctuations in the market value of
transportation service, as shown by the basis differentials between
Louisiana and New York City. This graph compares the daily difference
in gas prices between Louisiana and New York City to Transcontinental
Gas Pipe Line Corporation's maximum interruptible transportation rate,
including fuel retainage, during the 12 months ending July 31, 2007.
This graph shows that for most of the year, the value of transportation
service, as indicated by the basis differentials, is less than the
maximum transportation rate. However, during brief, peak demand
periods, the value of transportation service is measurably greater than
the maximum transportation rate. For example, on February 5, 2007, the
basis differential between Louisiana and New York City was in excess of
$27.00 per MMBtu, while the maximum tariff rate plus the cost of fuel
was approximately $1.08 per MMBtu.\43\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\43\ In Order No. 637, the Commission presented similar data in
figure 6 showing the implicit transportation value between South
Louisiana and Chicago. Order No. 637 at 31,274.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
[[Page 65923]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP26NO07.004
38. Figures 2 and 3 below reflect that a similar pattern of
transportation value is evident in other areas of the country. Focusing
on fluctuations in the market value of transportation service as shown
by basis differentials between Louisiana and Chicago and between the
Permian Basin and the California border, respectively, these figures
show that for most of the year, the value of transportation service is
less than the maximum transportation rate of Natural Gas Pipeline
Company of America and El Paso Natural Gas Company, respectively.
However, similar to figure 1, these figures also reflect that during
brief, peak-demand periods, the value of transportation service is
measurably greater than the maximum transportation rate.
[[Page 65924]]
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP26NO07.005
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP26NO07.006
[[Page 65925]]
39. The data in all three of the above figures reflect similar
market conditions to the data that the Commission relied upon in
lifting the price ceiling for short-term capacity releases in Order No.
637, with the market value of capacity generally below the pipeline's
maximum rate except for relatively brief price spikes.\44\ In affirming
the Commission's actions, the court in INGAA found that the data
presented by the Commission constituted a substantial basis for the
conclusion that a considerable amount of competition existed in the
capacity release market. Further, the INGAA court concluded that the
price spikes reflected in the data were consistent with competition and
that such spikes reflected scarcity rather than monopoly. \45\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\44\ Order No. 637 at 31,273-75.
\45\ INGAA at 32.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
C. Available Pipeline Service Constrains Market Power Abuses
40. The Commission envisions that under the instant proposal the
pipeline's open access transportation maximum tariff rates (recourse
rates) will serve as additional protection against possible abuses of
market power by releasing shippers. The Commission requires pipelines
to sell all their available capacity to shippers willing to pay the
pipeline's maximum recourse rate.\46\ Under their negotiated rate
authority, pipelines are free to negotiate individualized rates with
particular shippers that may be above the maximum tariff rate, subject
to several conditions including the availability of the maximum tariff
rate as a recourse rate for potential firm shippers.\47\ As the
Commission explained in its negotiated rate policy statement, ``[t]he
availability of a recourse service would prevent pipelines from
exercising market power by assuring that the customer can fall back to
traditional cost-based service if the pipeline unilaterally demands
excessive prices or withholds service.'' \48\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\46\ Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 91 FERC ] 61,053 (2002), reh'g
denied, 94 FERC ] 61,097 (2001), petitions for review denied sub
nom., Process Gas Consumers Group v. FERC, 292 F.3d 831, 837 (D.C.
Cir. 2002).
\47\ See, Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking
for Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ] 61,076, reh'g denied, 75 FERC ]
61,024 (1996), petitions for review denied sub nom., Burlington
Resources Oil & Gas Co. v. FERC, 172 F.3d 918 (D.C. Cir. 1998). See
also Natural Gas Pipelines Negotiated Rate Policies and Practices;
Modification of Negotiated Rate Policy, 104 FERC ] 61,134 (2003),
order on reh'g and clarification, 114 FERC ] 61,042, dismissing
reh'g and denying clarification, 114 FERC ] 61,304 (2006).
\48\ Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for
Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ] 61,076 at 61,240 (1996).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
41. The court in INGAA recognized the value of the pipeline's
recourse rate protecting against possible abuses of market power by
releasing shippers stating that,
[i]f holders of firm capacity do not use or sell all of their
entitlement, the pipelines are required to sell the idle capacity as
interruptible service to any taker at no more than the maximum
rate--which is still applicable to the pipelines.\49\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\49\ INGAA at 32.
Removing the price ceiling for short-term capacity release transactions
will enable releasing shippers to offer negotiated rate transactions
similar to those offered by the pipelines. Moreover, the same pipeline
open access service will protect against the possibility that a
releasing shipper will attempt to exercise market power by withholding
capacity. For example, should a releasing shipper attempt to charge a
price above competitive levels, the potential purchaser could seek to
negotiate a more acceptable rate with the pipeline. Even when the
pipeline's firm service is not available, a cost based interruptible
rate is always available as an alternative when a releasing shipper
attempts to withhold capacity.
D. Monitoring
42. Order No. 637 improved the Commission's and the industry's
ability to monitor capacity release transactions by requiring daily
posting of these transactions on pipeline Web sites.\50\ This has
increased the information available to buyers while at the same time
making it easier for the Commission to identify situations in which
shippers are abusing their market power.\51\ Further, the Commission
will entertain complaints and respond to specific allegations of market
power on a case-by-case basis if necessary. Furthermore, the Commission
will direct staff to monitor the capacity release program and, using
all available information, issue a report on the general performance of
the capacity release program, within six months after two years of
experience under the new rules.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\50\ 18 CFR 284.8 (2007).
\51\ Order No. 637 at 31,283; Order No. 637-A at 31,558.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
E. Requests to Expand Market-Based Rate Authority
1. Removal of Price Ceiling for Long-Term Releases
43. Several commenters request that the Commission remove the price
ceiling on long-term capacity releases in addition to eliminating the
price ceiling on short-term capacity releases. The Commission declines
to make such an adjustment to its policies at this time for several
reasons. As discussed above, by lifting the price ceiling for short-
term capacity releases, the Commission seeks to provide releasing
shippers the flexibility to price their capacity in a manner consistent
with the short-term price variations in transportation capacity market
values. This action will ameliorate restrictions on the efficient
allocation of capacity during the short-term periods when demand drives
the value of transportation capacity above the current maximum rate.
44. Limiting the removal of the release ceiling to short-term
transactions will also serve as additional protection for potential
replacement shippers. Such a limit will ensure that a replacement
shipper cannot be locked into a transaction that is not protected by
the maximum rate ceiling for more than one year. The expiration of such
a short-term transaction would give the replacement shipper an
opportunity to explore other options for satisfying its capacity needs.
The replacement shipper could seek to negotiate a different price with
its current releasing shipper or to obtain capacity from another
releasing shipper or directly from the pipeline.\52\ Any transaction in
which the parties want to continue the release past one year would have
to be re-posted for bidding to ensure that the capacity is allocated to
the highest valued use. This bidding process could provide an
opportunity for re-determining the current market value of the
capacity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\52\ Releasing and replacement shippers cannot simply roll over
a short-term release transaction in order to extend the release
beyond one year. The Commission's current regulations do not permit
rollovers or extensions of capacity releases made at less than
maximum rate or for less than 31 days without re-posting and bidding
of that capacity. 18 CFR Section 284.8(h) (2007).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
45. Finally, because any such release of a year or less would have
to be re-posted for bidding upon its expiration, the second release
would be a new release separate from the first release, and thus such a
second release of a year or less would also not be subject to the price
ceiling. The Commission, however, requests comment on whether there
should be any limit on the ability of releasing shippers to make
multiple, consecutive short-term releases not subject to the price
ceiling.
2. Removal of Price Ceiling for Pipeline Short-Term Transactions
46. Pipelines request that the Commission remove the price ceiling
for primary pipeline capacity whether firm
[[Page 65926]]
or interruptible. In sum, they argue that because the transportation of
gas on pipelines has become sufficiently competitive, and because
released capacity competes directly with primary short-term firm,
interruptible transportation and storage services provided by
interstate pipelines, the Commission should lift the rate ceiling on
the entire short-term capacity market, not just on capacity releases.
Further, they assert that because short-term firm and interruptible
services compete directly with capacity release, the same market
liquidity considerations that warrant lifting the ceiling on short-term
releases support lifting the price ceiling in the primary market. The
pipelines assert that the Commission should treat all holders of
capacity equally, whether they are pipelines or releasing shippers.
47. The pipelines also assert that removing the price ceiling only
on short-term capacity releases would bifurcate the single marketplace
for natural gas transportation services. They argue that if prices for
some of the capacity in the marketplace remain subject to a price
ceiling while the price ceiling is removed for other forms of capacity,
then once the capped capacity has been fully utilized, prices for the
uncapped capacity will be higher than they would have been without any
price ceiling at all. They assert that in affirming the Commission's
experiment in removing the price ceiling for short-term capacity
releases, the court in INGAA recognized this economic cost and labeled
it as a ``cost of g