New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations Applicable to Small Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities, 35872-35892 [E7-12553]
Download as PDF
35872
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
Order on Rehearing and Clarification
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
I. Introduction
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
18 CFR Part 292
[Docket No. RM06–10–001; Order No. 688–
A]
New PURPA Section 210(m)
Regulations Applicable to Small Power
Production and Cogeneration Facilities
Issued June 22, 2007.
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule; order on rehearing.
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: In this order on rehearing, the
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
(Commission) denies rehearing on most
major issues decided in Order No. 688,
which amended its regulations
governing small power production and
cogeneration in response to section 1253
of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct
2005), which added section 210(m) to
the Public Utility Regulatory Policies
Act of 1978 (PURPA). The Commission
also clarifies certain aspects of the rule
and adopts some additional filing
requirements.
DATES: Effective Date: The revisions to
our regulations in this order on
rehearing will become effective July 30,
2007.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Susan G. Pollonais (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Markets
and Reliability, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
(202) 502–6011.
Marka Shaw (Technical Information),
Office of Energy Markets and Reliability,
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC
20426, (202) 502–8641.
Samuel Higginbottom (Legal
Information), Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502–8561.
Mason Emnett (Legal Information),
Office of the General Counsel, Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
(202) 502–6540.
Eric Winterbauer (Legal Information),
Office of the General Counsel, Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
(202) 502–8329.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Before
Commissioners: Joseph T. Kelliher,
Chairman; Suedeen G. Kelly, Marc
Spitzer, Philip D. Moeller, and Jon
Wellinghoff.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:48 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
1. On October 20, 2006, the Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission
(Commission) issued Order No. 688,1 in
which the Commission revised its
regulations governing the purchase
requirement for electric energy
produced by qualifying cogeneration
and small power production facilities
(QFs). This rulemaking proceeding was
initiated to implement section 210(m) of
the Public Utility Regulatory Policies
Act of 1978 (PURPA),2 which mandates
termination of the requirement that an
electric utility enter into a new contract
or obligation to purchase electric energy
from QFs 3 if the Commission finds that
the QF has nondiscriminatory access to
one of three categories of markets
defined in section 210(m)(1)(A), (B), or
(C) of PURPA, as amended.
2. As relevant here, section 210(m)
provides for the following:
(i) Termination of the requirement that an
electric utility enter into a new contract or
obligation to purchase electric energy from a
QF after certain specified findings are made
by the Commission;
(ii) Reinstatement of the purchase
requirement upon a showing that the
conditions for terminating the requirement
are no longer met;
(iii) Termination of the requirement that an
electric utility enter into new contracts to sell
electric energy to QFs after certain specified
findings are made by the Commission;
(iv) Reinstatement of the sale requirement
upon a showing that the conditions for
terminating the requirement are no longer
met; and,
(v) Preservation of existing contracts and
obligations to purchase electric energy or
capacity from, or to sell electric energy or
capacity to, a QF.
The Final Rule amended Part 292 of
the Commission’s regulations,
pertaining to electric utilities’ obligation
to purchase electric energy from or sell
electric energy to a QF, to address these
provisions of section 210(m) and also to
provide a process for applying for the
reinstatement of the requirements to
purchase electric energy from or to sell
electric energy to QFs upon a showing
that the conditions for the removal of
those requirements are no longer met.
1 New
PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations
Applicable to Small Power Production and
Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 688, 71 FR 64342
(Nov. 1, 2006), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,233 (2006)
(Final Rule).
2 Section 210(m) was added to PURPA by section
1253 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005).
See Pub. L. 109–58, 1253, 119 Stat. 594, 967 (2005).
3 The requirement that an electric utility enter
into a new contract or obligation to purchase
electric energy from QFs is referred to herein as
either the mandatory purchase obligation or, more
simply, the purchase requirement.
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
3. New § 292.309 of the Commission’s
regulations describes the findings that
the Commission must make to justify
relieving an electric utility’s obligation
to enter into new QF purchase contracts.
If the Commission finds that the QF has
nondiscriminatory access to one of three
types of wholesale markets described in
subparagraphs (A), (B), and (C) of
section 210(m)(1), the requirement that
the electric utility enter into new
contracts or obligations is terminated. In
the Final Rule, the Commission
concluded that the four existing ‘‘Day 2’’
markets 4 satisfy the requirements of
subparagraph (A). The Commission
found that the ‘‘Day 1’’ markets 5 satisfy
some, but not all, of the requirements of
subparagraph (B). Finally, the
Commission found that the markets
operated by the Electric Reliability
Council of Texas (ERCOT) satisfy the
requirements of subparagraph (C). All of
these markets are administered by
regional transmission organizations
(RTOs) or independent system operators
(ISOs).
4. With regard to analyzing whether a
QF has nondiscriminatory access to one
of these markets, the Commission
adopted three rebuttable presumptions.
First, the Final Rule concluded that the
existence of an open access
transmission tariff (OATT), or a
reciprocity tariff filed by a non-public
utility pursuant to the Commission’s
open access regulations,6 justified a
rebuttable presumption that QFs have
nondiscriminatory access to the markets
in the transmission provider’s service
territory. Second, the Commission
adopted a rebuttable presumption that
QFs located within one of the four
existing ‘‘Day 2’’ markets also have
nondiscriminatory access to those
markets. Third, the Commission
concluded that QFs with a net capacity
no greater than 20 MW may not have
nondiscriminatory access to any market,
notwithstanding the availability of
service under an OATT or their location
within a ‘‘Day 2’’ market. The
Commission therefore adopted a
rebuttable presumption that such small
4 The four existing ‘‘Day 2’’ markets are those
auction based day-ahead and real-time markets
operated by the Midwest Independent Transmission
System Operator Corp. (MISO), PJM
Interconnection, LLC (PJM), New York Independent
System Operator, Inc. (NYISO), and ISO New
England, Inc. (ISO–NE).
5 The existing ‘‘Day 1’’ markets are those real-time
markets operated by the California Independent
System Operator Corporation (CAISO) and the
Southwest Power Pool (SPP).
6 18 CFR 35.28(e). An OATT provides
interconnection as well as transmission services on
a nondiscriminatory basis.
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
QFs do not have nondiscriminatory
access to any market.
5. Requests for rehearing and/or
clarification of these rulings, and the
procedure implementing them, were
received from the American Forest and
Paper Association (American Forest &
Paper) and California Cogeneration
Council (CCC), Central Vermont Public
Service Corporation (Central Vermont),
Cogeneration Association of California
and the Energy Producers and Users
Coalition (Cogeneration Association of
California), the Council of Industrial
Boiler Owners (CIBO), Deere &
Company (Deere), Edison Electric
Institute (EEI), Oklahoma Gas and
Electric Company (OG&E), jointly from
the Electricity Consumers Resource
Council (ELCON), the American Iron
and Steel Institute, the American
Chemistry Council, and the Council of
Industrial Boiler Owners (Industrial
Parties), National Rural Electric
Cooperative Association, (NRECA),
Occidental Chemical Corporation
(Occidental), PacifiCorp, and Public
Interest Organizations (PIOs). Southern
California Edison (SCE) and PJM
Interconnection, Inc. (PJM) filed
answers to the requests for rehearing.
ELCON and Cogeneration Association of
California filed answers those answers.7
6. As discussed below, the
Commission generally denies the
requests for rehearing of the Final Rule.
The Commission continues to believe
that the Final Rule appropriately
implements section 210(m) by
identifying what type of markets satisfy
the requirements of sections
210(m)(1)(A), (B), and (C) and the
criteria that will be used to determine
whether a QF has nondiscriminatory
access to one of those markets. We
therefore do not disturb the basic
implementation structure established in
that order. We do, however, grant
clarification regarding certain specific
matters. The Commission addresses
each of these issues in turn.
7 Rule 713(d) of the Commission’s Rules of
Practice and Procedure, 18 CFR 383.713(d),
provides that the Commission will not permit
answers to requests for rehearing. We will,
accordingly, reject SCE and PJM’s answers to the
requests for rehearing. Rule 213(a)(2) of the
Commission’s Rules of Practice and Procedure, 18
CFR 385.213(a)(2), prohibits an answer to an answer
unless otherwise ordered by the decisional
authority. We are not persuaded to accept the
answers of ELCON and Cogeneration Association of
California and will, therefore, reject them. The
alternative motions to reject of ELCON and
Cogeneration Association of California are rejected
as moot.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:48 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
35873
II. Discussion
1. Section 210(m)(1)(A)
A. Three Types of Markets
9. Section 210(m)(1)(A) of PURPA
requires the Commission to terminate an
electric utility’s obligation to purchase
from a QF if the QF has
nondiscriminatory access to (i)
independently administered, auctionbased, day ahead and real time
wholesale markets for the sale of electric
energy; and (ii) wholesale markets for
long-term sales of capacity and electric
energy. In the Final Rule, the
Commission found that the four existing
‘‘Day 2’’ markets, MISO, PJM, ISO–NE
and NYISO, satisfy the first prong of
section 210(m)(1)(A) because the
markets administered by these RTO/
ISOs are, as required by the statute,
independently administered, auctionbased day ahead and real time
wholesale markets for electricity.9 The
Commission further found that the
existence of bilateral long-term contracts
for long-term sales of capacity and
energy in these markets satisfies the
second prong of section 210(m)(1)(A).
Since both of these requirements are
satisfied, the Commission concluded
that a showing of nondiscriminatory
access to any of these ‘‘Day 2’’ markets
would terminate the purchase
requirement.
7. Section 210(m)(1) identifies three
types of markets, nondiscriminatory
access to which will satisfy the findings
the Commission must make to terminate
an electric utility’s purchase
requirement. As the Commission
explained in the Final Rule, the
statutory language of sections
210(m)(1)(A), (B), and (C) requires us to
differentiate among distinct types of
markets when analyzing whether an
electric utility will be relieved of its
purchase obligation. The Commission
must terminate the mandatory purchase
obligation if we find that a QF has
nondiscriminatory access to:
(A) ‘‘independently administered, auctionbased day ahead and real time wholesale
markets for the sale of electric energy’’ and
‘‘wholesale markets for long-term sales of
capacity and electric energy’’;
(B) ‘‘transmission and interconnection
services that are provided by a Commissionapproved regional transmission entity and
administered pursuant to an open access
transmission tariff that affords
nondiscriminatory treatment to all
customers’’ and ‘‘competitive wholesale
markets that provide a meaningful
opportunity to sell capacity, including longterm and short-term sales, and electric
energy, including long-term, short-term and
real-time sales, to buyers other than the
utility to which the [QF] is interconnected’’; 8
or,
(C) ‘‘wholesale markets for the sale of
capacity and electric energy that are, at a
minimum, of comparable competitive quality
as markets described in subparagraphs (A)
and (B).’’
8. In the Final Rule, the Commission
considered the specific criteria set forth
in these statutory provisions and
concluded that certain markets in the
United States satisfied some or all of the
requirements of each. The Commission
rejected proposals to adopt a single
standard for relief, which in effect
would interpret sections 210(m)(1)(A),
(B), and (C) as collectively defining a
single type of market, access to which
would require termination of the
purchase requirement. The Commission
found that the most reasonable
interpretation of section 210(m)(1) is
that Congress, in separately describing
three different types of markets, was
requiring the Commission to
differentiate among each type of market
when determining whether to terminate
the purchase requirement.
8 In determining whether a meaningful
opportunity to sell exists, section 210(m)(1)(B)
directs the Commission to consider, among other
factors, evidence of transactions within the relevant
market.
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Requests for Rehearing
10. No petitioner challenges the
Commission’s determination that the
existing ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISO markets
satisfy the requirements of the first
prong of section 210(m)(1)(A), i.e., that
they are independently administered,
auction-based day ahead and real time
wholesale electricity markets. Requests
for rehearing instead focus on the
second prong, regarding whether a
wholesale market for long-term sales of
capacity and electric energy also exists
in these regions. PIOs argue that the
mere existence of some bilateral longterm contracts does not demonstrate the
existence of a competitive wholesale
market for long-term sales or actual
‘‘meaningful opportunities’’ for QFs to
sell energy or capacity long-term to
multiple buyers. PIOs therefore contend
that the Commission erred in finding
that the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets satisfy the
requirements of section 210(m)(1)(A).
Cogeneration Association of California
agrees that the existence of a ‘‘Day 2’’
9 The Commission stated that any future
determinations of whether a new ‘‘Day 2’’ market
satisfies the requirements of section 210(m)(1)(A)
would be considered on a case-by-case basis, either
in response to an application for termination of the
mandatory purchase obligation or a petition for
declaratory order.
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
35874
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
market does not equate to a long-term
market, arguing that access to a longterm market is essential to provide the
assurance of long-term revenue
necessary to provide incentives for
construction of new resources.
11. American Forest & Paper and CCC
argue that there has never been a time
in the history of the power industry
when some bilateral contracts did not
exist. They contend that there is no
evidentiary basis that shows such
contracts are available to QFs on a
nondiscriminatory basis or that there is
a market for such contracts. They argue
that the word ‘‘market’’ presumes more
than an occasional, isolated transaction.
American Forest & Paper and CCC argue
that in the Final Rule the Commission
not only fails to explain why the
existence of bilateral contracts
constitutes a meaningful competitive
market, but also fails to establish any
standard for what constitutes a ‘‘long
term sale,’’ examine any of the bilateral
contracts it believes exist to determine
if they meet any such standard, or
consider whether bilateral contracts are
in fact available to QFs in any
meaningful sense.
12. Cogeneration Association of
California adds that the insufficiency of
the bilateral markets is also
demonstrated by the lack of meaningful
participation in utility requests for
offers. Cogeneration Association of
California argues that the current
practice of bilateral contracting is not
indicative of a competitive market, nor
is it proof that QFs have a meaningful
opportunity to participate in whatever
markets are there. It argues that there is
significant discrimination against QFs
when they attempt to enter into bilateral
contracts.
13. American Forest & Paper and CCC
also argue that the Final Rule errs as a
matter of law by determining generically
that ‘‘Day 2’’ markets satisfy section
210(m)(1)(A) rather than requiring
utilities to demonstrate, on a case-bycase basis, the factual basis upon which
relief is requested, which they argue is
required by section 210(m)(3). American
Forest & Paper and CCC contend that
the Commission simply presumed
adequate wholesale markets existed in
the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets, rendering the
language of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) of
the statute a nullity by not requiring
applicants to set forth the factual basis
on which relief is requested. American
Forest & Paper and CCC complain that
QFs have been denied the opportunity
to challenge the specific findings after
sufficient notice of the factual claims
being made.
14. American Forest & Paper and CCC
cite Alliant Energy Corporate Services
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
Inc.10 as support for its belief that
section 210(m)(3) requires notice to each
affected QF prior to the Commission
making a determination under section
210(m)(1). American Forest & Paper and
CCC compare the Commission’s generic
treatment of ‘‘Day 2’’ markets with its
case-by-case procedures for the
reinstatement of the obligation, despite
the almost identical statutory language
in sections 210(m)(3) and 210(m)(4).
American Forest & Paper argues that
‘‘regulations cannot alter the statutory
scheme,’’ 11 stating that the procedural
requirements have been inappropriately
interpreted away in the Final Rule.
15. In American Forest & Paper and
CCC’s view, Congressional intent to
encourage QF development supports
interpreting section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) as
requiring the Commission to find, based
on specific evidence, that there is a
meaningfully competitive market prior
to terminating the mandatory purchase
obligation. American Forest & Paper and
CCC note, for example, that EPAct 2005
did not repeal PURPA and provided for
termination of the purchase requirement
only if a very particular demonstration
is made.
16. Industrial Parties similarly argue
that the Commission erred in
categorically finding that ‘‘Day 2’’
markets provide QFs with access to
long-term wholesale markets. Industrial
Parties contend that the Commission
has ignored evidence that establishes
that these markets are in their infancy.
While acknowledging that suppliers
will offer QFs a bilateral contract in the
organized markets, Industrial Parties
argue that the rates and terms and
conditions of such contracts typically
are not truly long-term and are
discriminatory. Industrial Parties state
that the long-term markets that exist are
predominantly for resale—generators
selling to load serving entities that in
many cases have divested generation—
and that these contracts are typically for
a period of 6 to 18 months.
17. Industrial Parties also argue that
the Commission incorrectly assumed
that access to short-term ‘‘Day 2’’
markets is equivalent to a finding of
access to long-term markets under
section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii). Industrial
Parties contend that the Commission
must address the definition of ‘‘longterm,’’ arguing that the Commission
appears to view a market in excess of
one year as long-term. Industrial Parties
contend that a long-term market is a
10 113
FERC ¶ 61,024 (2005).
Forest & Paper Request for Rehearing
at 13 (citing P. Gioso & Sons, Inc. v. Occupational
Safety and Health Review Commission, 115 F.3d
100, 105 (1st Cir. 1997)).
11 American
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
market of several years’ duration or at
least the timeframe for planning a new
generator, which they state is three to
five years for a gas-fired combined cycle
unit. Industrial Parties ask that the
Commission require utility applicants to
present information on the short- and
long-term capacity obligations of loadserving entities in the relevant markets,
their practices for meeting such
obligations, and any barriers to entry
into such markets.
18. Finally, American Forest & Paper
and CCC argue that the Commission’s
interpretation of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii)
violates rules of statutory construction.
Because subparagraph (C) specifically
refers to markets for the sale of capacity
under both subparagraphs (A) and (B),
defining a third type of market that is
‘‘similar’’ to subparagraphs (A) and (B),
American Forest & Paper and CCC argue
it is nonsensical to conclude that the
markets for capacity referenced in
subparagraphs (A)(ii) and (B)(ii) are not
similar as between themselves.
American Forest & Paper and CCC
therefore argue that the Commission
erred by not interpreting subparagraph
(A)(ii) as imposing qualitative
requirements comparable to those
imposed under subparagraph (B)(ii). In
American Forest & Paper and CCC’s
view, otherwise the inclusion of a
requirement that the Commission
review specific ‘‘evidence of
transactions’’ in subparagraph (B)(ii)
would require the Commission to ignore
evidence of transactions when applying
subparagraph (A)(ii), which the
Commission did not do in the Final
Rule.
Commission Determination
19. The Commission denies rehearing
of the determination that the four
existing ‘‘Day 2’’ markets (MISO, PJM,
NYISO, and ISO–NE) satisfy the
requirements of the second prong of
section 210(m)(1)(A). Petitioners on
rehearing essentially argue that the
Commission should have imposed a
standard higher than what the statutory
language literally requires, i.e.,
nondiscriminatory access to ‘‘wholesale
markets for long-term sales of capacity
and electric energy.’’ The Commission
declined to do so in the Final Rule and
we affirm that determination here.
20. The Commission did not simply
assume the existence of long-term
markets in the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets, as some
petitioners argue. Rather, the
Commission found that the existence of
bilateral long-term contracts for longterm sales of capacity and energy is a
sufficient indication of a market. The
Commission continued that it is
reasonable to conclude that the
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
subparagraph (A)(ii) requirement for
long-term markets is met because
bilateral long-term contracts are
available to participants in the
footprints of the MISO, PJM, ISO–NE,
and NYISO. The Commission noted that
long-term contracts were to be expected
in these markets because of the nature
of these markets. In this regard, the
transmission access offered by RTOs
allows suppliers (including QFs) the
opportunity to enter into long-term
bilateral contracts. RTOs have no
incentive to favor one set of suppliers
over others in providing transmission
access. By eliminating pancaked rates,
eliminating problems with internal loop
flows, and improving the reliability of
transmission operations over a broad
multi-utility region, an RTO offers
regional transmission service which
facilitates longer-term contracting
practices. This is because an RTO’s
footprint encompasses many different
wholesale buyers, providing significant
opportunity for a seller to reach many
potential wholesale buyers.
21. In addition, organized markets
operated by an RTO facilitate long-term
bilateral contracts between sellers
(including QFs) and wholesale buyers
by reducing the costs to sellers of
making long-term bilateral supply
commitments. In the event a seller is
unable to produce the energy required
under a bilateral contract (for example,
because of an outage), the seller can
easily acquire replacement energy from
the organized market at a transparent
and competitive price. Even when the
seller is physically capable of producing
its contractually-required energy, the
seller can acquire the energy from the
RTO’s market whenever it is cheaper to
do so. Both of these factors reduce the
cost to a seller of entering into a longterm bilateral contract.12
22. With respect to bilateral long-term
markets in these RTO/ISOs, the
Commission noted that no commenters
argued that long-term contracts do not
exist in these markets or that QFs are
precluded from entering into them with
willing buyers.13 The Commission also
pointed out that electronic quarterly
report (EQR) filings indicate that there
are in fact contracts for long-term sales
of capacity and energy in each of the
‘‘Day 2’’ markets. The Commission
concluded that the existence of these
long-term contracts is a sufficient
indication that long-term wholesale
markets exist in those regions. It is
telling that no petitioner on rehearing
challenges (indeed, several petitioners
concede) that long-term contracts exist
14 The New Oxford English Dictionary Vol. 1 A–
M (1993 ed.).
15 Webster’s New Collegiate Dictionary (1979 ed.).
12 Final
Rule at P 120.
13 Final Rule at P 117–20.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
in the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets. Instead,
petitioners argue that existence of such
contracts does not necessarily indicate
that an adequate market for long-term
energy and capacity exists. Yet the very
fact that buyers and sellers of long-term
energy and capacity have found each
other, evidenced by the contracts they
have entered into, demonstrates that a
market for such products does in fact
exist, which is all that the statute
requires.
23. The thrust of many of the
arguments on rehearing is that the
Commission should have considered
whether these long-term markets were
competitive or as robust as QFs would
like. That is not the standard set forth
by Congress in section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii),
which requires only that a long-term
market is present, not that it be
competitive or that it meet the
subjective preferences of all QFs. As the
Commission noted in the Final Rule,
Congress knew how to impose a more
specific level of review regarding the
quality of the relevant long-term market
since, in contrast to the language it used
in section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii), it expressly
used prescriptive language in section
210(m)(1)(B)(ii).
24. Section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) requires
only that we find access to ‘‘wholesale
markets for long-term sales of capacity
and electric energy.’’ The term ‘‘market’’
is not defined with respect to any
particular number of purchasers or
sellers or the quality of the contracts
available. One definition is ‘‘the action
or business of buying and selling; an
instance of this, a commercial
transaction; a (good or bad) bargain.’’ 14
Another definition is ‘‘a meeting
together of people for the purpose of
trade by private purchase and sales and
usually not by auction.’’ 15 These
standard definitions support the
Commission’s finding that the ability of
QF sellers to reach purchasers and the
existence of long-term contracts for
capacity and energy are sufficient to
determine that ‘‘markets’’ exist for
purposes of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii). In
contrast to section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii),
section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii) requires us to
find access to ‘‘competitive wholesale
markets that provide a meaningful
opportunity to sell capacity, including
long-term and short-term sales, and
electric energy, including long-term,
short term and real-time sales.’’ Under
this statutory directive, the Commission
must not only find that markets exist,
but it must assess the quality of the
markets and find that they are
Jkt 211001
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
35875
‘‘competitive.’’ Congress chose not to
require a finding of ‘‘competitive’’ longterm markets as a condition of invoking
section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) and we have
given reasonable meaning to this
difference in language.16
25. Congress’s decision to establish
different standards in subparagraphs (A)
and (B) makes sense in light of the
ultimate question of whether a QF has
nondiscriminatory access to potential
purchasers other than the host utility,
sufficient to justify terminating the
purchase requirement, which is the
overarching theme of section 210(m)(1).
In the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets, which were in
existence when EPAct 2005 was enacted
and of which Congress was aware when
it was considering PURPA reform,
energy sold under bilateral long-term
contracts as well as in the competitive
day-ahead and real-time energy markets
is simply scheduled as a delivery to the
RTO and ISO grid. These market
conditions make it possible for parties
to enter into long-term contracts with
confidence that electric energy sold
pursuant to these contracts will be
delivered. It is reasonable to conclude,
therefore, that Congress considered the
criteria specified for long-term contracts
in section 210(m)(1)(B) unnecessary for
section 210(m)(1)(A). This explains the
distinctions embedded in the standards
set forth in sections 210(m)(1)(A) and
210(m)(1)(B).
26. It is true, as petitioners point out,
that in some ‘‘Day 2’’ markets there is
no formalized market for long-term sales
of energy and capacity. It may also be
true that such long-term markets are
nascent and that the sales that do occur
are predominantly to load serving
entities for resale. All that is required by
section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii), however, is that
there be a market, not that it has
particular market attributes desired by
petitioners. Petitioners have offered no
reasonable alternative to our
interpretation of section 210(m)(1).
27. Petitioners are correct to point out
that the Commission did not expressly
define what length of contract it
considered ‘‘long-term’’ within the
meaning of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii). The
Commission explained, however, that it
was relying on EQR data to find that
long-term contracts existed in the ‘‘Day
2’’ markets. Long-term contracts are
defined for EQR purposes as having a
16 Some petitioners argue that the Commission’s
reliance on EQR reports to find the existence of a
long-term market in ‘‘Day 2’’ regions is contradicted
by Congress’ reference to ‘‘evidence of transactions’’
in section 210(m)(1)(B), but not in section
210(m)(1)(A). The requirement in subparagraph (B)
for evidence of transactions does not bar the use of
such evidence in subparagraph (A), but merely
indicates that such evidence is not required under
subparagraph (A).
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
35876
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
term of one year or more and, thus, the
Commission’s findings regarding longterm contracts in the Final Rule
incorporated that definition. While
some petitioners argue that a longerterm should have been used, we
continue to believe that contracts of a
year or more are sufficiently long-term
to meet the statutory requirement that
there be ‘‘wholesale markets for longterm sales of capacity and energy’’
within the meaning of section
210(m)(1)(A)(ii).17
28. We note that the Commission has
initiated a proceeding to explore ways
to improve the operation of wholesale
organized electric markets administered
by RTOs and ISOs, including actions the
Commission might take to further
improve opportunities for long-term
contracting in RTO and ISO regions.18
While we disagree with petitioners who
argue that QFs above 20 MW do not
have access to long-term contracting
opportunities in organized markets, or
that section 210(m)(1)(A) requires us to
find ‘‘competitive’’ or ‘‘robust’’
contracting opportunities, we are taking
steps to facilitate additional
opportunities for long-term contracting.
29. The Commission also rejects
arguments that it may not make generic
findings in this rulemaking as to the
‘‘Day 2’’ markets satisfying the
requirements of section 210(m)(1)(A).
The Commission has broad discretion to
adopt generic policy or make generic
findings through the rulemaking process
rather than case-by-case adjudications.19
Establishing generic findings in this
rulemaking provides all parties,
including electric utilities and QFs
alike, a reasonable chance to be heard
on common issues that arise in various
17 Although the statute contrasts real-time, dayahead, and long-term wholesale sales, it provides
no definition of those categories of transactions.
Nevertheless, the terms real-time and day-ahead
markets were well known with respect to ISOs and
RTOs at the time EPAct 2005 was enacted and
definitions of these markets were well understood,
i.e., Congress knew the meaning the terms as used
with respect to ISOs and RTOs existing at the time
of enactment of EPAct 2005. Additionally, the
Commission at the time of enactment of EPAct 2005
had for years defined long-term contracts under the
OATT as one year or longer. Similarly, the
Commission has treated power sales with a contract
term of greater than one year to be ‘‘long-term’’ for
reporting purposes. See, e.g., Revised Public Utility
Filing Requirements, Order No. 2001, 67 FR 31043,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,127 (2002), Order No.
2001–A, 100 FERC ¶ 61,074, reconsideration and
clarification denied, Order No. 2001–B, 100 FERC
¶ 61,342 (2002). We thus believe it is reasonable to
use the convention of treating contracts of a year
or more as ‘‘long-term’’ consistent with our
longstanding practice.
18 Wholesale Competition in Regions with
Organized Electric Markets, 119 FERC ¶ 61,306.
19 Securities and Exchange Comm’n v. Chenery,
332 U.S. 194, 202–03, reh’g denied, 332 U.S. 747
(1947).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
market structures and involving classes
of QFs. Indeed, no party has sought
rehearing of the Commission’s
conclusion that the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets
satisfy the first prong of section
210(m)(1)(A). It is just as appropriate for
the Commission to find generically, in
this rulemaking, that long-term markets
exist in the ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISOs as it is
to find that those RTO/ISOs operate
independently administered, auctionbased day ahead and real time
wholesale markets within the meaning
of section 210(m)(1)(A)(i).
30. These generic findings do not
violate the requirements of section
210(m)(3), as some petitioners argue.
Under section 210(m)(1), the
Commission must terminate the
purchase requirement if it makes certain
findings regarding nondiscriminatory
access to specified markets. That
provision of the statute does not specify
the particular procedural mechanism
the Commission must use in making
those findings and, thus, the
Commission has discretion to act
through a rulemaking, case-by-case
determinations, or some combination
thereof. Section 210(m)(3) does not, as
the petitioners appear to assume,
require the Commission to await an
application from an electric utility in
order to make any of the particular
findings specified in section 210(m)(1).
While the Commission made certain
generic findings in the Final Rule, it
also required electric utilities (including
those in the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets) that seek
relief from the obligation to enter into
new contracts or obligations with QFs to
file an application pursuant to
regulations implementing section
210(m)(3).20 Thus, the Commission has
incorporated the application process
into its implementing regulations,
combining the application procedures
with generic findings and rebuttable
presumptions to streamline the
Commission’s review. The resulting
structure is fully consistent with the
requirements of both sections 210(m)(1)
and 210(m)(3).21
2. Section 210(m)(1)(B)
31. Section 210(m)(1)(B) requires
termination of the purchase obligation if
a QF has nondiscriminatory access to (i)
transmission and interconnection
services provided by a Commission20 Final
Rule at P 102.
comparative structures of sections
210(m)(3) and 210(m)(4) do not support a different
outcome. Section 210(m)(4) specifies the procedural
requirements for reinstating the purchase
requirement after the Commission has entered an
order terminating that requirement and, thus, does
not govern the Commission’s initial procedures for
acting to terminate the requirement.
21 The
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
approved regional transmission entity
pursuant to an open access tariff and (ii)
competitive wholesale markets
providing a meaningful opportunity to
sell long-term and short-term capacity
and electricity to buyers other than the
interconnecting electric utility. The
Commission concluded in the Final
Rule that the CAISO and SPP are
regional transmission entities within the
meaning of the first prong of section
210(m)(1)(B), but made no findings as to
the second prong for any market,
including those operated by CAISO and
SPP. The Commission also stated that
any future determinations of what
transmission providers qualify as a
regional transmission entity within the
meaning of the first prong will be made
on a case-by-case basis. The
Commission provided examples of
factors it may consider in making that
determination, such as sufficient
regional scope or configuration of the
multiple discrete transmission systems
the regional transmission entity
controls.
Requests for Rehearing
32. Occidental argues that the
Commission erred in reserving the
discretion to deem an entity a
‘‘Commission-approved regional
transmission entity’’ in the context of a
section 210(m) proceeding. Because
section 210(m)(1)(B)(i) refers to a
‘‘Commission-approved’’ entity,
Occidental argues that a transmission
provider must have been deemed by the
Commission to be a ‘‘regional
transmission entity’’ prior to the filing
of an application for relief from the
purchase requirement.
33. PacifiCorp argues that evidence of
robust bilateral markets or actual sales
by a QF to wholesale non-PURPA
purchasers should be considered when
the Commission determines whether
QFs have the requisite ‘‘meaningful
opportunity’’ to sell capacity and energy
to other buyers within the meaning of
section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii). PacifiCorp
offers factual examples of QF plans to
participate in wholesale markets,
depending on market prices, although it
acknowledges that the examples it used
are extreme and did not materialize.
PacifiCorp asks the Commission to
establish a rebuttable presumption that
evidence of a robust bilateral market
featuring liquid trading points, or actual
sales by QFs, should be adopted for
purposes of implementing section
210(m)(1)(B)(ii). Alternatively,
PacifiCorp asks the Commission to
provide further guidance as to how the
standards of that section will be
applied.
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
34. With regard to the SPP market,
OG&E argues that the Commission erred
in declining to find that utilities
operating in SPP also satisfy the second
prong of section 210(m)(1)(B) or to
provide guidance with respect to the
information required for utilities to
make such a showing. OG&E argues that
its comments on the NOPR adequately
demonstrated that QFs have
nondiscriminatory access to competitive
markets within SPP. If the evidence it
submitted was insufficient, OG&E
claims the Commission erred by failing
to provide guidance as to what type of
information would satisfy the
Commission’s requirements. OG&E
contends that such guidance would
reduce the costs and burdens associated
with preparing an application under
section 210(m).
35. With regard to the CAISO market,
Cogeneration Association of California
argues that the lack of new construction
in California, despite a clear supply
shortage, is evidence that competitive
long-term markets do not exist in that
region. Cogeneration Association of
California also argues that competitive
markets must have price transparency,
including both pricing terms and nonprice terms, contending that there is
virtually no disclosure to any market
participant of prices secured or
approved for capacity or energy
purchased by utilities. Industrial Parties
point to other characteristics of the
California market that, in their view,
would preclude a finding of access to
sufficiently competitive markets, such
as exit fees, the lack of direct access,
and the dominance of utility generation
in an otherwise thinly traded market.
Commission Determination
36. We disagree with Occidental’s
assertion that a transmission entity must
have been deemed by the Commission
to be a ‘‘regional transmission entity’’
prior to the filing of an application for
relief from the purchase requirement. As
we explained in the Final Rule, section
210 does not define regional
transmission entity and, therefore, the
Commission has discretion in
interpreting that term. At the time of
enactment of section 210(m), Congress
was aware of the existence of
Commission-approved RTOs and ISOs
with varying degrees of regional scope
(some spanning many states and some
covering only large individual states), as
well as the continuing voluntary
development of various types of
transmission organizations.22 It is
22 Indeed Congress, in EPAct 2005 incorporated
into the Federal Power Act (FPA) definitions of
RTO and ISO, with the RTO definition specifically
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
reasonable to conclude that Congress, by
using the generic term ‘‘regional
transmission entity’’ in section
210(m)(1)(B)(i), intended to leave it to
the Commission’s discretion to
determine on a case-be-case basis
whether or not an entity is regional
within the meaning of the statute.23
37. We also deny rehearing of the
decision not to find in the context of
this rulemaking that the SPP market
satisfies the second prong of section
210(m)(1)(B). While OG&E claims to
have provided in its initial comments
evidence demonstrating the quality of
the SPP market,24 what OG&E provided
was little more than cursory comments
and a description of bidding procedures
that are being adopted in Oklahoma.
Section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii) requires a
showing of ‘‘competitive wholesale
markets that provide a meaningful
opportunity to sell capacity, including
long-term and short-term sales, and
electric energy, including long-term,
short-term and real-time sales, to buyers
other than the utility to which the
qualifying facility is interconnected.’’
This provision also provides that ‘‘[i]n
determining whether a meaningful
opportunity to sell exists the
Commission shall consider, among
other factors, evidence of transactions
within the relevant market.’’ We do not
find OG&E’s cursory submission
sufficient to meet the statutory
requirements. Moreover OG&E did not
include any evidence of transactions in
the SPP market. There was, and
continues to be, an insufficient record in
this proceeding to find that the SPP
market satisfies the second prong of
section 210(m)(1)(B).
38. With regard to OG&E’s and
PacifiCorp’s requests for further
guidance, we believe that the statutory
language requiring that a QF have a
meaningful opportunity to sell capacity
and energy to buyers other than the
interconnected utility means an actual,
and not just theoretical, opportunity.
recognizing that such an entity must be of sufficient
‘‘regional’’ scope, whereas the ISO definition does
not contain a sufficient regional scope element.
Pub. L. 109–58, 1291, 119 Stat. 594, 984 (2005)
(codified at 16 U.S.C. 796(27), (28)). Cf. Pub. L. 109–
58, 1286, 119 Stat. 594, 981 (2005) (adding section
206(a)(2) to the FPA, allowing Commission to order
refunds for certain sales in ‘‘organized’’ markets).
23 Congress in section 210(m) did not use the term
‘‘regional transmission organization’’ and thus
presumably did not intend to limit a ‘‘regional
transmission entity’’ to the regional scope
requirements of Order No. 2000. Regional
Transmission Organizations, Order No. 2000, 65 FR
809 (Jan. 6, 2000), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089
(1999), order on reh’g, Order No. 2000–A, 65 FR
12088 (Mar. 8, 2000), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,092
(2000), dismissed sub nom. Pub. Util. Dist. No. 1 of
Snohomish County, Washington v. FERC, 272 F.3d
607 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
24 OG&E Comments at 4–6.
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
35877
Concrete evidence of transactions would
further that finding, as the statutory
language implies. To the extent such
evidence is not available, we would
expect at a minimum a petitioning
electric utility to explain any lack of
evidence of transactions and to provide
a reasoned explanation of how the
Commission could find that a
meaningful opportunity to sell to buyers
other than the interconnected utility
exists in the absence of a history of
transactions.25 PacifiCorp’s evidence of
QF proposals that never reached fruition
does not provide an adequate basis for
the Commission to make any
presumptions regarding whether
particular markets satisfy the
requirements of section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii).
We continue to believe that it is best to
address on a case-by-case basis whether
non-RTO/ISOs and RTO/ISOs that do
not have both auction-based real-time
and day-ahead markets satisfy those
statutory requirements.26
39. The claims of Cogeneration
Association of California and the
Industrial Parties regarding the lack of a
sufficiently competitive market in
California can be addressed in any
individual cases concerning California.
We note that the CAISO has been found
only to satisfy section 210(m)(1)(B)(i)
and that a separate finding of
‘‘competitive wholesale markets’’ is
required under section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii).
Thus, if a California utility makes a
filing pursuant to section 210(m)(3) and
§ 292.310 of the Commission’s
regulations, and claims that it satisfies
the section 210(m)(1)(B) criteria for
relief from the purchase obligation, the
issue of whether ‘‘competitive
wholesale markets’’ exist will be an
issue in that proceeding and the burden
will be on the applicant to make the
required demonstration.27
3. A Single Standard of Relief
40. As explained above, the
Commission concluded in the Final
Rule that the most reasonable
interpretation of section 210(m)(1) is
that Congress, in setting forth three
discrete tests for three different types of
markets, was directing the Commission
to differentiate among three different
25 The Commission is aware that certain types of
evidence of transactions may contain information
that an electric utility considers to be confidential.
If information is considered confidential by the
electric utility, procedures exist to maintain its
confidentiality.
26 Final Rule at P 145.
27 The Commission also left open the option of
California utilities seeking a determination that the
California market satisfies section 210(m)(1)(A) by
filing requests for declaratory orders, after there is
a functioning ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISO in California. Final
Rule at P 157.
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
35878
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
markets, access to which would require
termination of the purchase requirement
provided such access is available on a
nondiscriminatory basis. A number of
petitioners had advocated a different
interpretation of section 210(m)(1),
arguing that subparagraphs (A), (B), and
(C), when read together, establish a
single standard for relief from the
purchase requirement. In their view,
these separate provisions together
require electric utilities to demonstrate
that a QF would remain economically
viable or would otherwise have access
to the technical equivalent of the
purchase requirement in order to
terminate the purchase requirement.
The Commission rejected that view by
interpreting section 210(m)(1) as
establishing different standards for each
of the three types of markets identified
in subparagraphs (A), (B), and (C).
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
Requests for Rehearing
41. American Forest & Paper and CCC
again challenge the Commission’s
determination that the three standards
of relief described in section 210(m)(1)
were intended to be different in terms
of the organization and competitiveness
of the relevant market or the evidentiary
showings required for each. They argue
that EPAct 2005 did not repeal PURPA
or the Commission’s obligation to
encourage QF development and,
therefore, the Commission’s
interpretation of section 210(m)(1) is
unreasonable. American Forest & Paper
and CCC suggest that section
210(m)(1)(C) clearly requires markets
under subparagraphs (A), (B) and (C) to
be of similar competitive quality since
markets that satisfy subparagraph (C)
must be ‘‘similar’’ to those described in
subparagraphs (A) and (B). American
Forest & Paper and CCC conclude that
the Commission has adopted an
unreasonable statutory construction by
interpreting section 210(m)(1) as
referring to three distinct types of
markets.
Commission Determination
42. The Commission denies requests
for rehearing of the determination not to
adopt a single test to evaluate whether
the requirements of section 210(m)(1)
are met. We continue to believe, as we
found in the Final Rule, that the most
reasonable interpretation of section
210(m)(1) is that Congress, in setting
forth discrete tests for three different
types of markets, was requiring the
Commission to differentiate among
these markets and the differing
circumstances they present in
determining whether a utility is relieved
of the purchase requirement. As
discussed above, this interpretation is
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
supported by the different language
Congress used in subparagraphs (A) and
(B) and the consequent need to make
meaningful distinctions in the explicit
statutory language Congress used.
Otherwise, subparagraphs (A) and (B)
presumably would have been collapsed
by Congress into one test.
43. We agree the reference in section
210(m)(1)(C) to markets that are of
‘‘comparable competitive quality as
markets described in subparagraphs (A)
and (B)’’ indicates Congress’ belief that
those two types of markets share a
certain set of competitive qualities. It
does not follow, however, that the
Commission should disregard the
specific statutory tests in each of those
subparagraphs when applying section
210(m)(1). The structure of section
210(m)(1), which separately describes
different types of markets, makes clear
that Congress was establishing a
particular set of tests for the
Commission to apply. In the Final Rule,
the Commission adopted the most
reasonable interpretation of
subparagraph (C)—that Congress
believed the two types of markets
identified in subparagraphs (A) and (B),
while distinct between themselves,
contain certain competitive qualities
that justify termination of the purchase
requirement for any QF with
nondiscriminatory access to those
markets. Subparagraph (C) directs the
Commission to consider these
competitive qualities when analyzing
whether there are other markets that,
while not meeting the specific
requirements of subparagraphs (A) and
(B), are sufficiently competitive to
justify termination of the purchase
requirement.
44. The fact that the markets
identified in subparagraphs (A) and (B)
contain certain competitive qualities
does not mean that they are the same
type of market, or that a single test must
be adopted for determining whether a
particular market satisfies the
requirements of a particular
subparagraph. Such an interpretation
would undermine Congress’s decision
to separately identify the two types of
markets that it believes are sufficiently
competitive to justify termination of the
purchase requirement. It would also
conflict with the particular
determinations to be made under each
of the subparagraphs. Subparagraph (A)
explicitly refers to both ‘‘day ahead and
real time’’ (i.e., ‘‘Day 2’’) organized
markets. RTO/ISO day-ahead and real
time markets are operated pursuant to
Commission tariffs containing market
rules and market mitigation aimed at
preventing exercises of market power. It
is reasonable to conclude that Congress
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
assumed these markets to be sufficiently
competitive, in combination with
markets for long-term contracts, to
justify termination of the mandatory
purchase obligation.
45. As we noted in the Final Rule,
‘‘Day 2’’ markets are generally
recognized as providing greater
opportunities for QFs and other
independent generators to make sales to
a large number of buyers than other
markets because the existence of dayahead and real-time energy markets
allows all competing generators to
submit bids to participate on a
nondiscriminatory basis in a market
from which many buyers over a large
area make purchases. While the ‘‘Day 1’’
markets also provide opportunities for
independent generators to compete, the
markets are more limited. It is therefore
not surprising that the factual showing
required under section 210(m)(1)(B) is
more difficult relative to section
210(m)(1)(A), which enjoys the benefit
of the ‘‘Day 2’’ market structures. These
different standards support, rather than
undermine, the Commission’s
interpretation that subparagraphs (A)
and (B) separately identify the particular
markets that Congress has deemed
sufficiently competitive to justify
termination of the purchase
requirement.
46. The Commission’s task under
section 210(m)(1)(C) is, therefore, to
determine the set of competitive
qualities that are shared by markets
satisfying the requirements of
subparagraphs (A) and (B). Recognizing
this task, the Commission declined in
the Final Rule to adopt any bright line
tests when applying subparagraph (C).
Simply put, the common objective of
subparagraphs (A) and (B), and therefore
subparagraph (C), is the identification of
a wholesale marketplace where QFs
have alternatives to their local utility to
sell their electric energy. We believe the
three-tiered structure of section
210(m)(1) indicates a finding by
Congress that two particular market
designs provide those alternatives,
while directing the Commission to
consider whether other market designs
might as well.
47. Congress could have stated a
broad, general finding to be made by the
Commission such as ‘‘workably
competitive markets.’’ Instead, Congress
tailored subparagraphs (A) and (B) to
establish criteria specific to each market
design that, in its view, provide
sufficient sales alternatives for QFs.
Under these circumstances, we believe
it appropriate to use the market designs
identified in subparagraphs (A) and (B)
as guides when analyzing whether an
alternative market design satisfies the
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
requirements of subparagraph (C). For
example, the Commission found in the
Final Rule that the markets in ERCOT
satisfy the statutory requirements of
subparagraph (C) because they are of
comparable quality to those described in
subparagraph (A). We continue to
believe that finding is appropriate and
note that no petitioner challenges it on
rehearing.
48. Finally, while it is true that EPAct
2005 did not repeal PURPA or the
Commission’s obligation to encourage
QF development, enactment of section
210(m) of PURPA clearly changed the
rights of QFs under PURPA. The
Commission has no discretion other
than to terminate the purchase
requirement if it finds that a QF has
nondiscriminatory access to any of the
markets described in section
210(m)(1)(A), (B) or (C). It would be
inappropriate for the Commission to
ignore this mandate by implementing
section 210(m)(1) in a way that
undermines the specific standards of
relief Congress chose to establish in the
statute.
B. Nondiscriminatory Access to a
Market
49. The Commission also must
determine that a QF has
nondiscriminatory access to a PURPA
section 210(m)(1) market in order to
terminate the purchase requirement. In
the Final Rule, the Commission adopted
several presumptions to be used in
determining whether access to a
particular market is available on a
nondiscriminatory basis in order to
streamline processing of applications for
termination of the purchase
requirement.
50. First, the Final Rule found that a
QF’s eligibility for service under an
OATT, or a reciprocity tariff filed by a
non-public utility, creates a rebuttable
presumption that the QF has
nondiscriminatory access to the relevant
market. Second, the Commission
adopted a rebuttable presumption that
QFs interconnected with electric utility
members of a ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISO have
nondiscriminatory access to the ‘‘Day 2’’
market. Finally, regardless of available
transfer capability (ATC) under an
OATT or location within a ‘‘Day 2’’
market, the Final Rule establishes an
additional rebuttable presumption that
QFs with a net capacity no greater than
20 MW do not have nondiscriminatory
access to wholesale markets.
51. These rebuttable presumptions
were designed to work together to
facilitate prompt Commission review of
requests to terminate the purchase
requirement within the 90-day time
frame mandated in the statute. Various
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
petitioners challenge the adoption of
these presumptions on rehearing, which
we address below.
1. The OATT
52. The Commission first established
a rebuttable presumption that a QF has
nondiscriminatory access to a market if
it is eligible for service under a
Commission-approved OATT, or
Commission-filed reciprocity tariff, and
Commission-approved interconnection
rules.28 If the Commission determines
that a particular market meets the
criteria of section 210(m)(1)(A), (B), or
(C), and a QF in that market is eligible
for service under an OATT or
reciprocity tariff, a QF may seek to rebut
the presumption of access to the market
by providing specific and credible
evidence that the QF does not have
nondiscriminatory access due to
operational characteristics or
transmission constraints. If the QF is
unable to make this demonstration, the
purchase requirement will be
terminated.
53. In the Final Rule, the Commission
determined that only issues other than
issues related to the provision of open
access transmission under the OATT
would be considered when analyzing
whether the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access to markets has
been rebutted. The Commission rejected
requests to allow a QF to litigate open
access implementation issues in the
context of these 90-day applications,
concluding that complaint proceedings
are the appropriate forum for such
disputes. The Commission also rejected
arguments that it is unreasonable to rely
on a presumption that a Commissionapproved OATT provides
nondiscriminatory access to markets in
light of the then-pending NOPR in the
OATT reform rulemaking, Docket Nos.
RM05–17, et al., in which reforms to the
pro forma OATT had been proposed.
Requests for Rehearing
54. Occidental challenges the
Commission’s reliance on an OATT to
create a rebuttable presumption that
QFs have nondiscriminatory access to
the relevant wholesale markets.
Occidental argues that the
Commission’s actions in the OATT
reform rulemaking have demonstrated
that, notwithstanding the existence of
an OATT, there remain continuing
opportunities for undue discrimination
by transmission entities. Occidental
contends that the Commission’s
statement in the Final Rule that it had
28 Transmission providers are required to provide
interconnection as well as transmission services on
a nondiscriminatory basis under their OATTs.
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
35879
not found actual discrimination in the
OATT reform rulemaking is inconsistent
with findings in the OATT reform
NOPR that deficiencies in the OATT
needed to be addressed. In Occidental’s
view, the Commission’s determination
in the OATT reform NOPR that there are
remaining opportunities for undue
discrimination bear directly on the
finding that the Commission must make
under section 210(m) that a utility is
administering its OATT in a
nondiscriminatory manner.
55. Occidental argues that the
Commission’s determination that only
issues not related to the provision of
open access transmission under the
OATT may be raised to rebut the
presumption of nondiscriminatory
access is inconsistent with the statutory
language of section 210(m) and is a
violation of due process. Industrial
Parties assert that the Commission must
consider evidence of discrimination
when analyzing whether the
presumption has been rebutted. Failure
to do so would, in their view, violate the
Commission’s statutory obligation to
eradicate discrimination.
56. Occidental further argues that the
Commission should clarify that QFs
under section 210(m)(1)(B) and (C) have
the same opportunity to rebut the
presumption of nondiscriminatory
access as QFs under section
210(m)(1)(A). Occidental notes that the
Commission lists several factors in the
Final Rule as a possible rebuttal to a
finding of nondiscriminatory access to
the markets set forth in subparagraph
(A), but that it is not clear if the factors
are also relevant to the question of
whether the purchase obligation should
be terminated under subparagraphs (B)
and (C). If the Commission does not
grant clarification, Occidental requests
rehearing on this issue.
57. Cogeneration Association of
California argues that existence of an
OATT is insufficient to guarantee
nondiscriminatory access since it may
not provide physical transmission
rights. Because QFs generate electricity
as a necessary by-product of their
service to their thermal hosts,
Cogeneration Association of California
contends that a cogenerator must have
a physical location to deliver the
electricity. Cogeneration Association of
California argues that this requires
physical transmission rights that
recognize the operating requirements of
cogeneration operations. In its view, the
lack of physical delivery rights places a
cogeneration QF in the untenable
situation of either ceasing operation or
violating ISO tariff and scheduling
protocols, thereby incurring penalties or
sanctions. Cogeneration Association of
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
35880
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
California goes on to illustrate its
concern using the California market
redesign effort as an example. Because
the congestion revenue rights are
allocated first to load-serving entities,
and the remainder are auctioned to
other market participants, Cogeneration
Association of California fears that
existing QFs would be unable to hedge
congestion and that new projects would
be unable to obtain long-term rights
necessary to support long-term contacts,
a prerequisite for financing.
58. Occidental adds that, if the
Commission does not reject the OATT
presumption on rehearing, it should
require applicants to submit at a
minimum additional information such
as clear and specific definitions and
descriptions of each real-time, shortand long-term market the utility claims
in its section 210(m) application that the
QF is able to access on a
nondiscriminatory basis.
59. Multiple petitioners argue that the
Commission erred by establishing any
form of rebuttable presumption.
Industrial Parties contend that the
Administrative Procedure Act requires
that the applicant for relief—in this case
an electric utility—has the burden of
proof.29 Industrial Parties argue that an
agency may not use a presumption to
shift the burden of proof if the result is
not in keeping with the statutory
purpose and, in their view, it runs
counter to section 210(m) to impose on
QFs the burden to prove a lack of
nondiscriminatory access to markets
since the relevant information
concerning transmission and access to
markets is most likely in the possession
of the utility rather than the QF.
60. PIOs argues that creating
rebuttable presumptions that electric
utilities meet section 210(m)
requirements is contrary to the plain
language of section 210(m)(3). PIOs
argues that, when a utility seeks relief
from the mandatory purchase
obligation, the Commission is required
by section 210(m)(3) to consider
evidence of the assertion that the
required access and markets are actually
available to QFs in the utility’s service
territory, including a utility in an RTO.
In PIOs’ view, the Commission is not
authorized to permit utilities to escape
the obligation to set forth facts that
demonstrate that the conditions
provided in section 210(m)(1)(A), (B) or
(C) have been met for the QFs in its
territory.
61. American Forest & Paper and CCC
agree, citing NICOR Exploration Co. v.
FERC 30 for the proposition that the
Commission incorrectly shifts the
burden of proof away from electric
utilities through adoption of rebuttable
presumptions. American Forest & Paper
and CCC state that NICOR found that
the Commission erred by shifting the
burden for a natural gas producer to
prove that an area rate clause authorized
incentive based rates.31 American Forest
& Paper and CCC argue that that
situation is directly analogous to the
issue in this proceeding, where the
Commission has relieved electric
utilities of proving that QFs have nondiscriminatory access to wholesale
markets and, instead, forced QFs to
prove the absence of such access.
29 Industrial Parties Request for Rehearing at 7
(citing Hi-Tech Furnace Sys. v. FCC, 224 F. 3d 781
(D.C. Cir. 2000); Pub. Serv. Comm’n of New York
v. FERC, 866 F.2d 487 (D.C. Cir. 1989)).
30 NICOR Exploration Co. v. FERC, 50 F.3d 1341
(5th Cir. 1995) (NICOR).
31 American Forest & Paper and CCC Request for
Rehearing at 25.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
Commission Determination
62. The Commission denies rehearing
of the adoption of a rebuttable
presumption that eligibility for service
under a Commission-approved OATT,
or Commission-filed reciprocity tariff,
provides nondiscriminatory access to
the market. We first address arguments
against the use of any form of rebuttable
presumption and then turn to arguments
against relying on the OATT in
particular.
63. The Commission denies rehearing
regarding the use of rebuttable
presumptions in processing requests to
terminate the purchase requirement. As
discussed in paragraph 30 above, under
the plain language of section 210(m)(1),
it is the Commission’s responsibility to
find that there is nondiscriminatory
access to certain specified markets prior
to terminating the purchase
requirement. The use of rebuttable
presumptions serves to identify, in
advance, the Commission’s preliminary
analysis, subject to future evidentiary
submissions, thereby streamlining the
application review process. The
Commission believes this will facilitate
prompt processing of applications under
section 210(m), which is required by
section 210(m)(3), and ultimately
benefit QFs and electric utilities alike by
providing advance notice of how the
Commission will consider certain
issues. Abandoning the use of rebuttable
presumptions, as some petitioners
advocate, would unduly complicate the
application process and impair the
Commission’s ability to act within the
90-day timeframe required by section
210(m)(3). Moreover, these rebuttable
presumptions were not created in a
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
vacuum. They are based on the
Commission’s experience in
implementing non-discriminatory open
access transmission over the past 11
years, its experience with QF issues
(including interconnection issues) over
the past 29 years, and its experience
with RTO/ISO markets over almost 10
years.
64. The cases cited by petitioners,
which taken together stand for the
proposition that the proponent of a rate
change bears the burden of proving that
change satisfies the relevant statutory or
regulatory requirements, are therefore
inapposite.32 The rebuttable
presumptions do not relieve the
Commission of its ultimate
responsibility to make findings under
section 210(m)(1) prior to relieving an
electric utility of the purchase
requirement. Instead, they simply
provide advance notice of how the
Commission will carry out that
responsibility.
65. The rebuttable presumptions are
also consistent with the requirements of
section 210(m)(3), which establishes the
procedures to be followed when an
electric utility requests that the
Commission make the finding of
nondiscriminatory access to a market
identified in section 210(m)(1)(A), (B),
or (C). As required in section 210(m)(3),
the regulations promulgated in the Final
Rule clearly require a petitioning
electric utility to state the factual basis
on which it relies and describe why the
conditions set forth in subparagraphs
(A), (B), or (C) are met.33 That factual
basis could include the factual
determinations made in the Final Rule
regarding certain markets satisfying the
criteria of those subparagraphs, the
presumptions adopted in the Final Rule
regarding nondiscriminatory access, or
any other factor the electric utility
considers relevant to the determination
the Commission must make under
section 210(m)(1). There is no conflict
between the use of rebuttable
presumptions and the procedural
requirements of section 210(m)(3).
66. We reiterate that the rebuttable
presumptions adopted in the Final
Rule—some of which are presumptions
in favor of the electric utility and some
of which are in favor of the QF—are not
final determinations. Each of these
presumptions is expressly rebuttable.
Electric utilities and QFs alike will have
the opportunity to present case-specific
evidence in support of or against
32 See Hi-Tech Furnace Sys. v. FCC, 224 F.3d 781
(D.C. Cir. 2000); Pub. Serv. Comm’n of New York
v. FERC, 866 F.2d 487 (D.C. Cir. 1989); NICOR
Exploration Co. v. FERC, 50 F.3d 1341 (5th Cir.
1995).
33 See 18 CFR 292.310.
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
application of the presumption on
review of a request to terminate the
purchase requirement. For example,
regarding the OATT presumption in
particular, there may be circumstances
unique to a particular QF that interfere
with that QF’s nondiscriminatory access
notwithstanding its eligibility for
service under an OATT. The QF might
have operational characteristics that
effectively prevent its participation in a
market. The QF might lack access to a
mechanism to schedule transmission
service or make advance sales on a
consistent basis. Each QF will be in the
best position to have knowledge of the
particular circumstances that interfere
with its ability to access the market
through the OATT and, thus, requiring
the QF to submit evidence of its lack of
nondiscriminatory access is entirely
reasonable. The Commission clarifies
that the ability to rebut the presumption
of nondiscriminatory access applies
regardless of the market in which the
QF is located.
67. The Commission was nonetheless
sensitive to the QFs’ potential need for
information relevant to rebutting the
presumption of nondiscriminatory
access. The Commission therefore
required petitioning electric utilities to
submit information regarding
transmission constraints, levels of
congestion, and interconnections in
order to give potentially affected QFs
data that may be relevant to rebutting
the presumption that they have access
to the market. With these informational
safeguards in place, we believe that
reliance on a rebuttable presumption
regarding nondiscriminatory access to
the market is reasonable.
68. We also reject arguments on
rehearing that the Commission failed to
justify reliance on the OATT in
particular when formulating its
rebuttable presumptions. Since issuance
of the Final Rule, the Commission has
issued Order No. 890, adopting reforms
to the OATT to ensure that transmission
customers continue to have
nondiscriminatory access to
transmission service.34 The
Commission’s findings in Order No. 890
do not, however, conflict with the
rebuttable presumption adopted in this
proceeding, as petitioners claim. The
Commission did not find in Order No.
890 that any transmission provider
actually discriminated against a
particular customer and, instead, found
that there remained opportunities for
such discrimination that needed to be
34 Preventing Undue Discrimination and
Preference in Transmission Service, Order No. 890,
72 FR 12266 (Mar. 15, 2007), FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,241 at P 443 (2007).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
remedied.35 The fact that opportunities
remained for discrimination in the
provision of transmission service
(which, we add, we have now
addressed) would conflict with an
irrebuttable presumption of
nondiscriminatory access, not a
rebuttable presumption. The rebuttable
nature of the presumption
acknowledges that a QF may not
actually have nondiscriminatory access
and leaves that determination for caseby-case review by the Commission.
69. At the same time, the underlying
structure of the OATT, even before the
reforms adopted in Order No. 890 are
implemented, and certainly after,
counsels in favor of the rebuttable
presumption that eligibility for service
under an OATT provides
nondiscriminatory access to markets.
Under the OATT, transmission
providers must make transmission
capacity available to all customers on a
nondiscriminatory basis, thereby
ensuring a level playing field for all
market participants attempting to access
supplies. That requirement by definition
satisfies the nondiscriminatory access
criteria of section 210(m). To the extent
a QF believes that it in fact is not
receiving nondiscriminatory access to
the market, however, it can make that
demonstration in response to an electric
utility’s application to terminate the
purchase requirement.
70. In response to arguments by
Cogeneration Association of California
that the existence of an OATT is
insufficient to guarantee
nondiscriminatory access because it
may not provide physical rights, we
note that in organized markets which
offer financial transmission rights, these
financial rights are in addition to, not in
place of, physical rights. In essence, the
Cogeneration Association of California
is arguing that the Commission should
provide a QF with transmission services
superior to those available to other
generators in the organized markets.
However, section 210(m)(1) requires
that a QF have nondiscriminatory access
to one of the markets specified in
section 210(m)(1)(A), (B), or (C); it does
not guarantee a QF preferential access to
transmission service. To the extent that
Cogeneration Association of California
also argues that a QF that has
contractual obligations to thermal hosts
does not have the flexibility to
participate in markets where the access
is provided by financial, rather than
physical, transmission rights, the
Commission in its regulations has
provided each QF the opportunity to
argue that its operational characteristics
35 Id.
PO 00000
at P 42.
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
35881
prevent the qualifying facility’s
participation in a market. Thus any QF
that believes it does not have
nondiscriminatory access to the market
(regardless of whether access is
provided by physical or financial rights)
has the right to rebut the OATT
presumption of access in response to an
electric utility filing seeking termination
of the mandatory purchase obligation.
71. The Commission also declines to
adopt Occidental’s recommendation to
require additional information from
electric utilities relying on the OATT
presumption. The filing requirements of
§ 292.310 of the Commission’s
regulations, as modified below, are
sufficient to provide the Commission
with the information necessary to
promptly process applications for
termination of the purchase
requirement.
72. Finally, the Commission grants
clarification of its determination in the
Final Rule that only issues other than
issues related to the provision of open
access transmission under the OATT
will be considered when analyzing
whether the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access to markets has
been rebutted. The Commission
continues to believe that complaint
proceedings are the appropriate forum
for such disputes. However, where there
are pending complaints raising credible
issues concerning a transmission
provider’s implementation or
administration of its OATT, the
Commission will also consider that fact,
as appropriate, when evaluating
whether a QF does in fact have
nondiscriminatory access to the market.
2. ‘‘Day 2’’ Markets
73. The Final Rule provided for a
second rebuttable presumption specific
to QFs operating in a ‘‘Day 2’’ market.
Because members of the ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/
ISOs have turned over the operation of
their transmission facilities to an
independent entity that has no stake in
the marketplace and that ensures all
users of the transmission system are
treated on a nondiscriminatory basis
and are provided access to their
markets, the Commission established a
rebuttable presumption that QFs
interconnected with electric utility
members of a ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISO have
nondiscriminatory access to that ‘‘Day
2’’ market. Since the Commission found
that the existing ‘‘Day 2’’ markets
satisfied the requirements of section
210(m)(1)(A), this creates a rebuttable
presumption that electric utility
members of the existing ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/
ISOs are relieved of the purchase
requirement.
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
35882
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
74. The Commission declined to
apply this presumption of
nondiscriminatory access to entities that
are not members of the ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/
ISOs. In order for such entities to obtain
relief of the purchase requirement, the
Commission stated that they must file
an application pursuant to either section
210(m)(1)(B) or (C), to be reviewed on a
case-by-case basis by the Commission.
Requests for Rehearing
75. Industrial Parties argue that the
Commission does not have sufficient
experience to impose a presumption of
access in the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets. In their
view, these markets are nascent and the
Commission does not have the ability to
determine whether QFs have sufficient
access to competitive alternatives to
justify relieving electric utilities within
those markets of the mandatory
purchase obligation.
76. NRECA, on the other hand, argues
that it is arbitrary and capricious to
deny to non-member utilities within or
adjacent to the footprint of a ‘‘Day 2’’
RTO/ISO the same presumption
accorded to RTO/ISO members. NRECA
contends that there is no basis for
denying non-RTO member utilities
adjacent to an RTO the same
presumption where the non-RTO
member utilities have a Commissionapproved OATT or reciprocity tariff.
NRECA also argues that the Final Rule
appears inconsistent as to which
standard a non-RTO member within a
‘‘Day 2’’ RTO footprint must satisfy in
order to obtain a waiver from the
purchase requirement. Although the
Final Rule provides that non-RTO
members, if they are located within or
adjacent to the footprint of a ‘‘Day 2’’
RTO, must satisfy the section
210(m)(1)(B) or (C) standards in order to
remove the purchase obligation, NRECA
notes that the Final Rule also states that
any electric utility may file an
application for relief from the purchase
requirement by showing
nondiscriminatory access to any of the
section 210(m)(1)(A), (B) or (C)
markets.36
77. NRECA also argues the Final Rule
effectively allows QFs interconnected to
an RTO member that has had its
purchase requirement terminated to
have the option of participating in that
RTO market or requesting wheeling
service to whichever non-member
utility within or adjacent to the RTO’s
footprint has the highest avoided cost.
NRECA expresses concern that the QF
in this circumstance could seek to
consummate a mandatory purchase
36 NRECA Request for Rehearing at 8 (citing Final
Rule at P 125, 151).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
agreement with a distant utility,
notwithstanding termination of the
purchase obligation for its
interconnected utility. NRECA therefore
asks the Commission to address this
unintended consequence on rehearing.
78. Even if Congress assumed that
QFs in RTO regions have access to
nondiscriminatory transmission
services, as well as meaningful
opportunities to sell long-term capacity/
energy in competitive markets, PIOs
argues that it does not follow that
Congress intended to permit utilities in
those regions to bypass section
210(m)(3) requirements or to authorize
the Commission not to consider
evidence of actual QF access to required
services and markets when utilities in
those regions seek to end their PURPA
obligations.
Commission Determination
79. The Commission denies rehearing
of its decision to adopt a rebuttable
presumption that QFs interconnected
with electric utility members of a ‘‘Day
2’’ market have nondiscriminatory
access to that ‘‘Day 2’’ market.
Arguments that the ‘‘Day 2’’ markets do
not provide QFs sufficient competitive
alternatives are rejected above.37 The
Commission has sufficient experience
with the four ‘‘Day 2’’ markets to
determine that QFs have
nondiscriminatory access to those
markets. Industrial Cogenerators offers
no reason to depart from the statutory
language and impose a more rigorous
standard.
80. The Commission also denies
rehearing of its decision to limit
application of the ‘‘Day 2’’ presumption
only to member utilities of the
particular ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISO. Member
utilities have turned over control of
their transmission to the regional
organization. As a result, QFs
interconnected with a member utility
may offer their energy into the RTO/ISO
day ahead and real time energy markets
without any additional concerns about
securing transmission capacity. These
QFs face few, if any, barriers to be able
to sell energy and capacity to any
willing purchaser within the RTO/ISO
region, subject to the purchaser’s
willingness to pay any relevant
congestion charges.
81. In contrast, non-member utilities
have retained control over their
transmission facilities and, thus, control
the only access interconnected QFs have
to the market. While an OATT or
reciprocity tariff will provide a QF
interconnected with a non-member
utility with access to the market within
37 See
PO 00000
supra P 19–30, 41–48.
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
that particular utility’s subregion, the
QF must compete with the non-member
utility to secure transmission service in
order to access the nearby regional
market. Issues may arise concerning
ATC and a range of other open access,
commercial, and coordination (with the
RTO or ISO) matters that are more
appropriately examined on a casespecific basis.38 Accordingly, it is
reasonable for the Commission to limit
application of the rebuttable
presumption that the four RTO/ISOs
meet the statutory standards under
PURPA 210(m)(1)(A) only to member
utilities of those regional organizations.
Non-member utilities remain free,
though, to seek termination of the
obligation to purchase from QFs in
individual cases.
82. NRECA is correct that any electric
utility may file an application for relief
of the purchase obligation under any
subparagraph of section 210(m)(1). We
clarify that the Commission’s
conclusion not to apply a presumption
of nondiscriminatory access to nonmember utilities of a ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISOs
does not preclude such utilities from
seeking to satisfy the requirements of
subparagraphs (A), (B), or (C), as the
regulations in Part 292 of the
Commission’s regulations expressly
provide.
83. In response to NRECA’s concern
that a QF interconnected with a member
utility of a ‘‘Day 2’’ market will seek
PURPA contracts with adjacent utilities,
using QF wheeling rights, we do not
interpret section 210(m) to permit this.
Section 210(m)(1) provides that ‘‘no
electric utility’’ shall be subject to the
purchase requirement if the
Commission finds that the QF has
nondiscriminatory access to one of the
specified markets. Thus, once the
Commission makes a finding that a
particular QF has nondiscriminatory
access to one of the specified markets,
no electric utility shall be required to
enter into a new contract or obligation
with that QF. The QF would therefore
no longer be able to impose the
purchase requirement on any electric
utility. If a QF that has been found to
have nondiscriminatory access to one of
the specified markets pursuant to the
request of a particular electric utility
seeks to enforce the purchase obligation
against another electric utility, the
38 For example, QFs interconnected with member
utilities would not experience rate pancaking for
transmission service to access the market,
additional risks and costs of possible curtailment
outside of the locational marginal price (LMP)
managed market, or increased scheduling burdens
associated with taking service over an intervening
transmission system under the OATT (in
comparison to directly scheduling energy deliveries
in the day-ahead and real-time LMP markets).
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
second electric utility may file an
application to terminate its purchase
obligation with respect to that QF, and
the Commission would consider its
findings in the first proceeding to be
determinative, absent a showing by the
QF that circumstances, either
nondiscriminatory access or the state of
the markets, have changed.
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
3. Small Size
84. Notwithstanding the presumption
of nondiscriminatory access afforded by
the OATT or the structure of the ‘‘Day
2’’ markets, the Commission concluded
in the Final Rule that certain QFs may
nonetheless have difficulty accessing
the market due to their small size. The
Commission, therefore, adopted an
additional rebuttable presumption that
small QFs do not have
nondiscriminatory access to the market,
regardless of whether the QF is an
eligible customer under an OATT or
interconnected with a member utility of
a ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISO. Although the
Commission did not specify in the Final
Rule what evidence would be sufficient
to rebut this presumption, it did note
that relevant evidence could include the
extent to which the small QF has been
participating in the market or is owned
by, or is an affiliate of, an entity that has
been participating in the relevant
market. The Commission also found that
a reasonable and administratively
workable definition of ‘‘small’’ is 20
MW net capacity or smaller.
Requests for Rehearing
85. On rehearing, petitioners raise
several issues regarding the rebuttable
presumption for small QFs. Some
utilities argue that there should be no
special treatment of small QFs and that
the rebuttable presumption is an
impermissible waiver of section 210(m).
Some QFs, however, argue that small
QFs should be completely exempt from
termination of the mandatory purchase
obligation. Various petitioners argue
that the Commission should set the
threshold for ‘‘small’’ lower or higher.
86. Central Vermont argues that
making exceptions for certain QFs
because of their small size goes against
the plain language of the statute,
contending that the statute says nothing
about allowing the Commission to
consider whether it is practical or
economical for the QF to reach the
wholesale market in question. Central
Vermont argues that the Commission’s
findings with respect to QFs
interconnected with member utilities of
the ‘‘Day 2’’ RTO/ISO should apply
equally to all QFs regardless of size.
NRECA similarly argues that Congress
did not establish exceptions for size,
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
characterizing the Commission’s
standards for overcoming this
presumption as insurmountable and,
therefore, arbitrary and capricious.
87. Deere argues, however, that the
purchase requirement for small QFs
should be retained in full in any market
in which that obligation is otherwise
lifted for large generators. Otherwise,
Deere contends, the rebuttable
presumption will be an invitation for
expensive litigation. Deere argues that
the Commission should treat small QFs
in a manner that prevents the costs of
defending the rebuttable presumption
from becoming a discouragement to the
development of small renewable
projects.
88. CIBO argues that the Commission
should expand the size presumption to
apply to QFs with a net capacity of 80
MW or less. CIBO contends such
treatment would be consistent with the
Commission’s obligation under EPAct
2005 to issue a rule that ensures
continuing progress in the development
of efficient electric energy generating
technology. CIBO argues that Congress
defined ‘‘small’’ in PURPA as 80 MW
for small biomass, waste, renewable
resources and geothermal resource
power generation and, therefore, the
Commission’s defining of small QFs at
20 MW contravenes Congress’s
longstanding support of QFs, creates
obstacles for some but not all small QFs
and upsets capital investment. CIBO
argues that the Commission makes no
attempt to explain how 20 MW QFs
differ from 80 MW QFs and that any
differentiation for purposes of unequal
statutory treatment must have a rational
basis.
89. CIBO further argues that the
orders cited by the Commission in favor
of a 20 MW threshold, such as Order
No. 671 39 and Order No. 2006,40 do not
address the operational limits or
difficulties that larger QFs have in
accessing ‘‘Day 2’’ markets, such as
widely fluctuating steam-host demand,
siting issues and transmission versus
distribution interconnection access
issues. Without guaranteed access to
markets, CIBO contends that many QFs
in the 20–80 MW range will simply stop
39 Revised Regulations Governing Small Power
Production and Cogeneration Facilities, Order No.
671, 71 FR 7852 (Feb. 15, 2006), FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,203 (2006), order on reh’g, Order No. 671–A,
71 FR 30585 (May 30, 2006), FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,219 (2006).
40 Standardization of Small Generator
Interconnection Agreements and Procedures, Order
No. 2006, 70 FR 34189 (June 13, 2005), FERC Stats.
& Regs. ¶ 31,180 (2005), order on reh’g, Order No.
2006–A, 70 FR 71760 (Nov. 30, 2005), FERC Stats.
& Regs. ¶ 31,196 (2005).
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
35883
cogenerating and new industrial
cogeneration will not be developed.
90. Finally, CIBO argues that
increasing the threshold to 80 MW adds
a very small number of QFs and would
add little to the amount of capacity
compared to total nationwide capacity.
In CIBO’s view, the Final Rule already
requires utilities to purchase power
from QFs that are less than 20 MW and,
thus, there would not be any material
increase in administrative burden for
electric utilities to use an 80 MW
threshold.
91. Industrial Parties argue that the
Commission should expand the small
size presumption to include any QF that
is unable to sell power in 50 MW
blocks, regardless of the particular
capacity of the facility. Industrial Parties
contend that certain over the counter
bilateral contracts stipulate a minimum
lot increment of 50 MW, which can be
a problem for larger QFs (i.e., above the
20 MW threshold) because their
intermittent production of surplus
power cannot always or easily be
packaged in 50 MW x 16 hour
increments. Industrial Parties state that
QFs that cannot sell 50 MW blocks have
only very limited access to financial
markets, at disadvantageous terms.
92. NRECA argues that the
Commission’s 20 MW threshold is too
generous. NRECA states there is
evidence in the record that RTOs are
capable of transacting with generators
with capacities as small as one or two
MW depending on the RTO. NRECA
contends that no party has
demonstrated that the existing RTO
processes for utilities between one and
20 MW are ineffective, unduly
complicated or overly burdensome.
NRECA also suggests that the
Commission’s earlier decision to
simplify interconnection for generators
with capacities of less than 20 MW is
unrelated to the question of whether
QFs have access to markets or, if related,
demonstrates that they have such
access.
93. With regard to how the
Commission measures the size of a QF
for purposes of applying the rebuttable
presumption, the Cogeneration
Association of California requests the
Commission to clarify it is by reference
to capacity delivered to the grid. The
Cogeneration Association of California
state that cogenerators often supply
electricity to on-site load and only
supply a portion of their maximum
electrical output to the grid. In its view,
electricity used to supply on-site load
should not be counted for purposes of
applying the size presumption.
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
35884
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
Commission Determination
94. The Commission denies the
requests for rehearing regarding the
rebuttable presumption that small QFs
do not have nondiscriminatory access to
the market. We continue to believe it is
appropriate to adopt a rebuttable
presumption that certain QFs do not
have nondiscriminatory access to
markets because of their small size. The
purchase requirement will therefore
remain in effect, in all markets, for all
QFs with a net capacity of 20 MW or
smaller, although electric utilities will
have the opportunity to rebut the
presumption by showing that a small
QF does in fact have nondiscriminatory
access to the relevant market.
95. We share CIBO’s goal of
continuing progress in the development
of efficient electric generating
technology, but disagree with CIBO and
other petitioners that we have
unreasonably differentiated ‘‘small’’
from ‘‘large’’ QFs. There is no perfect
bright line that can be drawn and we
have reasonably exercised our
discretion in adopting a 20 MW or
below demarcation for purposes of
determining which QFs are unlikely to
have nondiscriminatory access to
markets. Moreover, any QF above 20
MW is permitted to demonstrate an
inability to access the markets, and any
electric utility is permitted to
demonstrate that a QF 20 MW or smaller
is able to access the markets. The
Commission’s development of
rebuttable presumptions is based on its
experience with QFs, transmission
interconnections and related market
issues, and is designed to provide a
reasoned and fair approach for
processing applications within the 90day time frame dictated by the statute.
96. While the Final Rule does not
make a generic finding that QFs
interconnected at a distribution level
lack nondiscriminatory access to
markets, we believe that it is reasonable
to conclude that some, perhaps most,
small QFs at or below the 20 MW level
can be distinguished from larger QFs by
the type of delivery facilities to which
they typically interconnect. Most QFs
larger than 20 MW are interconnected to
higher voltage lines, typically
considered to be transmission lines,
while smaller QFs tend to be
interconnected to lower voltage radial
lines, frequently considered to be
distribution.41 Many lower voltage
41 See, e.g., Standardization of Small Generator
Interconnection Agreements and Procedures, Order
No. 2006–A, 70 FR 71760 (Nov. 30, 2005), FERC
Stats. & Regs. 31,196 at P 105 (2005), (‘‘We expect
the vast majority of small generator
interconnections will be with state interconnection
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
facilities are radial systems designed to
carry power from the high-voltage grid
downstream to loads, and there may be
technical enhancements required to
move power injected into such facilities
upstream to the transmission grid to
access the broader wholesale market.
Smaller QFs are also more likely to have
to overcome other obstacles, such as
jurisdictional differences, pancaked
delivery rates, and perhaps additional
administrative procedures, to obtain
access to distant buyers.42 Taken
together, these factors support a
rebuttable presumption that smaller QFs
have substantially less ability to access
wholesale markets than do larger QFs.
97. Although there is no unique and
distinct megawatt size that uniquely
determines if a generator is small, in
other contexts the Commission has used
20 MW, based on similar considerations
to those presented here, to determine
the applicability of its rules and
policies. Indicative of this is the
Commission’s reliance in the Final Rule
on its findings in Order No. 671, where
the Commission retained exemptions for
QFs that are 20 MW or smaller from
sections 205 and 206 of the FPA, and
Order Nos. 2006 and 2006–A, where the
Commission recognized that generators
20 MW or smaller should have different
standards for interconnection than large
generators. We continue to believe that
20 MW is the appropriate level at which
to apply this rebuttable presumption.
98. We disagree with CIBO that the
Commission’s small QF threshold of 20
MW contradicts Congress’s 80 MW
definition of small power producers in
PURPA section 210(a).43 The 80 MW
threshold in section 210(a) of PURPA
defines the qualification of small power
producers eligible for the rights,
privileges and protections of QFs. The
use of 20 MW in the Commission’s
implementation of section 210(m) of
PURPA serves a fundamentally different
purpose. The Commission is
distinguishing between small and large
facilities to reflect the ability of
particular QFs to access markets.
Categorically applying the presumption
to all small power production facilities,
through adoption of a 80 MW threshold,
would not appropriately take into
programs.’’); Id. at P 102 (‘‘a QF selling at retail is
not eligible to interconnect under either Order No.
2003 or Order No. 2006. Under the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, such
interconnections are governed by state law.’’)
(citations omitted).
42 See, e.g., Standardization of Small Generator
Interconnection Agreements and Procedures, Notice
of Proposed Rulemaking, 68 FR 49974 (Aug. 19,
2003), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,572 (2003) at P 23–
25.
43 16 U.S.C. 796(17)(A)(ii).
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
account the different considerations that
affect a QF’s ability to access markets.
99. We also disagree that use of a 20
MW threshold defeats Congressional
intent to foster small power production.
The purchase requirement remains in
place for small power producers that do
not have nondiscriminatory access to
one of the markets identified in section
210(m)(1)(A), (B), or (C). The purchase
requirement can be terminated only if
the Commission finds
nondiscriminatory access to such
markets, which in turn means the small
power producers will have the ability to
sell their energy and capacity into the
wholesale marketplace.
100. We reject the request that the
Commission expand the small size
presumption to include any QF that is
unable to sell power in 50 MW blocks,
regardless of the particular capacity of
the facility. While it may be true that
certain over-the-counter bilateral
contracts stipulate a minimum lot
increment of 50 MW, and while also it
may be true that such a contractual
requirement may be a problem for some
QFs that are larger than 20 MW because
of their intermittent production of
surplus power, the Commission has
provided these larger QFs the
opportunity to rebut the presumption of
access to the ‘‘Day 2’’ market by
showing, among other things,
operational characteristics that
effectively prevent the QF’s
participation in a market or that the QF
has no access to a mechanism to
schedule transmission service or make
sales in advance on a consistent basis
because of variability of the QF’s
electric energy production or because of
market rules that prevent the QF from
scheduling transmission service or
participating in organized markets.44
The effect of needing to sell in 50 MW
blocks may therefore be presented to the
Commission in the context of a
particular request to terminate the
purchase requirement. Expansion of the
small size rebuttable presumption to
reflect this concern, which may not be
relevant in all cases, is thus neither
necessary nor appropriate.
101. The Commission rejects requests
to apply the small size presumption
only to much smaller QFs, such as those
with a net capacity of one or two MW.
We set the rebuttable presumption at an
appropriate level, reflecting our
understanding of the general nature of
QFs’ interconnection practices and the
relative capabilities of small entities.
However, we again stress that the
presumption is rebuttable. Electric
utilities are free to argue that smaller
44 Final
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
Rule at P 82–84; 18 CFR 292.309(e)(1).
29JNR3
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
entities have nondiscriminatory access
to qualifying markets. We believe that
the best place to consider such
arguments is in the individual cases that
electric utilities bring to the
Commission.
102. Petitioners arguing that the
Commission has inappropriately waived
the effects of section 210(m) for small
QFs mischaracterize the Final Rule. The
Commission made clear in the Final
Rule that no class of QFs had been
shown to uniformly lack
nondiscriminatory access based on a
single factor and, as such, no
justification existed for exempting any
category of QFs from any future orders
which may terminate a utility’s
purchase requirement. The Commission
did, however, create a rebuttable
presumption that small QFs may not
have nondiscriminatory access to
markets because of their small size. As
we explain above, the use of such
rebuttable presumptions is fully
consistent with the Commission’s
obligation under section 210(m) and the
Commission’s need to identify ways to
expedite processing of applications.
103. To be clear, the use of a
rebuttable presumption does not
prevent a utility from seeking to
terminate the obligation to purchase
power from small QFs, as would be the
case if the Commission implemented a
waiver. Instead, the use of the rebuttable
presumption simply leaves the burden
on the utility to show that these smaller
entities indeed have nondiscriminatory
access. This approach recognizes that,
more often than not, a small QF will
have greater difficulty obtaining
nondiscriminatory access to markets
due to the tendency for small QFs to be
interconnected to lower voltage radial
lines, and the consequent need to
overcome other potential obstacles to
nondiscriminatory access, such as local
distribution access rules that are not
within the Commission’s jurisdiction,
pancaked delivery rates and additional
administrative burdens to obtain access
to buyers other than the interconnected
utility. It is therefore appropriate in the
first instance to place on the electric
utility the burden of demonstrating that
a small QF does in fact have
nondiscriminatory access to the types of
markets identified in sections
210(m)(1)(A), (B) or (C). Similarly, the
rebuttable presumption that QFs above
20 MWs do have nondiscriminatory
access to markets does not prevent a QF
from providing evidence to the contrary.
104. With regard to the request to
clarify how the 20 MW threshold will be
measured, the Commission explained in
the Final Rule that a QF is required to
state its size in terms of ‘‘net capacity’’
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
when certifying its status as a QF.45 Net
capacity is the maximum amount of
power that the facility is able to produce
(gross capacity) less any auxiliary load
for devices that are necessary and
integral to the power production process
(station power). Any power consumed
by on-site load at the location of the QF
for purposes unrelated to the power
production process should not be
subtracted from gross capacity for
purposes of reporting net capacity.
Whether the facility is a Commissioncertified facility or a self-certified
facility, both are certified at net
capacity. Therefore, a QF’s Commissioncertified (or self-certified) net capacity
would determine whether the QF
qualifies for the ‘‘small size’’ rebuttable
presumption.
C. Filing Requirements
105. In the Final Rule, the
Commission found that a utility electing
to file for relief from the purchase
requirement must submit an application
with the Commission providing certain
information, including transmission
constraints within its service territory in
order to give potentially affected QFs
information that may be useful in
rebutting the presumption that they
have access to all aspects of the
applicable ‘‘Day 2’’ markets.46 The filing
requirements are contained in new
§ 292.310(d) of the Commission’s
regulations.
Requests for Rehearing
106. Industrial Parties contend that
the Commission is not sufficiently
prescriptive as to the level of detail on
transmission availability that utilities
should provide in their applications.
Industrial Parties argue that the
Commission should require the same
information on transmission access as in
UniSource Energy Corporation.47
Industrial Parties also argue that to
enable effective input by QFs and other
interested parties, any information
provided to support an electric utility’s
application to terminate its purchase
obligation must be provided to all
affected QFs at the time of filing.
Industrial Parties continue that if a QF
later seeks to reinstate the purchase
obligation, the electric utility needs to
provide current data, and not rely on the
45 Final
Rule at P 72, n.41.
Rule at P 102.
47 UniSource Energy Corporation, 109 FERC
¶ 61,047 (2004) (UniSource) (reviewing a market
monitoring plan submitted in support of a request
for Commission authorization of the disposition of
jurisdictional facilities for purposes of identifying
anticompetitive conduct).
46 Final
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
35885
data it used to justify termination of the
purchase obligation.
107. EEI, however, believes the filing
requirements in § 292.310(d)(3) of the
Commission’s regulations are unduly
broad and potentially burdensome. EEI
urges the Commission to exempt
utilities operating within the footprint
of Commission-approved RTO/ISOs that
have financial, rather than physical,
transmission rights models and ERCOT
(which likewise operates under a
financial transmission rights model)
from the information submission
requirements in § 292.310(d)(3). Since a
QF has the right to interconnect to
transmission within an RTO/ISO that
operates under a financial transmission
rights model, EEI contends that the QF
has access to that market regardless of
whether a physical path exists for
electric sales. As a result, EEI argues
that interconnection and other
transmission constraint and congestion
studies are of little relevance in
determining whether a QF has
nondiscriminatory access to
transmission in any market with a
financial rights transmission model.
108. EEI argues that even in markets
without financial transmission rights,
all new QFs have nondiscriminatory
access if they are willing to fund on an
up-front basis the transmission upgrades
necessary to receive network resource
status, i.e., if they are willing to comply
with Order Nos. 2003 and 2006. Despite
the fact that any upgrade costs for firm
transmission service are typically rolled
into rates, EEI contends that the
Commission’s transmission pricing
policy could require that existing QFs
bear the incremental cost of upgrades if
firm transmission service is not
available and the costs of the upgrades
exceed the rolled-in rate. As a result,
EEI argues that the only grounds for
rebuttal of the presumption of
nondiscriminatory access when OATT
service is available should be related to
unique operational characteristics of the
specific QF or in the rare circumstance
in which there is not a sufficient
opportunity to relieve a transmission
constraint because of unique factors,
such as the inability to secure regulatory
approval for upgrades or otherwise to
remedy physical system limitations. EEI
therefore asks the Commission to limit
the informational filing requirements to
those particular circumstances.
109. In addition, EEI requests the
Commission to clarify what is intended
by ‘‘[r]elevant system impact studies for
the generation interconnections, already
completed’’ for both non-RTO/ISO and
RTO/ISO regions. EEI states that it is
unclear what studies, and what time
frames, are contemplated by this
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
35886
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
requirement and whether this language
is intended to refer to the
interconnection studies for existing QFs
or for all generator interconnections. EEI
requests clarification that ‘‘relevant’’
studies will be limited to studies that
are the most recent regarding the QF’s
impact on the system or the most recent
generic studies of the applicable control
area. EEI states that, for the last several
decades, interconnection studies for
QFs not selling to the market have been
performed under state oversight. EEI
requests that the Commission clarify
whether the equivalent of system impact
studies performed for QFs pursuant to
state regulation should be provided.
110. Lastly, if the Commission
chooses to maintain the requirements in
§ 292.310(d)(3) of the Commission’s
regulations, EEI requests that the
requirements identified in paragraph
(iii) of § 292.310(d)(3), regarding system
impact studies for generator
interconnections, be clarified to require
all Commission-approved RTO/ISOs to
identify and make available to their
member transmission owners
confidential and public versions of each
interconnection study it performs for
submission to the Commission. They
argue that it is not clear how electric
utilities that have transferred
operational control of their transmission
to RTO/ISOs could fulfill the
requirement to provide ‘‘relevant system
impact studies’’ without imposing
certain requirements on the RTO/ISO.
EEI urges the Commission to clarify that
submitting studies conducted by the
RTO/ISO will be sufficient to meet the
informational requirements.
Commission Determination
111. In order to ensure that a
potentially affected QF has an adequate
opportunity to evaluate potential
obstacles to nondiscriminatory access,
despite the existence of an OATT or the
QF’s location in a ‘‘Day 2’’ market, the
Commission will maintain the
requirement for applicants to submit
transmission-related information
relevant to a QF’s evaluation of this
question. Information about the
applicant’s long-term transmission plan,
the location of transmission constraints,
levels of congestion, system impact
studies, and links to applicant’s Open
Access Same Time Information System
(OASIS) for ATC information will allow
a potentially affected QF to detect
whether it might be located on a portion
of a utility’s system where limited
transfer capability may constrain its
ability to transfer power into the
wholesale market. In response to
Industrial Parties’ concerns that QFs be
provided any information used to
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
support an electric utility’s application,
our rules currently provide that an
electric utility must identify with names
and addresses all potentially affected
QFs.48 Electric utilities serve potentially
affected QFs with a copy of the
application. In addition, the
Commission by letter provides notice of
the application to the potentially
affected QFs and explains comment
procedures and how the QFs can access
the electric utility’s filings.49 An
interested potentially affected QF
should intervene in the proceeding and
would then receive any subsequent
information provided by an electric
utility.
112. We disagree with EEI that the
filing requirements are unduly broad or
burdensome. It is reasonable to place
those obligations on the petitioning
electric utility, the party requesting the
Commission to make the findings
required by section 210(m)(1) of
PURPA. These filing requirements will
facilitate timely processing of the
application by the Commission, while
also providing QFs with the information
necessary for their own evaluation of
nondiscriminatory access to wholesale
markets. We find that EEI’s claim of
burden is overstated, since we do not
require anything which has not already
been developed. It is our experience that
most of this documentation is in
electronic format and available through
online resources.50 We clarify,
moreover, that an applicant can provide
a hyperlink to the relevant studies, if
available, rather than submitting
complete studies and reports.51 We
therefore believe that the burden on a
utility of providing existing information
is minimal and that the benefits to the
QFs and the Commission of providing
this information readily in one filing
48 18
CFR 292.310.
the unlikely event a potentially affected QF
is intentionally or unintentionally omitted by the
electric utility and not served notice of an
application, the Commission will take remedial
steps as appropriate.
50 We note that the following public and nonpublic sources contain transmission information:
RTO websites for links to publicly available
regional transmission plans; OASIS websites for
system impact studies including various
transmission service requests, available through
confidentiality agreements; OASIS websites for
posted ATC values, available through an OASIS
certificate; and, FERC Form 715 for the Annual
Transmission Planning and Evaluation Report
submitted to the Commission, available on the
FERC website through the Critical Energy
Infrastructure Information (CEII) process.
51 The filing should identify the relevance of the
material in the hyperlink. And to the extent that the
filing discusses particular portions of such studies
and reports, the electric utility should clearly
identify those portions by page, paragraph, or
similar reference.
49 In
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
will outweigh any such minimal
burdens.
113. We deny EEI’s request to exempt
utilities operating within the footprint
of a Commission-approved RTO/ISOs
from submitting the information to the
extent it is otherwise available from or
provided by the RTO or ISO. The fact
that electric utilities in RTO/ISO regions
may be able to access information
required in those filings on an equal
basis as other parties, i.e., through the
RTO/ISO website or databases, does not
eliminate the Commission’s underlying
need for the information to process the
application in a timely manner.
Furthermore, we emphasize that
§ 202.310(d)(3) of the Commission’s
regulations requires the submission of
non-publicly available information to
the extent it is the only relevant
available resource responsive to this
requirement. Any need to maintain
confidentiality can be addressed in the
context of the particular application.
114. We also disagree that the
information required in § 292.310(d)(3)
is not necessary in RTO/ISO markets
with financial transmission rights
models. This information is relevant
even in the context of financial RTO
markets as it will help potentially
affected QFs understand the
transmission market circumstances they
would face if the Commission approves
the utility’s application. The filing
requirements will, in this regard,
therefore not be changed for any electric
utility seeking termination of the
purchase requirement.
115. As to the argument that
transmission-related information is
unnecessary since new QFs have
nondiscriminatory access if they fund
transmission upgrades necessary to
receive network resource status, we
disagree. Information about
transmission system constraints will
allow a potentially affected QF to
evaluate the impact of a utility’s request
on the QF. Transmission constraints
also provide valuable information about
the scope and geographic reach of the
market a potentially affected QF may
reach as an alternative to selling to the
local utility.
116. With regard to EEI’s request to
explain the phrase ‘‘[r]elevant system
impact studies for the generation
interconnections, already completed,’’
we clarify that the studies we consider
relevant are the most recent system
impact studies, already completed, that
analyze the generation interconnection
to the applicant’s transmission
substation that is ‘‘electrically close’’ to
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
the QF’s substation.52 With respect to
EEI’s question whether the equivalent of
system impact studies performed for
QFs pursuant to state regulation should
be provided, we clarify that these
studies must be submitted if they
provide responsive information relevant
to the filing requirements.
117. We also clarify, as requested by
EEI, that submitting studies conducted
by an RTO/ISO will be sufficient to
meet the informational requirements,
provided the submission is complete,
i.e., the applicant submits every study
required (or hyperlinks to the relevant
studies) and all related information
listed in § 292.310(d). However, we
deny EEI’s request that the Commission
require RTO/ISOs to identify and make
available confidential and public
versions of each interconnection study
it performs. We believe this request is
unnecessary. It is our understanding
that the current practice within the
RTO/ISOs is that the electric utility
receives the confidential version of the
study from the RTO/ISO, and likely has
participated at least in an advisory role
in the performance of the study.
Therefore, we expect that these studies
would already be in the applicant’s
possession or could be made available
to them without placing any extra
requirements or burdens on the RTO/
ISOs. It is the utility who is filing an
application seeking relief from the
purchase requirement and, therefore, we
believe it is their responsibility to gather
and submit the information to the
Commission. Additionally, while the
publicly available reports are available
through the OASIS websites, an
applicant still needs to identify those
studies that are relevant, and provide
them (either physically or by hyperlink)
with the filing.53
118. In response to the Industrial
Parties’ argument that the Commission
is not sufficiently prescriptive as to the
level of detail regarding transmission
availability required under the
Commission’s regulations, we deny
rehearing in part. As a general matter,
we believe the information identified in
§ 292.310(d)(3) is sufficient to give
potentially affected QFs information
relevant to evaluate whether there is
adequate transmission available for new
selling arrangements, subsequent to
termination of the utility’s purchase
52 By ‘‘electrically close’’ we mean any
interconnection to the same substation where the
QF is connected or to any adjacent substation or
interconnection point where power injection to the
transmission system has the same or similar impact
on the transmission facilities’ loadings, as the QF’s
power injection.
53 See supra note 51.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
requirement.54 In addition, the
information on processes to be followed
to access the markets, identified in
§ 292.310(d)(4) and (5), is sufficient to
give affected QFs information relevant
to evaluating nondiscriminatory access
to the markets described in section
210(m)(1) of PURPA. The relevant
transmission information referred to by
Industrial Parties in the UniSource
proceeding is thus embedded in the
studies we require to be filed. We do not
agree that the other elements offered by
UniSource in the market monitoring
plan for its proposed merger are either
relevant or necessary to evaluating
nondiscriminatory access in this
context.
119. We do, however, believe that
§ 292.310 of the Commission’s
regulations lacks certain information
that will facilitate the Commission’s
processing of section 210(m)
applications. The Commission has
processed applications in Docket Nos.
QM07–2–000 and QM07–4–000 and as
a result of its experience in those
dockets finds that additional
information from electric utilities would
help avoid the need to issue
‘‘deficiency’’ letters or send additional
information requests, ultimately slowing
down the processing of requests for
relief. The Commission therefore
amends its regulations to require that
the following additional information be
submitted: the docket number assigned
to each potentially affected QF if it filed
for self-certification of QF status or an
application for Commission-certification
of QF status; the net capacity of each
potentially affected QF; the location of
each potentially affected QF depicted by
state and county and the name and
location of the substation where each
potentially affected QF is
interconnected; the interconnection
status of each potentially affected QF
including whether the QF is
interconnected as an energy or a
network resource; and the expiration
date of the energy and/or capacity
agreement between the applicant utility
and each potentially affected QF. The
introductory paragraph of § 292.310(c) is
thus amended to read as follows:
54 However,
we note, in order for a QF to evaluate
potential ATC on an applicant’s OASIS, the QF will
need to determine the type, firmness and duration
of transmission service that the affected QF will
need for the power it intends to sell on a
prospective basis. While this information will
provide a potentially affected QF with information
about current ATC, it is no guarantee that service
from a particular source to a particular load can be
provided on a firm basis. Only submission of a
request and subsequent reservation of transmission
service can provide that level of certainty to any
prospective customer.
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
35887
(c) An electric utility must submit with its
application for each potentially affected
qualifying facility: the docket number
assigned if a qualifying facility filed for selfcertification or an application for
Commission certification of qualifying
facility status; the net capacity of the
qualifying facility; the location of the
qualifying facility depicted by state and
county, and the name and location of the
substation where each qualifying facility is
interconnected; the interconnection status of
each potentially affected qualifying facility
including whether the qualifying facility is
interconnected as an energy or a network
resource; and, the expiration date of the
energy and/or capacity agreement between
the applicant utility and each potentially
affected qualifying facility. All potentially
affected qualifying facilities shall include:
*
*
*
*
*
120. Additionally, in reviewing the
regulations adopted in the Final Rule,
we have discovered a mistake in
§ 292.310(d)(3) that we will correct here.
The applicant’s ‘‘long-term transmission
plan’’ referred to in § 292.310(d)(3) was
intended to be information required to
be filed with an application. Therefore
the applicant’s ‘‘long-term transmission
plan’’ is redesignated as
§ 292.310(d)(3)(i). Also, in
§ 292.310(d)(3)(vi), the term ‘‘available
transmission capacity (ATC)’’ will be
corrected to state ‘‘available transfer
capability (ATC).’’ The new
§ 292.310(d)(3) is amended to read as
follows:
(3) Transmission Studies and related
information, including:
(i) The applicant’s long-term transmission
plan, conducted by applicant, or the RTO,
ISO or other relevant entity;
(ii) Transmission constraints by path,
element or other level of comparable detail
that have occurred and/or are known and
expected to occur, and any proposed
mitigation including transmission
construction plans;
(iii) Levels of congestion, if available;
(iv) Relevant system impact studies for the
generation interconnections, already
completed;
(v) Other information pertinent to showing
whether transfer capability is available; and
(vi) The appropriate link to applicant’s
OASIS, if any, from which a qualifying
facility may obtain applicant’s available
transfer capability (ATC) information.
121. Finally, Industrial Parties asks us
to clarify that if a QF later seeks to
reinstate the purchase obligation
pursuant to § 292.311, the electric
utility, if it chooses to answer the QF’s
petition to reinstate, needs to provide
current data, and not rely on the data it
used to originally justify termination of
the mandatory purchase obligation. We
decline to make a generic determination
here on this matter. If an electric utility
answers the QF’s petition, it is free to
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
35888
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
decide what information to file so as to
present its best arguments, based on the
content of the QF’s filing, the amount of
time since the prior proceeding and any
indications of changed circumstances in
the interim. Our decision on whether to
reinstate the purchase obligation will be
based on all of the information
presented.
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
D. Obligation To Sell
122. Section 210(m)(5) of PURPA
removes the requirement that an electric
utility sell electric energy to any QF if
the Commission finds that: ‘‘Competing
retail electric suppliers are willing and
able to sell and deliver electric energy
to the qualifying cogeneration facility or
qualifying small power production
facility; and the electric utility is not
required by State law to sell electric
energy in its service territory.’’
123. In the Final Rule, the
Commission clarified that lifting the
obligation from a particular utility to
purchase electric energy from a QF did
not relieve such utility of its obligation
to sell supplemental, backup, standby
and maintenance power to the QF. The
Commission explained that any finding
under section 210(m)(5) would be made
under a separate standard and in a
separate proceeding pursuant to
§ 292.312 of the Commission’s
regulations. The Commission
emphasized that it would strictly
interpret the statutory language in such
proceedings, noting in particular the
reference to ‘‘competing retail electric
providers’’ in section 210(m)(5). The
Commission concluded that the
reference required a finding that the QF
has available at least two competing
suppliers who are not affiliated with the
interconnecting utility.
Requests for Rehearing
124. Industrial Parties request that the
Commission condition releasing electric
suppliers from their obligation to sell
standby and backup power on a finding
that a competitive market for power
exists. Although utilities in the
organized markets may assert that there
are multiple retail providers, Industrial
Parties contend that in many cases the
providers have little capacity to serve
the QF profile or would attach a large
premium to the price given their interest
in serving a stable load. They argue that
some utility or other supplier being
willing to sell a QF power at some
exorbitant price does not satisfy the
Commission’s duty under PURPA to see
that QFs are not exploited and under the
FPA to ensure that rates are just and
reasonable rates. Industrial Parties also
assert one or two suppliers do not make
a competitive market and that rates paid
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
by QFs cannot be just and reasonable
unless the Commission finds that
market power cannot be exercised by
those suppliers.55
Commission Determination
125. We deny Industrial Parties’
request to condition termination of the
sales obligation on the existence of a
competitive market for replacement
power. We continue to believe a strict
interpretation of section 210(m)(5) is
appropriate in response to requests to
terminate the obligation to sell standby
and backup power to QFs. All the
statute requires is a finding that
‘‘competing retail electric suppliers are
willing and able to sell and deliver
electric energy to’’ the QF. Competing
retail electric suppliers implies two or
more sellers, and the word competing
suggests some level of competition
between them. The requirement that the
suppliers be willing and able to deliver
also appears to require sufficient
capacity to actually make sales.
126. In proceedings on applications
requesting termination of the sales
obligation under § 292.312 of the
Commission’s regulations, QFs
opposing termination of an electric
utility’s obligation to sell may certainly
argue that current practices in a
particular market may provide a basis
for the Commission to find that there are
no ‘‘competing retail electric suppliers’’
in some instances. We will decline to
rule generically on such issues in this
rulemaking.
127. We also reject the Industrial
Parties’ request to condition relief under
section 210(m)(5) on a finding that rates
for replacement power are reasonable.
We affirm our decision in the Final Rule
that the rates for retail service are
beyond the Commission’s jurisdiction.
The Industrial Parties are simply wrong
to imply that the Commission must first
find a competitive retail market before
terminating an electric utility’s
obligation to sell power to a QF. That
argument is based on the same false
premise that this Commission is
responsible for setting retail rates.
Section 210(m) does not shift
responsibility for setting or maintaining
appropriate retail rates from the States
to this Commission. Rather, section
210(m)(5) requires the Commission,
before it terminates an electric utility’s
obligation to sell electric energy to a QF,
to find that ‘‘competing retail electric
suppliers are willing and able to sell
and deliver electric energy to the’’ QF,
and that ‘‘the electric utility is not
required by State law to sell electric
energy in its service territory.’’ Section
55 Industrial
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Parties at P 19–20.
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
210(m)(5) does not require this
Commission to pass judgment on Stateapproved retail rates.
E. Existing Rights and Remedies
Background
128. Section 210(m)(6) of PURPA
protects the rights and remedies under
a contract or obligation in effect or
pending approval before a state
regulatory authority. In the Final Rule,
the Commission interpreted the term
‘‘obligation’’ as a ‘‘legally enforceable
obligation,’’ which is established
through a state’s implementation of
PURPA. The Commission stated that a
QF that had initiated, prior to date of
enactment of section 210(m) (i.e.,
August 8, 2005), a state PURPA
proceeding that may result in a contract
or legally enforceable obligation would
be considered to have triggered an
‘‘obligation’’ with an electric utility
regarding section 210(m)(6).
129. The Commission found that,
when a QF contract terminates by its
own accord, an electric utility would
not be compelled to enter into a new,
successor contract with the QF if the
purchase requirement has been
terminated for the QF. As long as there
is mutual agreement between a QF and
the electric utility to terminate a
contract, the electric utility is not
compelled to enter into another contract
with the QF. The Commission stated
that nothing in the Final Rule was
intended to abrogate existing contracts.
The Commission noted, however, that
there may be contracts containing
provisions that provide that legislation
such as EPAct 2005, or a Final Rule
such as this one, trigger termination of
the contract. To the extent the parties to
a contract cannot agree whether a
termination clause has been triggered,
the Commission determined that the
issue would be best determined in an
individual case-specific proceeding in
which the particulars of the contract can
be examined.
Requests for Rehearing
130. Deere argues that clarification is
required to preserve state law processes
as creating legally enforceable
obligations in the context of section
210(m)(1). Deere contends that language
in paragraph 213 of the Final Rule
indicates that an obligation is triggered
prior to the utility applying for relief of
the PURPA purchase requirement if a
QF ‘‘has initiated a state’s PURPA
proceeding that may result in a contract
or legally enforceable contract or
obligation.’’ Deere argues that the phrase
‘‘state’s PURPA proceeding’’ is too
narrow and should be broadened
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
because it does not recognize that a
‘‘legally enforceable obligation’’ can be
created under state law processes which
do not involve a docketed state
proceeding, such as issuance of
regulations.
131. Deere also notes that some states
have adopted PURPA implementation
approaches that require QFs to first start
construction, if not complete it, before
an obligation is created in connection
with section 210(m). Deere argues that
the Commission should therefore clarify
that a QF located in a ‘‘build first’’ state
triggers a legally enforceable obligation
if, prior to the time of the utility PURPA
relief application, it has already begun
construction. Deere argues that
otherwise, QFs that are nearly complete
in the construction will be unfairly
penalized and the significant capital
resources they have committed will be
impaired.
132. OG&E asks the Commission to
clarify that it is not prejudging when—
or if—a QF’s state PURPA application
gives rise to a legally enforceable
obligation under PURPA. OG&E
contends that the Commission has
consistently held that it is for the states,
not the Commission, to determine ‘‘the
specific parameters of individual QF
power purchase agreements, including
the date at which a legally enforceable
obligation is incurred under state
law.’’ 56 OG&E states that presuming that
a section 210(m)(1) ‘‘obligation’’ exists
as of the date a QF files a state
application that ‘‘may’’ lead to a legally
enforceable obligation is inconsistent
with how many states address this
issue. OG&E adds that the Commission
should also clarify that it is not dictating
what factors the states can consider
when evaluating whether a QF has
established a legally enforceable
obligation.
133. OG&E asks that the Commission
clarify that a utility has the opportunity
to respond to a purported legally
enforceable obligation by making a
section 210(m) filing particularly if the
state legally enforceable obligation filing
was made between August 8, 2005 and
the effective date of the Final Rule, as
may be revised on rehearing. OG&E
contends that the utility should be able
to respond by filing a section 210(m)(1)
application with the Commission.
134. OG&E also asks that the
Commission establish a formal process
that allows section 210(m)(1) issues to
be evaluated in response to a state
PURPA ‘‘obligation’’ filing. It argues that
a QF attempting to establish a legally
enforceable obligation should be
required to provide the utility with
formal notice of such a filing, and that
within sixty days of such notice, the
utility must file the necessary
application to satisfy the market criteria.
OG&E argues that this opportunity to
rebut an obligation is essential where a
QF seeks to establish a state-mandated
obligation between January 19, 2006 and
the effective date of the Final Rule.
OG&E states that the Commission made
clear in the NOPR that a utility would
not be able to submit a section 210(m)
application until after a final rule in this
rulemaking. OG&E contends that it is
therefore unreasonable for the
Commission to require utilities to delay
submitting section 210(m)(1)
applications, and then hold that it is too
late to avoid obligations purportedly
incurred during the Commissionmandated delay.
135. With regard to termination of
contracts with a QF, Industrial Parties
note that many utility contracts have a
change-in-law clause that allows them
to terminate current contracts. To the
extent that the parties to a contract
cannot agree whether a termination
clause has been triggered, the Industrial
Parties agree that the issue will be best
determined in an individual casespecific proceeding in which the
particulars of the contract can be
examined. Industrial Parties argue,
however, that the Commission should
clarify that utilities may not use such
clauses to terminate their purchase
obligation without obtaining a
Commission determination pursuant to
the processes set out in the Final Rule.
Commission Determination
136. Section 210(m)(6) provides:
NO EFFECT ON EXISTING RIGHTS AND
REMEDIES.—Nothing in this subpart affects
the rights or remedies of any party under any
contract or obligation, in effect or pending
approval before the appropriate State
regulatory authority or non-regulated electric
utility on the date of enactment of this
subsection, to purchase electric energy or
capacity from or to sell electric energy or
capacity to a qualifying cogeneration facility
or qualifying small power production facility
under this Act (including the right to recover
costs of purchasing electric energy or
capacity).
In the Final Rule, the Commission
adopted the statutory language into its
regulations 57 and pointed out that it
had previously addressed the meaning
of section 210(m)(6) in Midwest
Renewable Energy Projects, LLC.58 In
Midwest Renewable, we rejected the
35889
notion that ‘‘contract’’ and ‘‘obligation’’
are synonymous terms. When a utility
refuses to enter into a contract with a
QF, and the QF seeks state regulatory
authority assistance to enforce its
PURPA regulations, a non-contractual
but still legally enforceable obligation
may be created pursuant to the state’s
implementation of PURPA. The
Commission explained in the Final Rule
that such obligations do not necessarily
involve a single writing containing all
material terms and that how QFs may
initiate the process varies from state to
state. As a result, narrowly defining an
‘‘obligation’’ to encompass only a
specific legal arrangement with all the
relevant and material rates, terms and
conditions established could be at odds
with a state’s implementation of
PURPA. The Commission therefore
concluded in the Final Rule that the
term ‘‘obligation’’ means a ‘‘legally
enforceable obligation’’ which is
established through a state’s
implementation of PURPA.59 We affirm
the Commission’s determination in the
Final Rule that a QF that initiated, prior
to August 8, 2005, a state PURPA
proceeding that may result in a contract
or legally enforceable obligation would
be considered to have triggered an
‘‘obligation’’ with the electric utility
subject to section 210(m)(6) pending the
state’s determination of whether an
enforceable obligation exists. If the state
determines that no enforceable
obligation exists, then relief from the
utility’s purchase obligation with
respect to that QF may be granted.
137. The Commission clarifies that
the date when an ‘‘obligation’’ under
PURPA is established is the date such
obligation is established by each state
regulatory authority or nonregulated
utility. In the Final Rule, the
Commission noted that the statute
grandfathered contracts and obligations
entered into before the effective date of
EPAct 2005 in section 210(m)(6) of
PURPA, but that section 210(m)(1) of
PURPA only gives the Commission
authority to terminate the obligation to
enter into new contracts or obligations.
The Commission determined that a QF
that has initiated a state PURPA
proceeding that may result in a legally
enforceable contract or obligation prior
to the applicable electric utility filing its
petition for relief pursuant to § 292.310
of the Commission’s regulations will be
entitled to have any contract or
obligation that may be established by
state law grandfathered.60 We see no
59 Final
56 OG&E
Request for Rehearing at 5 (citing
Metropolitan Edison Co., 72 FERC ¶ 61,015 at
61,050 (1995)).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
57 Final
Rule at P 210–11.
58 Midwest Renewable Energy Projects, LLC, 116
FERC ¶ 61,017 (2006) (Midwest Renewable).
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Rule at P 211–13.
we noted above, once the Commission has
made a finding that a particular QF has
60 As
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
Continued
29JNR3
35890
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
reason to change this determination, as
the grandfathering of only pre-August 8,
2005 contracts or obligations would
undermine any subsequent QF
investments.
138. We do note, however, that if a QF
argues that any contract or obligation
was ‘‘pending approval before the
appropriate State regulatory authority or
non-regulated electric utility,’’ and thus
argues that the utility’s obligation to
purchase from the QF ought not be
terminated pursuant to a § 292.310
proceeding, the Commission will
consider those claims in the individual
proceedings as they arise. Whether a
contract or obligation exists would
depend on state law. What we do not
expect to see is a race to make filings
either to be grandfathered, or to negate
a potential obligation filed after August
8, 2005, but prior to a utility’s filing for
relief from the obligation to enter new
contracts or obligations.
139. Deere requests that we clarify
that a legally enforceable obligation may
be created not just by a state PURPA
proceeding, but also by other means
such as by a state issuing regulations or
taking other action reasonably designed
to give effect to the Commission’s rules.
We find that the language ‘‘or pending
approval’’ in section 210(m)(6) implies
that there has been a filing before a state
regulatory authority. As we stated in
Midwest Renewable, ‘‘the phrase ‘or
pending approval’ [is] quite significant,
as it ensures that contracts or
obligations that had not yet been
entered into but were being pursued in
the context of the state commission
proceedings that were pending on the
date of enactment of EPAct 2005 will
fall within the savings clause.’’ 61 We
therefore find that, under most
circumstances, there must be some sort
of filing before a state regulatory
authority for a QF to be ‘‘pending
approval.’’ Even under these
circumstances, we emphasize, however,
that in the division of responsibilities of
administering PURPA between this
Commission and state regulatory
authorities (and non-regulated utilities),
it is the state regulatory authorities (or
non-regulated utilities) that determine
whether and when a legally enforceable
obligation is created, and the procedures
for obtaining approval of such an
nondiscriminatory access to one of the specified
markets, this conclusion would be binding in
proceedings involving the same QF and other
electric utilities, absent a showing of changed
circumstances. Accordingly, as of the date of the
first electric utility’s filing seeking termination of
the obligation to purchase from a particular QF, any
subsequent state filing that a QF makes will not
result in a grandfathered obligation.
61 Midwest Renewable at P 14 (emphasis added).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
obligation. QFs that believe that some
other sort of state proceeding has
created a legally enforceable obligation
under state law may argue their claim
before the Commission, and we will
make such determinations on a case-bycase basis based on state law.
140. Accordingly, while we agree
with Deere that QFs that have begun but
not yet completed physical
construction, and therefore that have
not been able to complete the process
for creating a legally enforceable
obligation under a ‘‘build first’’ state
law, may have utilized a particular
state’s implementation of PURPA in a
way that results in a legally enforceable
obligation, such a determination would
need to be made on a case-specific basis.
Whether the state regulatory authority’s
process for creating a legally enforceable
obligation has begun, and thus there is
a contract or obligation pending,
depends on state law. A QF may argue
that an obligation or contract is pending
approval as provided by state law in any
proceedings seeking termination of the
purchase obligation, or pursuant to a
petition for declaratory order.
141. The Commission denies OG&E’s
request to establish a new process by
which a utility could use a section
210(m) application to nullify a state
proceeding to establish a new QF
purchase obligation. OG&E complains
that the Commission prevented utility
section 210(m) filings from January 19,
2006, when the NOPR issued, until
issuance of the Final Rule, and should
not now find that QFs initiating state
‘‘obligation’’ proceedings during that
interim period, or thereafter, are
grandfathered under section 210(m)(6)
of PURPA. Under OG&E’s proposal, a
QF seeking a new state ‘‘obligation’’
determination would be required to
notify the utility and the utility would
have 60 days to file a section 210(m)
application with the Commission; this
application would be addressed in a
final determination within 90 days. This
final determination could then be taken
into account by the state in deciding
whether to grant the QF’s application to
create a new ‘‘obligation’’ for the local
utility to purchase power from the QF.
142. We decline to create the new
process requested by OG&E. We
continue to believe that the
Commission’s determination to adopt
the language of section 210(m)(6) and to
look to state law to determine whether
a contract or obligation is pending
approval provides a sufficient balance
between the rights of the electric
utilities seeking relief from the
obligation to enter into new contracts or
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
obligations, and the rights of QFs under
existing contracts or obligations.
143. We will grant clarification with
regard to the termination of existing
contracts. Industrial Parties’ request is
consistent with our other findings with
regard to contract termination in the
Final Rule. In the Final Rule, in
response to comments by AEP, we
stated that an electric utility will not be
compelled to enter into a new contract
as long as there is mutual agreement
between a QF and the electric utility to
terminate the existing contract. We
made clear, however, that ‘‘a QF
contract is to remain in effect until it
terminates by mutual agreement or by
its own terms.’’ 62 The Commission also
recognized that some contracts contain
clauses stating that legislation, such as
EPAct 2005, or a Commission action,
such as the Final Rule in this docket,
may be grounds for termination of the
contract. If an electric utility and a QF
disagree as to the meaning of a
termination clause, either the electric
utility or the QF may seek a
determination regarding its rights under
the termination clause in the
appropriate state forum since the issue
of whether a QF has a continuing right
to sell is a matter of contract
interpretation.
F. Implementation Procedures
144. Section 210(m)(3) of PURPA
provides in part that ‘‘[a]ny electric
utility may file an application with the
Commission for relief from the
mandatory purchase obligation pursuant
to this subsection on a service territorywide basis.’’ The Commission
essentially incorporated this language
into § 292.310 of its regulations. The
Commission also determined that an
electric utility’s mandatory purchase
obligation would be suspended upon
the filing of its PURPA petition. When
an electric utility files its PURPA
petition, that electric utility will not be
obligated to enter into new contracts or
obligations with QFs as of the date its
PURPA petition is filed. If the
Commission finds that the requirements
of section 210(m)(1) of PURPA have
been met, then the purchase
requirement for that electric utility ends
as of the date of the PURPA petition.
However, if the Commission finds that
the requirements of section 210(m)(1)
have not been met, then the electric
utility’s obligation to enter into new
contracts or obligations is reinstated as
of the date of the Commission order.
62 Final
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
Rule at P 219.
29JNR3
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
Requests for Rehearing
145. PacifiCorp and EEI argue that the
Commission should clarify the
procedures for utilities requesting
termination of the mandatory purchase
obligation on a ‘‘service territory-wide’’
basis. PacifiCorp notes that the term
‘‘service territory-wide’’ is not defined
in PURPA or in the Final Rule and
could refer to a portion of a utility’s
electric infrastructure located in a
specific state or could be understood to
be synonymous with the control area
operated by the applicant. PacifiCorp
argues that a single entity (such as
PacifiCorp) owning transmission
facilities and operates multiple control
areas should be able to file separate
applications for each control area.
PacifiCorp and EEI argue that such
clarification would facilitate the
processing of applications by the
Commission within the time limitations
established by Congress. PacifiCorp and
EEI request that the Commission clarify
that it will interpret ‘‘service territory’’
to be the particular control area or areas
identified in the application when the
applicant operates multiple control
areas spanning several states.
146. If the Commission retains the
small QF rebuttable presumption, Deere
requests that the Commission grant
rehearing of its decision to temporarily
suspend a utility’s PURPA obligation
once a request for relief has been filed.
Deere argues that the Commission
should instead apply the utility’s
PURPA relief to small QFs only after the
Commission makes the required
findings with regard to the small QF
issue. Deere contends that this would
protect small QFs who, at the time of
the utility’s PURPA relief application,
have already begun preliminary
development work but have not yet
been able to begin utilization of the
applicable state law process for creating
a legally enforceable obligation.
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
Commission Determination
147. We clarify that an electric utility
may specify in its application the
territory within which it seeks to have
its purchase obligation terminated.
148. We grant Deere’s request to
distinguish between particular types of
QFs for purpose of suspending the
mandatory purchase obligation once an
application for relief has been filed
under section 210(m)(3). The rebuttable
presumption that small QFs do not have
access to markets will remain in effect
and, thus, it is reasonable to retain the
mandatory purchase obligation from
small QFs pending consideration a
PURPA petition. We clarify that to the
extent that an electric utility seeks to be
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
relieved of the obligation to purchase
from a small QF, the electric utility
must rebut the presumption that the
small QF does not have
nondiscriminatory access to the
applicable market prior to the
termination of the purchase requirement
as applied to that QF, and that the
purchase obligation remains in effect
until, and if, the Commission makes the
finding that the small QF does have
nondiscriminatory access to markets
that warrant termination of the purchase
obligation.
III. Information Collection Statement
149. The regulations of the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) 63
require that OMB approve certain
information requirements imposed by
an agency. OMB has approved the
information requirements contained in
Order No. 688. Specifically, OMB
approved the following information
collections and assigned the
corresponding OMB control numbers:
Small Power Production and
Cogeneration Facilities (FERC–556)
(1902–0075).
150. On rehearing EEI argues that the
filing requirements in § 292.310(d)(3)
are unduly broad and burdensome. We
have addressed those arguments
elsewhere in this order.64
151. This order on rehearing adopts a
change. Specifically, we are requiring
electric utilities filing an application
with the Commission for relief from the
mandatory purchase requirement to
provide more information about the
potentially affected QFs, including the
docket number assigned if the QF filed
for self-certification or Commission
certification of qualifying facility status,
the location of the QF depicted by state
and county, and by the name and
location of the substation where the QF
is interconnected, and whether the QF
is interconnected as an energy or
network resource. We do not anticipate
that this new requirement to provide
additional information about the
potentially affected QFs will impose a
significant additional burden on electric
utilities; the additional information we
are requiring is readily available to
electric utilities. Accordingly, we will
allow the original projected burden
estimates expressed in Order No. 688 to
stand.
Interested persons may obtain
information on the reporting
requirements by contacting the
following: Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426 [Attention:
63 5
CFR 1320.12.
supra P 112–17.
Michael Miller, Office of the Executive
Director, Phone (202) 502–8415, fax:
(202) 273–0873, e-mail:
michael.miller@ferc.gov]
152. To submit comments concerning
the collection of information(s) and the
associated burden estimates, please
send your comments to the contact
listed above and to the Office of
Management and Budget, Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs,
Washington, DC 20503, Attention: Desk
Officer for the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission; Phone: (202)
395–4650, fax: (202) 395–7285.
IV. Document Availability
153. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through
FERC’s Home Page (https://www.ferc.gov)
and in FERC’s Public Reference Room
during normal business hours (8:30 a.m.
to 5 p.m. Eastern time) at 888 First
Street, NE., Room 2A, Washington, DC
20426.
154. From FERC’s Home Page on the
Internet, this information is available on
eLibrary. The full text of this document
is available on eLibrary in PDF and
Microsoft Word format for viewing,
printing, and/or downloading. To access
this document in eLibrary, type the
docket number excluding the last three
digits of this document in the docket
number field.
155. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the FERC’s Web site during
normal business hours from our FERC
Online Support at 202–502–6652 (tollfree at 1–866–208–3676) or e-mail at
ferconlinesupport@ferc.gov, or the
Public Reference Room at (202) 502–
8371 Press 0, TTY (202) 502–8659. EMail the Public Reference Room at
public.referenceroom @ferc.gov.
V. Effective Date
156. These revisions in this order on
rehearing are effective July 30, 2007.
By the Commission.
Commissioner Kelly concurring with a
separate statement attached.
Kimberly D. Bose,
Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission amends part 292, Chapter I,
Title 18, Code of Federal Regulations, as
follows:
I
64 See
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
35891
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
35892
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules and Regulations
PART 292—REGULATIONS UNDER
SECTIONS 201 AND 210 OF THE
PUBLIC UTILITY REGULATORY
POLICIES ACT OF 1978 WITH REGARD
TO SMALL POWER PRODUCTION AND
COGENERATION
1. The authority citation for part 292
continues to read as follows:
I
Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a–825r, 2601–
2645; 31 U.S.C. 9701; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352.
2. In § 292.310, paragraphs (c)
introductory text and (d)(3) are revised
to read as follows:
I
§ 292.310 Procedures for utilities
requesting termination of obligation to
purchase from qualifying facilities.
*
*
*
*
(c) An electric utility must submit
with its application for each potentially
affected qualifying facility: The docket
number assigned if the qualifying
facility filed for self-certification or an
application for Commission certification
of qualifying facility status; the net
capacity of the qualifying facility; the
location of the qualifying facility
depicted by state and county, and the
name and location of the substation
where the qualifying facility is
interconnected; the interconnection
status of each potentially affected
qualifying facility including whether the
qualifying facility is interconnected as
an energy or a network resource; and the
expiration date of the energy and/or
capacity agreement between the
applicant utility and each potentially
affected qualifying facility. All
potentially affected qualifying facilities
shall include:
*
*
*
*
*
(d) * * *
(3) Transmission Studies and related
information, including:
(i) The applicant’s long-term
transmission plan, conducted by
applicant, or the RTO, ISO or other
relevant entity;
mstockstill on PROD1PC66 with RULES3
*
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:42 Jun 28, 2007
Jkt 211001
(ii) Transmission constraints by path,
element or other level of comparable
detail that have occurred and/or are
known and expected to occur, and any
proposed mitigation including
transmission construction plans;
(iii) Levels of congestion, if available;
(iv) Relevant system impact studies
for the generation interconnections,
already completed;
(v) Other information pertinent to
showing whether transfer capability is
available; and
(vi) The appropriate link to
applicant’s OASIS, if any, from which a
qualifying facility may obtain
applicant’s available transfer capability
(ATC) information.
*
*
*
*
*
KELLY, Commissioner, concurring:
Under PURPA section 210(m)(1)(A), no
electric utility shall be required to enter into
a new contract or obligation to purchase
electric energy from a QF under section
210(m) if the Commission finds that the QF
has nondiscriminatory access to: ‘‘(i)
independently administered, auction-based
day ahead and real time wholesale markets
for the sale of electric energy; and (ii)
wholesale markets for long-term sales of
capacity and electric energy.’’ This order
affirms the finding in Order No. 688 that the
four ‘‘Day 2’’ markets (MISO, PJM, NYISO
and ISO-NE) satisfy both requirements of
section 210(m)(1)(A).
By contrast to section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii),
section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii) requires that a QF
have nondiscriminatory access to
‘‘competitive wholesale markets that provide
a meaningful opportunity to sell capacity,
including long-term and short-term sales, and
electric energy, including long-term, shortterm and real-time sales, to buyers other than
the utility to which the qualifying facility is
interconnected.’’ Section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii) also
provides that ‘‘[i]n determining whether a
meaningful opportunity to sell exists, the
Commission shall consider, among other
factors, evidence of transactions within the
relevant market.’’ In Order No. 688, the
Commission interpreted the use of the terms
‘‘competitive,’’ ‘‘meaningful opportunity’’
and ‘‘evidence of transactions’’ in section
210(m)(1)(B)(ii) to mean that Congress
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
intended for termination of the purchase
requirement in a ‘‘Day 1’’ market, such as
CAISO and SPP, only if it could be
demonstrated that QFs had opportunities to
make long-term and short-term sales of
capacity and long-term, short-term and realtime sales of energy into competitive
wholesale markets. This order clarifies that,
based on the specific language contained in
section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii), a petitioning electric
utility located in a ‘‘Day 1’’ market must
demonstrate an actual, not just theoretical,
opportunity to meet this requirement.
Accordingly, this order affirms Order No. 688
in finding that the ‘‘Day 1’’ markets, SPP and
CAISO, have not been shown to meet the
requirements of section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii).
On rehearing, petitioners dispute the
Commission’s finding in Order No. 688 that
the four ‘‘Day 2’’ markets meet the second
prong of section 210(m)(1)(A). They argue
that the mere existence of long-term bilateral
contracts for sales of capacity and energy in
these markets is not sufficient to demonstrate
that there is a competitive market for
capacity and energy sales or meaningful
opportunities for QFs to sell energy or
capacity long-term to multiple buyers.
I sympathize with petitioners’ argument,
and in fact I believe that section
210(m)(1)(A)(ii) logically should have
required a demonstration of a competitive
long-term market that provides a meaningful
opportunity for QFs to sell energy or capacity
long-term to buyers other than the utility to
which the QF is interconnected, as is
required under section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii).
However, the less specific language in
section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) used to describe the
quality of the relevant long-term market that
would satisfy this requirement indicates that
either this was not Congress’s intent, or that
perhaps there was a drafting oversight. In any
event, we must look to the plain language of
the statute. Thus, in my view, the
Commission has reasonably interpreted
section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) to require only that
there be a ‘‘market’’ for long-term sales of
capacity and energy with respect to electric
utilities located in ‘‘Day 2’’ markets.
Accordingly, I concur with this order.
Suedeen G. Kelly
[FR Doc. E7–12553 Filed 6–28–07; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
E:\FR\FM\29JNR3.SGM
29JNR3
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 72, Number 125 (Friday, June 29, 2007)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 35872-35892]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E7-12553]
[[Page 35871]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Part VI
Department of Energy
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
18 CFR Part 292
New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations Applicable to Small Power
Production and Cogeneration Facilities; Final Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 125 / Friday, June 29, 2007 / Rules
and Regulations
[[Page 35872]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 292
[Docket No. RM06-10-001; Order No. 688-A]
New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations Applicable to Small Power
Production and Cogeneration Facilities
Issued June 22, 2007.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule; order on rehearing.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In this order on rehearing, the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission (Commission) denies rehearing on most major issues decided
in Order No. 688, which amended its regulations governing small power
production and cogeneration in response to section 1253 of the Energy
Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005), which added section 210(m) to the
Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978 (PURPA). The Commission
also clarifies certain aspects of the rule and adopts some additional
filing requirements.
DATES: Effective Date: The revisions to our regulations in this order
on rehearing will become effective July 30, 2007.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Susan G. Pollonais (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Markets and Reliability, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
(202) 502-6011.
Marka Shaw (Technical Information), Office of Energy Markets and
Reliability, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street,
NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8641.
Samuel Higginbottom (Legal Information), Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8561.
Mason Emnett (Legal Information), Office of the General Counsel,
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-6540.
Eric Winterbauer (Legal Information), Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8329.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: Before Commissioners: Joseph T. Kelliher,
Chairman; Suedeen G. Kelly, Marc Spitzer, Philip D. Moeller, and Jon
Wellinghoff.
Order on Rehearing and Clarification
I. Introduction
1. On October 20, 2006, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
(Commission) issued Order No. 688,\1\ in which the Commission revised
its regulations governing the purchase requirement for electric energy
produced by qualifying cogeneration and small power production
facilities (QFs). This rulemaking proceeding was initiated to implement
section 210(m) of the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act of 1978
(PURPA),\2\ which mandates termination of the requirement that an
electric utility enter into a new contract or obligation to purchase
electric energy from QFs \3\ if the Commission finds that the QF has
nondiscriminatory access to one of three categories of markets defined
in section 210(m)(1)(A), (B), or (C) of PURPA, as amended.
2. As relevant here, section 210(m) provides for the following:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ New PURPA Section 210(m) Regulations Applicable to Small
Power Production and Cogeneration Facilities, Order No. 688, 71 FR
64342 (Nov. 1, 2006), FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,233 (2006) (Final
Rule).
\2\ Section 210(m) was added to PURPA by section 1253 of the
Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005). See Pub. L. 109-58, 1253,
119 Stat. 594, 967 (2005).
\3\ The requirement that an electric utility enter into a new
contract or obligation to purchase electric energy from QFs is
referred to herein as either the mandatory purchase obligation or,
more simply, the purchase requirement.
(i) Termination of the requirement that an electric utility
enter into a new contract or obligation to purchase electric energy
from a QF after certain specified findings are made by the
Commission;
(ii) Reinstatement of the purchase requirement upon a showing
that the conditions for terminating the requirement are no longer
met;
(iii) Termination of the requirement that an electric utility
enter into new contracts to sell electric energy to QFs after
certain specified findings are made by the Commission;
(iv) Reinstatement of the sale requirement upon a showing that
the conditions for terminating the requirement are no longer met;
and,
(v) Preservation of existing contracts and obligations to
purchase electric energy or capacity from, or to sell electric
energy or capacity to, a QF.
The Final Rule amended Part 292 of the Commission's regulations,
pertaining to electric utilities' obligation to purchase electric
energy from or sell electric energy to a QF, to address these
provisions of section 210(m) and also to provide a process for applying
for the reinstatement of the requirements to purchase electric energy
from or to sell electric energy to QFs upon a showing that the
conditions for the removal of those requirements are no longer met.
3. New Sec. 292.309 of the Commission's regulations describes the
findings that the Commission must make to justify relieving an electric
utility's obligation to enter into new QF purchase contracts. If the
Commission finds that the QF has nondiscriminatory access to one of
three types of wholesale markets described in subparagraphs (A), (B),
and (C) of section 210(m)(1), the requirement that the electric utility
enter into new contracts or obligations is terminated. In the Final
Rule, the Commission concluded that the four existing ``Day 2'' markets
\4\ satisfy the requirements of subparagraph (A). The Commission found
that the ``Day 1'' markets \5\ satisfy some, but not all, of the
requirements of subparagraph (B). Finally, the Commission found that
the markets operated by the Electric Reliability Council of Texas
(ERCOT) satisfy the requirements of subparagraph (C). All of these
markets are administered by regional transmission organizations (RTOs)
or independent system operators (ISOs).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ The four existing ``Day 2'' markets are those auction based
day-ahead and real-time markets operated by the Midwest Independent
Transmission System Operator Corp. (MISO), PJM Interconnection, LLC
(PJM), New York Independent System Operator, Inc. (NYISO), and ISO
New England, Inc. (ISO-NE).
\5\ The existing ``Day 1'' markets are those real-time markets
operated by the California Independent System Operator Corporation
(CAISO) and the Southwest Power Pool (SPP).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. With regard to analyzing whether a QF has nondiscriminatory
access to one of these markets, the Commission adopted three rebuttable
presumptions. First, the Final Rule concluded that the existence of an
open access transmission tariff (OATT), or a reciprocity tariff filed
by a non-public utility pursuant to the Commission's open access
regulations,\6\ justified a rebuttable presumption that QFs have
nondiscriminatory access to the markets in the transmission provider's
service territory. Second, the Commission adopted a rebuttable
presumption that QFs located within one of the four existing ``Day 2''
markets also have nondiscriminatory access to those markets. Third, the
Commission concluded that QFs with a net capacity no greater than 20 MW
may not have nondiscriminatory access to any market, notwithstanding
the availability of service under an OATT or their location within a
``Day 2'' market. The Commission therefore adopted a rebuttable
presumption that such small
[[Page 35873]]
QFs do not have nondiscriminatory access to any market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ 18 CFR 35.28(e). An OATT provides interconnection as well as
transmission services on a nondiscriminatory basis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. Requests for rehearing and/or clarification of these rulings,
and the procedure implementing them, were received from the American
Forest and Paper Association (American Forest & Paper) and California
Cogeneration Council (CCC), Central Vermont Public Service Corporation
(Central Vermont), Cogeneration Association of California and the
Energy Producers and Users Coalition (Cogeneration Association of
California), the Council of Industrial Boiler Owners (CIBO), Deere &
Company (Deere), Edison Electric Institute (EEI), Oklahoma Gas and
Electric Company (OG&E), jointly from the Electricity Consumers
Resource Council (ELCON), the American Iron and Steel Institute, the
American Chemistry Council, and the Council of Industrial Boiler Owners
(Industrial Parties), National Rural Electric Cooperative Association,
(NRECA), Occidental Chemical Corporation (Occidental), PacifiCorp, and
Public Interest Organizations (PIOs). Southern California Edison (SCE)
and PJM Interconnection, Inc. (PJM) filed answers to the requests for
rehearing. ELCON and Cogeneration Association of California filed
answers those answers.\7\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ Rule 713(d) of the Commission's Rules of Practice and
Procedure, 18 CFR 383.713(d), provides that the Commission will not
permit answers to requests for rehearing. We will, accordingly,
reject SCE and PJM's answers to the requests for rehearing. Rule
213(a)(2) of the Commission's Rules of Practice and Procedure, 18
CFR 385.213(a)(2), prohibits an answer to an answer unless otherwise
ordered by the decisional authority. We are not persuaded to accept
the answers of ELCON and Cogeneration Association of California and
will, therefore, reject them. The alternative motions to reject of
ELCON and Cogeneration Association of California are rejected as
moot.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
6. As discussed below, the Commission generally denies the requests
for rehearing of the Final Rule. The Commission continues to believe
that the Final Rule appropriately implements section 210(m) by
identifying what type of markets satisfy the requirements of sections
210(m)(1)(A), (B), and (C) and the criteria that will be used to
determine whether a QF has nondiscriminatory access to one of those
markets. We therefore do not disturb the basic implementation structure
established in that order. We do, however, grant clarification
regarding certain specific matters. The Commission addresses each of
these issues in turn.
II. Discussion
A. Three Types of Markets
7. Section 210(m)(1) identifies three types of markets,
nondiscriminatory access to which will satisfy the findings the
Commission must make to terminate an electric utility's purchase
requirement. As the Commission explained in the Final Rule, the
statutory language of sections 210(m)(1)(A), (B), and (C) requires us
to differentiate among distinct types of markets when analyzing whether
an electric utility will be relieved of its purchase obligation. The
Commission must terminate the mandatory purchase obligation if we find
that a QF has nondiscriminatory access to:
(A) ``independently administered, auction-based day ahead and
real time wholesale markets for the sale of electric energy'' and
``wholesale markets for long-term sales of capacity and electric
energy'';
(B) ``transmission and interconnection services that are
provided by a Commission-approved regional transmission entity and
administered pursuant to an open access transmission tariff that
affords nondiscriminatory treatment to all customers'' and
``competitive wholesale markets that provide a meaningful
opportunity to sell capacity, including long-term and short-term
sales, and electric energy, including long-term, short-term and
real-time sales, to buyers other than the utility to which the [QF]
is interconnected''; \8\ or,
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ In determining whether a meaningful opportunity to sell
exists, section 210(m)(1)(B) directs the Commission to consider,
among other factors, evidence of transactions within the relevant
market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
(C) ``wholesale markets for the sale of capacity and electric
energy that are, at a minimum, of comparable competitive quality as
markets described in subparagraphs (A) and (B).''
8. In the Final Rule, the Commission considered the specific
criteria set forth in these statutory provisions and concluded that
certain markets in the United States satisfied some or all of the
requirements of each. The Commission rejected proposals to adopt a
single standard for relief, which in effect would interpret sections
210(m)(1)(A), (B), and (C) as collectively defining a single type of
market, access to which would require termination of the purchase
requirement. The Commission found that the most reasonable
interpretation of section 210(m)(1) is that Congress, in separately
describing three different types of markets, was requiring the
Commission to differentiate among each type of market when determining
whether to terminate the purchase requirement.
1. Section 210(m)(1)(A)
9. Section 210(m)(1)(A) of PURPA requires the Commission to
terminate an electric utility's obligation to purchase from a QF if the
QF has nondiscriminatory access to (i) independently administered,
auction-based, day ahead and real time wholesale markets for the sale
of electric energy; and (ii) wholesale markets for long-term sales of
capacity and electric energy. In the Final Rule, the Commission found
that the four existing ``Day 2'' markets, MISO, PJM, ISO-NE and NYISO,
satisfy the first prong of section 210(m)(1)(A) because the markets
administered by these RTO/ISOs are, as required by the statute,
independently administered, auction-based day ahead and real time
wholesale markets for electricity.\9\ The Commission further found that
the existence of bilateral long-term contracts for long-term sales of
capacity and energy in these markets satisfies the second prong of
section 210(m)(1)(A). Since both of these requirements are satisfied,
the Commission concluded that a showing of nondiscriminatory access to
any of these ``Day 2'' markets would terminate the purchase
requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ The Commission stated that any future determinations of
whether a new ``Day 2'' market satisfies the requirements of section
210(m)(1)(A) would be considered on a case-by-case basis, either in
response to an application for termination of the mandatory purchase
obligation or a petition for declaratory order.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Requests for Rehearing
10. No petitioner challenges the Commission's determination that
the existing ``Day 2'' RTO/ISO markets satisfy the requirements of the
first prong of section 210(m)(1)(A), i.e., that they are independently
administered, auction-based day ahead and real time wholesale
electricity markets. Requests for rehearing instead focus on the second
prong, regarding whether a wholesale market for long-term sales of
capacity and electric energy also exists in these regions. PIOs argue
that the mere existence of some bilateral long-term contracts does not
demonstrate the existence of a competitive wholesale market for long-
term sales or actual ``meaningful opportunities'' for QFs to sell
energy or capacity long-term to multiple buyers. PIOs therefore contend
that the Commission erred in finding that the ``Day 2'' markets satisfy
the requirements of section 210(m)(1)(A). Cogeneration Association of
California agrees that the existence of a ``Day 2''
[[Page 35874]]
market does not equate to a long-term market, arguing that access to a
long-term market is essential to provide the assurance of long-term
revenue necessary to provide incentives for construction of new
resources.
11. American Forest & Paper and CCC argue that there has never been
a time in the history of the power industry when some bilateral
contracts did not exist. They contend that there is no evidentiary
basis that shows such contracts are available to QFs on a
nondiscriminatory basis or that there is a market for such contracts.
They argue that the word ``market'' presumes more than an occasional,
isolated transaction. American Forest & Paper and CCC argue that in the
Final Rule the Commission not only fails to explain why the existence
of bilateral contracts constitutes a meaningful competitive market, but
also fails to establish any standard for what constitutes a ``long term
sale,'' examine any of the bilateral contracts it believes exist to
determine if they meet any such standard, or consider whether bilateral
contracts are in fact available to QFs in any meaningful sense.
12. Cogeneration Association of California adds that the
insufficiency of the bilateral markets is also demonstrated by the lack
of meaningful participation in utility requests for offers.
Cogeneration Association of California argues that the current practice
of bilateral contracting is not indicative of a competitive market, nor
is it proof that QFs have a meaningful opportunity to participate in
whatever markets are there. It argues that there is significant
discrimination against QFs when they attempt to enter into bilateral
contracts.
13. American Forest & Paper and CCC also argue that the Final Rule
errs as a matter of law by determining generically that ``Day 2''
markets satisfy section 210(m)(1)(A) rather than requiring utilities to
demonstrate, on a case-by-case basis, the factual basis upon which
relief is requested, which they argue is required by section 210(m)(3).
American Forest & Paper and CCC contend that the Commission simply
presumed adequate wholesale markets existed in the ``Day 2'' markets,
rendering the language of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) of the statute a
nullity by not requiring applicants to set forth the factual basis on
which relief is requested. American Forest & Paper and CCC complain
that QFs have been denied the opportunity to challenge the specific
findings after sufficient notice of the factual claims being made.
14. American Forest & Paper and CCC cite Alliant Energy Corporate
Services Inc.\10\ as support for its belief that section 210(m)(3)
requires notice to each affected QF prior to the Commission making a
determination under section 210(m)(1). American Forest & Paper and CCC
compare the Commission's generic treatment of ``Day 2'' markets with
its case-by-case procedures for the reinstatement of the obligation,
despite the almost identical statutory language in sections 210(m)(3)
and 210(m)(4). American Forest & Paper argues that ``regulations cannot
alter the statutory scheme,'' \11\ stating that the procedural
requirements have been inappropriately interpreted away in the Final
Rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ 113 FERC ] 61,024 (2005).
\11\ American Forest & Paper Request for Rehearing at 13 (citing
P. Gioso & Sons, Inc. v. Occupational Safety and Health Review
Commission, 115 F.3d 100, 105 (1st Cir. 1997)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
15. In American Forest & Paper and CCC's view, Congressional intent
to encourage QF development supports interpreting section
210(m)(1)(A)(ii) as requiring the Commission to find, based on specific
evidence, that there is a meaningfully competitive market prior to
terminating the mandatory purchase obligation. American Forest & Paper
and CCC note, for example, that EPAct 2005 did not repeal PURPA and
provided for termination of the purchase requirement only if a very
particular demonstration is made.
16. Industrial Parties similarly argue that the Commission erred in
categorically finding that ``Day 2'' markets provide QFs with access to
long-term wholesale markets. Industrial Parties contend that the
Commission has ignored evidence that establishes that these markets are
in their infancy. While acknowledging that suppliers will offer QFs a
bilateral contract in the organized markets, Industrial Parties argue
that the rates and terms and conditions of such contracts typically are
not truly long-term and are discriminatory. Industrial Parties state
that the long-term markets that exist are predominantly for resale--
generators selling to load serving entities that in many cases have
divested generation--and that these contracts are typically for a
period of 6 to 18 months.
17. Industrial Parties also argue that the Commission incorrectly
assumed that access to short-term ``Day 2'' markets is equivalent to a
finding of access to long-term markets under section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii).
Industrial Parties contend that the Commission must address the
definition of ``long-term,'' arguing that the Commission appears to
view a market in excess of one year as long-term. Industrial Parties
contend that a long-term market is a market of several years' duration
or at least the timeframe for planning a new generator, which they
state is three to five years for a gas-fired combined cycle unit.
Industrial Parties ask that the Commission require utility applicants
to present information on the short- and long-term capacity obligations
of load-serving entities in the relevant markets, their practices for
meeting such obligations, and any barriers to entry into such markets.
18. Finally, American Forest & Paper and CCC argue that the
Commission's interpretation of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) violates rules
of statutory construction. Because subparagraph (C) specifically refers
to markets for the sale of capacity under both subparagraphs (A) and
(B), defining a third type of market that is ``similar'' to
subparagraphs (A) and (B), American Forest & Paper and CCC argue it is
nonsensical to conclude that the markets for capacity referenced in
subparagraphs (A)(ii) and (B)(ii) are not similar as between
themselves. American Forest & Paper and CCC therefore argue that the
Commission erred by not interpreting subparagraph (A)(ii) as imposing
qualitative requirements comparable to those imposed under subparagraph
(B)(ii). In American Forest & Paper and CCC's view, otherwise the
inclusion of a requirement that the Commission review specific
``evidence of transactions'' in subparagraph (B)(ii) would require the
Commission to ignore evidence of transactions when applying
subparagraph (A)(ii), which the Commission did not do in the Final
Rule.
Commission Determination
19. The Commission denies rehearing of the determination that the
four existing ``Day 2'' markets (MISO, PJM, NYISO, and ISO-NE) satisfy
the requirements of the second prong of section 210(m)(1)(A).
Petitioners on rehearing essentially argue that the Commission should
have imposed a standard higher than what the statutory language
literally requires, i.e., nondiscriminatory access to ``wholesale
markets for long-term sales of capacity and electric energy.'' The
Commission declined to do so in the Final Rule and we affirm that
determination here.
20. The Commission did not simply assume the existence of long-term
markets in the ``Day 2'' markets, as some petitioners argue. Rather,
the Commission found that the existence of bilateral long-term
contracts for long-term sales of capacity and energy is a sufficient
indication of a market. The Commission continued that it is reasonable
to conclude that the
[[Page 35875]]
subparagraph (A)(ii) requirement for long-term markets is met because
bilateral long-term contracts are available to participants in the
footprints of the MISO, PJM, ISO-NE, and NYISO. The Commission noted
that long-term contracts were to be expected in these markets because
of the nature of these markets. In this regard, the transmission access
offered by RTOs allows suppliers (including QFs) the opportunity to
enter into long-term bilateral contracts. RTOs have no incentive to
favor one set of suppliers over others in providing transmission
access. By eliminating pancaked rates, eliminating problems with
internal loop flows, and improving the reliability of transmission
operations over a broad multi-utility region, an RTO offers regional
transmission service which facilitates longer-term contracting
practices. This is because an RTO's footprint encompasses many
different wholesale buyers, providing significant opportunity for a
seller to reach many potential wholesale buyers.
21. In addition, organized markets operated by an RTO facilitate
long-term bilateral contracts between sellers (including QFs) and
wholesale buyers by reducing the costs to sellers of making long-term
bilateral supply commitments. In the event a seller is unable to
produce the energy required under a bilateral contract (for example,
because of an outage), the seller can easily acquire replacement energy
from the organized market at a transparent and competitive price. Even
when the seller is physically capable of producing its contractually-
required energy, the seller can acquire the energy from the RTO's
market whenever it is cheaper to do so. Both of these factors reduce
the cost to a seller of entering into a long-term bilateral
contract.\12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ Final Rule at P 120.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. With respect to bilateral long-term markets in these RTO/ISOs,
the Commission noted that no commenters argued that long-term contracts
do not exist in these markets or that QFs are precluded from entering
into them with willing buyers.\13\ The Commission also pointed out that
electronic quarterly report (EQR) filings indicate that there are in
fact contracts for long-term sales of capacity and energy in each of
the ``Day 2'' markets. The Commission concluded that the existence of
these long-term contracts is a sufficient indication that long-term
wholesale markets exist in those regions. It is telling that no
petitioner on rehearing challenges (indeed, several petitioners
concede) that long-term contracts exist in the ``Day 2'' markets.
Instead, petitioners argue that existence of such contracts does not
necessarily indicate that an adequate market for long-term energy and
capacity exists. Yet the very fact that buyers and sellers of long-term
energy and capacity have found each other, evidenced by the contracts
they have entered into, demonstrates that a market for such products
does in fact exist, which is all that the statute requires.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ Final Rule at P 117-20.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
23. The thrust of many of the arguments on rehearing is that the
Commission should have considered whether these long-term markets were
competitive or as robust as QFs would like. That is not the standard
set forth by Congress in section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii), which requires only
that a long-term market is present, not that it be competitive or that
it meet the subjective preferences of all QFs. As the Commission noted
in the Final Rule, Congress knew how to impose a more specific level of
review regarding the quality of the relevant long-term market since, in
contrast to the language it used in section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii), it
expressly used prescriptive language in section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii).
24. Section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) requires only that we find access to
``wholesale markets for long-term sales of capacity and electric
energy.'' The term ``market'' is not defined with respect to any
particular number of purchasers or sellers or the quality of the
contracts available. One definition is ``the action or business of
buying and selling; an instance of this, a commercial transaction; a
(good or bad) bargain.'' \14\ Another definition is ``a meeting
together of people for the purpose of trade by private purchase and
sales and usually not by auction.'' \15\ These standard definitions
support the Commission's finding that the ability of QF sellers to
reach purchasers and the existence of long-term contracts for capacity
and energy are sufficient to determine that ``markets'' exist for
purposes of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii). In contrast to section
210(m)(1)(A)(ii), section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii) requires us to find access
to ``competitive wholesale markets that provide a meaningful
opportunity to sell capacity, including long-term and short-term sales,
and electric energy, including long-term, short term and real-time
sales.'' Under this statutory directive, the Commission must not only
find that markets exist, but it must assess the quality of the markets
and find that they are ``competitive.'' Congress chose not to require a
finding of ``competitive'' long-term markets as a condition of invoking
section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii) and we have given reasonable meaning to this
difference in language.\16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ The New Oxford English Dictionary Vol. 1 A-M (1993 ed.).
\15\ Webster's New Collegiate Dictionary (1979 ed.).
\16\ Some petitioners argue that the Commission's reliance on
EQR reports to find the existence of a long-term market in ``Day 2''
regions is contradicted by Congress' reference to ``evidence of
transactions'' in section 210(m)(1)(B), but not in section
210(m)(1)(A). The requirement in subparagraph (B) for evidence of
transactions does not bar the use of such evidence in subparagraph
(A), but merely indicates that such evidence is not required under
subparagraph (A).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. Congress's decision to establish different standards in
subparagraphs (A) and (B) makes sense in light of the ultimate question
of whether a QF has nondiscriminatory access to potential purchasers
other than the host utility, sufficient to justify terminating the
purchase requirement, which is the overarching theme of section
210(m)(1). In the ``Day 2'' markets, which were in existence when EPAct
2005 was enacted and of which Congress was aware when it was
considering PURPA reform, energy sold under bilateral long-term
contracts as well as in the competitive day-ahead and real-time energy
markets is simply scheduled as a delivery to the RTO and ISO grid.
These market conditions make it possible for parties to enter into
long-term contracts with confidence that electric energy sold pursuant
to these contracts will be delivered. It is reasonable to conclude,
therefore, that Congress considered the criteria specified for long-
term contracts in section 210(m)(1)(B) unnecessary for section
210(m)(1)(A). This explains the distinctions embedded in the standards
set forth in sections 210(m)(1)(A) and 210(m)(1)(B).
26. It is true, as petitioners point out, that in some ``Day 2''
markets there is no formalized market for long-term sales of energy and
capacity. It may also be true that such long-term markets are nascent
and that the sales that do occur are predominantly to load serving
entities for resale. All that is required by section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii),
however, is that there be a market, not that it has particular market
attributes desired by petitioners. Petitioners have offered no
reasonable alternative to our interpretation of section 210(m)(1).
27. Petitioners are correct to point out that the Commission did
not expressly define what length of contract it considered ``long-
term'' within the meaning of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii). The Commission
explained, however, that it was relying on EQR data to find that long-
term contracts existed in the ``Day 2'' markets. Long-term contracts
are defined for EQR purposes as having a
[[Page 35876]]
term of one year or more and, thus, the Commission's findings regarding
long-term contracts in the Final Rule incorporated that definition.
While some petitioners argue that a longer-term should have been used,
we continue to believe that contracts of a year or more are
sufficiently long-term to meet the statutory requirement that there be
``wholesale markets for long-term sales of capacity and energy'' within
the meaning of section 210(m)(1)(A)(ii).\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ Although the statute contrasts real-time, day-ahead, and
long-term wholesale sales, it provides no definition of those
categories of transactions. Nevertheless, the terms real-time and
day-ahead markets were well known with respect to ISOs and RTOs at
the time EPAct 2005 was enacted and definitions of these markets
were well understood, i.e., Congress knew the meaning the terms as
used with respect to ISOs and RTOs existing at the time of enactment
of EPAct 2005. Additionally, the Commission at the time of enactment
of EPAct 2005 had for years defined long-term contracts under the
OATT as one year or longer. Similarly, the Commission has treated
power sales with a contract term of greater than one year to be
``long-term'' for reporting purposes. See, e.g., Revised Public
Utility Filing Requirements, Order No. 2001, 67 FR 31043, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ] 31,127 (2002), Order No. 2001-A, 100 FERC ] 61,074,
reconsideration and clarification denied, Order No. 2001-B, 100 FERC
] 61,342 (2002). We thus believe it is reasonable to use the
convention of treating contracts of a year or more as ``long-term''
consistent with our longstanding practice.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
28. We note that the Commission has initiated a proceeding to
explore ways to improve the operation of wholesale organized electric
markets administered by RTOs and ISOs, including actions the Commission
might take to further improve opportunities for long-term contracting
in RTO and ISO regions.\18\ While we disagree with petitioners who
argue that QFs above 20 MW do not have access to long-term contracting
opportunities in organized markets, or that section 210(m)(1)(A)
requires us to find ``competitive'' or ``robust'' contracting
opportunities, we are taking steps to facilitate additional
opportunities for long-term contracting.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized Electric
Markets, 119 FERC ] 61,306.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
29. The Commission also rejects arguments that it may not make
generic findings in this rulemaking as to the ``Day 2'' markets
satisfying the requirements of section 210(m)(1)(A). The Commission has
broad discretion to adopt generic policy or make generic findings
through the rulemaking process rather than case-by-case
adjudications.\19\ Establishing generic findings in this rulemaking
provides all parties, including electric utilities and QFs alike, a
reasonable chance to be heard on common issues that arise in various
market structures and involving classes of QFs. Indeed, no party has
sought rehearing of the Commission's conclusion that the ``Day 2''
markets satisfy the first prong of section 210(m)(1)(A). It is just as
appropriate for the Commission to find generically, in this rulemaking,
that long-term markets exist in the ``Day 2'' RTO/ISOs as it is to find
that those RTO/ISOs operate independently administered, auction-based
day ahead and real time wholesale markets within the meaning of section
210(m)(1)(A)(i).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ Securities and Exchange Comm'n v. Chenery, 332 U.S. 194,
202-03, reh'g denied, 332 U.S. 747 (1947).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
30. These generic findings do not violate the requirements of
section 210(m)(3), as some petitioners argue. Under section 210(m)(1),
the Commission must terminate the purchase requirement if it makes
certain findings regarding nondiscriminatory access to specified
markets. That provision of the statute does not specify the particular
procedural mechanism the Commission must use in making those findings
and, thus, the Commission has discretion to act through a rulemaking,
case-by-case determinations, or some combination thereof. Section
210(m)(3) does not, as the petitioners appear to assume, require the
Commission to await an application from an electric utility in order to
make any of the particular findings specified in section 210(m)(1).
While the Commission made certain generic findings in the Final Rule,
it also required electric utilities (including those in the ``Day 2''
markets) that seek relief from the obligation to enter into new
contracts or obligations with QFs to file an application pursuant to
regulations implementing section 210(m)(3).\20\ Thus, the Commission
has incorporated the application process into its implementing
regulations, combining the application procedures with generic findings
and rebuttable presumptions to streamline the Commission's review. The
resulting structure is fully consistent with the requirements of both
sections 210(m)(1) and 210(m)(3).\21\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ Final Rule at P 102.
\21\ The comparative structures of sections 210(m)(3) and
210(m)(4) do not support a different outcome. Section 210(m)(4)
specifies the procedural requirements for reinstating the purchase
requirement after the Commission has entered an order terminating
that requirement and, thus, does not govern the Commission's initial
procedures for acting to terminate the requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. Section 210(m)(1)(B)
31. Section 210(m)(1)(B) requires termination of the purchase
obligation if a QF has nondiscriminatory access to (i) transmission and
interconnection services provided by a Commission-approved regional
transmission entity pursuant to an open access tariff and (ii)
competitive wholesale markets providing a meaningful opportunity to
sell long-term and short-term capacity and electricity to buyers other
than the interconnecting electric utility. The Commission concluded in
the Final Rule that the CAISO and SPP are regional transmission
entities within the meaning of the first prong of section 210(m)(1)(B),
but made no findings as to the second prong for any market, including
those operated by CAISO and SPP. The Commission also stated that any
future determinations of what transmission providers qualify as a
regional transmission entity within the meaning of the first prong will
be made on a case-by-case basis. The Commission provided examples of
factors it may consider in making that determination, such as
sufficient regional scope or configuration of the multiple discrete
transmission systems the regional transmission entity controls.
Requests for Rehearing
32. Occidental argues that the Commission erred in reserving the
discretion to deem an entity a ``Commission-approved regional
transmission entity'' in the context of a section 210(m) proceeding.
Because section 210(m)(1)(B)(i) refers to a ``Commission-approved''
entity, Occidental argues that a transmission provider must have been
deemed by the Commission to be a ``regional transmission entity'' prior
to the filing of an application for relief from the purchase
requirement.
33. PacifiCorp argues that evidence of robust bilateral markets or
actual sales by a QF to wholesale non-PURPA purchasers should be
considered when the Commission determines whether QFs have the
requisite ``meaningful opportunity'' to sell capacity and energy to
other buyers within the meaning of section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii). PacifiCorp
offers factual examples of QF plans to participate in wholesale
markets, depending on market prices, although it acknowledges that the
examples it used are extreme and did not materialize. PacifiCorp asks
the Commission to establish a rebuttable presumption that evidence of a
robust bilateral market featuring liquid trading points, or actual
sales by QFs, should be adopted for purposes of implementing section
210(m)(1)(B)(ii). Alternatively, PacifiCorp asks the Commission to
provide further guidance as to how the standards of that section will
be applied.
[[Page 35877]]
34. With regard to the SPP market, OG&E argues that the Commission
erred in declining to find that utilities operating in SPP also satisfy
the second prong of section 210(m)(1)(B) or to provide guidance with
respect to the information required for utilities to make such a
showing. OG&E argues that its comments on the NOPR adequately
demonstrated that QFs have nondiscriminatory access to competitive
markets within SPP. If the evidence it submitted was insufficient, OG&E
claims the Commission erred by failing to provide guidance as to what
type of information would satisfy the Commission's requirements. OG&E
contends that such guidance would reduce the costs and burdens
associated with preparing an application under section 210(m).
35. With regard to the CAISO market, Cogeneration Association of
California argues that the lack of new construction in California,
despite a clear supply shortage, is evidence that competitive long-term
markets do not exist in that region. Cogeneration Association of
California also argues that competitive markets must have price
transparency, including both pricing terms and non-price terms,
contending that there is virtually no disclosure to any market
participant of prices secured or approved for capacity or energy
purchased by utilities. Industrial Parties point to other
characteristics of the California market that, in their view, would
preclude a finding of access to sufficiently competitive markets, such
as exit fees, the lack of direct access, and the dominance of utility
generation in an otherwise thinly traded market.
Commission Determination
36. We disagree with Occidental's assertion that a transmission
entity must have been deemed by the Commission to be a ``regional
transmission entity'' prior to the filing of an application for relief
from the purchase requirement. As we explained in the Final Rule,
section 210 does not define regional transmission entity and,
therefore, the Commission has discretion in interpreting that term. At
the time of enactment of section 210(m), Congress was aware of the
existence of Commission-approved RTOs and ISOs with varying degrees of
regional scope (some spanning many states and some covering only large
individual states), as well as the continuing voluntary development of
various types of transmission organizations.\22\ It is reasonable to
conclude that Congress, by using the generic term ``regional
transmission entity'' in section 210(m)(1)(B)(i), intended to leave it
to the Commission's discretion to determine on a case-be-case basis
whether or not an entity is regional within the meaning of the
statute.\23\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\22\ Indeed Congress, in EPAct 2005 incorporated into the
Federal Power Act (FPA) definitions of RTO and ISO, with the RTO
definition specifically recognizing that such an entity must be of
sufficient ``regional'' scope, whereas the ISO definition does not
contain a sufficient regional scope element. Pub. L. 109-58, 1291,
119 Stat. 594, 984 (2005) (codified at 16 U.S.C. 796(27), (28)). Cf.
Pub. L. 109-58, 1286, 119 Stat. 594, 981 (2005) (adding section
206(a)(2) to the FPA, allowing Commission to order refunds for
certain sales in ``organized'' markets).
\23\ Congress in section 210(m) did not use the term ``regional
transmission organization'' and thus presumably did not intend to
limit a ``regional transmission entity'' to the regional scope
requirements of Order No. 2000. Regional Transmission Organizations,
Order No. 2000, 65 FR 809 (Jan. 6, 2000), FERC Stats. & Regs. ]
31,089 (1999), order on reh'g, Order No. 2000-A, 65 FR 12088 (Mar.
8, 2000), FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,092 (2000), dismissed sub nom.
Pub. Util. Dist. No. 1 of Snohomish County, Washington v. FERC, 272
F.3d 607 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
37. We also deny rehearing of the decision not to find in the
context of this rulemaking that the SPP market satisfies the second
prong of section 210(m)(1)(B). While OG&E claims to have provided in
its initial comments evidence demonstrating the quality of the SPP
market,\24\ what OG&E provided was little more than cursory comments
and a description of bidding procedures that are being adopted in
Oklahoma. Section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii) requires a showing of ``competitive
wholesale markets that provide a meaningful opportunity to sell
capacity, including long-term and short-term sales, and electric
energy, including long-term, short-term and real-time sales, to buyers
other than the utility to which the qualifying facility is
interconnected.'' This provision also provides that ``[i]n determining
whether a meaningful opportunity to sell exists the Commission shall
consider, among other factors, evidence of transactions within the
relevant market.'' We do not find OG&E's cursory submission sufficient
to meet the statutory requirements. Moreover OG&E did not include any
evidence of transactions in the SPP market. There was, and continues to
be, an insufficient record in this proceeding to find that the SPP
market satisfies the second prong of section 210(m)(1)(B).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ OG&E Comments at 4-6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
38. With regard to OG&E's and PacifiCorp's requests for further
guidance, we believe that the statutory language requiring that a QF
have a meaningful opportunity to sell capacity and energy to buyers
other than the interconnected utility means an actual, and not just
theoretical, opportunity. Concrete evidence of transactions would
further that finding, as the statutory language implies. To the extent
such evidence is not available, we would expect at a minimum a
petitioning electric utility to explain any lack of evidence of
transactions and to provide a reasoned explanation of how the
Commission could find that a meaningful opportunity to sell to buyers
other than the interconnected utility exists in the absence of a
history of transactions.\25\ PacifiCorp's evidence of QF proposals that
never reached fruition does not provide an adequate basis for the
Commission to make any presumptions regarding whether particular
markets satisfy the requirements of section 210(m)(1)(B)(ii). We
continue to believe that it is best to address on a case-by-case basis
whether non-RTO/ISOs and RTO/ISOs that do not have both auction-based
real-time and day-ahead markets satisfy those statutory
requirements.\26\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\25\ The Commission is aware that certain types of evidence of
transactions may contain information that an electric utility
considers to be confidential. If information is considered
confidential by the electric utility, procedures exist to maintain
its confidentiality.
\26\ Final Rule at P 145.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
39. The claims of Cogeneration Association of California and the
Industrial Parties regarding the lack of a sufficiently competitive
market in California can be addressed in any individual cases
concerning California. We note that the CAISO has been found only to
satisfy section 210(m)(1)(B)(i) and that a separate finding of
``competitive wholesale markets'' is required under section
210(m)(1)(B)(ii). Thus, if a California utility makes a filing pursuant
to section 210(m)(3) and Sec. 292.310 of the Commission's regulations,
and claims that it satisfies the section 210(m)(1)(B) criteria for
relief from the purchase obligation, the issue of whether ``competitive
wholesale markets'' exist will be an issue in that proceeding and the
burden will be on the applicant to make the required demonstration.\27\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ The Commission also left open the option of California
utilities seeking a determination that the California market
satisfies section 210(m)(1)(A) by filing requests for declaratory
orders, after there is a functioning ``Day 2'' RTO/ISO in
California. Final Rule at P 157.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. A Single Standard of Relief
40. As explained above, the Commission concluded in the Final Rule
that the most reasonable interpretation of section 210(m)(1) is that
Congress, in setting forth three discrete tests for three different
types of markets, was directing the Commission to differentiate among
three different
[[Page 35878]]
markets, access to which would require termination of the purchase
requirement provided such access is available on a nondiscriminatory
basis. A number of petitioners had advocated a different interpretation
of section 210(m)(1), arguing that subparagraphs (A), (B), and (C),
when read together, establish a single standard for relief from the
purchase requirement. In their view, these separate provisions together
require electric utilities to demonstrate that a QF would remain
economically viable or would otherwise have access to the technical
equivalent of the purchase requirement in order to terminate the
purchase requirement. The Commission rejected that view by interpreting
section 210(m)(1) as establishing different standards for each of the
three types of markets identified in subparagraphs (A), (B), and (C).
Requests for Rehearing
41. American Forest & Paper and CCC again challenge the
Commission's determination that the three standards of relief described
in section 210(m)(1) were intended to be different in terms of the
organization and competitiveness of the relevant market or the
evidentiary showings required for each. They argue that EPAct 2005 did
not repeal PURPA or the Commission's obligation to encourage QF
development and, therefore, the Commission's interpretation of section
210(m)(1) is unreasonable. American Forest & Paper and CCC suggest that
section 210(m)(1)(C) clearly requires markets under subparagraphs (A),
(B) and (C) to be of similar competitive quality since markets that
satisfy subparagraph (C) must be ``similar'' to those described in
subparagraphs (A) and (B). American Forest & Paper and CCC conclude
that the Commission has adopted an unreasonable statutory construction
by interpreting section 210(m)(1) as referring to three distinct types
of markets.
Commission Determination
42. The Commission denies requests for rehearing of the
determination not to adopt a single test to evaluate whether the
requirements of section 210(m)(1) are met. We continue to believe, as
we found in the Final Rule, that the most reasonable interpretation of
section 210(m)(1) is that Congress, in setting forth discrete tests for
three different types of markets, was requiring the Commission to
differentiate among these markets and the differing circumstances they
present in determining whether a utility is relieved of the purchase
requirement. As discussed above, this interpretation is supported by
the different language Congress used in subparagraphs (A) and (B) and
the consequent need to make meaningful distinctions in the explicit
statutory language Congress used. Otherwise, subparagraphs (A) and (B)
presumably would have been collapsed by Congress into one test.
43. We agree the reference in section 210(m)(1)(C) to markets that
are of ``comparable competitive quality as markets described in
subparagraphs (A) and (B)'' indicates Congress' belief that those two
types of markets share a certain set of competitive qualities. It does
not follow, however, that the Commission should disregard the specific
statutory tests in each of those subparagraphs when applying section
210(m)(1). The structure of section 210(m)(1), which separately
describes different types of markets, makes clear that Congress was
establishing a particular set of tests for the Commission to apply. In
the Final Rule, the Commission adopted the most reasonable
interpretation of subparagraph (C)--that Congress believed the two
types of markets identified in subparagraphs (A) and (B), while
distinct between themselves, contain certain competitive qualities that
justify termination of the purchase requirement for any QF with
nondiscriminatory access to those markets. Subparagraph (C) directs the
Commission to consider these competitive qualities when analyzing
whether there are other markets that, while not meeting the specific
requirements of subparagraphs (A) and (B), are sufficiently competitive
to justify termination of the purchase requirement.
44. The fact that the markets identified in subparagraphs (A) and
(B) contain certain competitive qualities does not mean that they are
the same type of market, or that a single test must be adopted for
determining whether a particular market satisfies the requirements of a
particular subparagraph. Such an interpretation would undermine
Congress's decision to separately identify the two types of markets
that it believes are sufficiently competitive to justify termination of
the purchase requirement. It would also conflict with the particular
determinations to be made under each of the subparagraphs. Subparagraph
(A) explicitly refers to both ``day ahead and real time'' (i.e., ``Day
2'') organized markets. RTO/ISO day-ahead and real time markets are
operated pursuant to Commission tariffs containing market rules and
market mitigation aimed at preventing exercises of market power. It is
reasonable to conclude that Congress assumed these markets to be
sufficiently competitive, in combination with markets for long-term
contracts, to justify termination of the mandatory purchase obligation.
45. As we noted in the Final Rule, ``Day 2'' markets are generally
recognized as providing greater opportunities for QFs and other
independent generators to make sales to a large number of buyers than
other markets because the existence of day-ahead and real-time energy
markets allows all competing generators to submit bids to participate
on a nondiscriminatory basis in a market from which many buyers over a
large area make purchases. While the ``Day 1'' markets also provide
opportunities for independent generators to compete, the markets are
more limited. It is therefore not surprising that the factual showing
required under section 210(m)(1)(B) is more difficult relative to
section 210(m)(1)(A), which enjoys the benefit of the ``Day 2'' market
structures. These different standards support, rather than undermine,
the Commission's interpretation that subparagraphs (A) and (B)
separately identify the particular markets that Congress has deemed
sufficiently competitive to justify termination of the purchase
requirement.
46. The Commission's task under section 210(m)(1)(C) is, therefore,
to determine the set of competitive qualities that are shared by
markets satisfying the requirements of subparagraphs (A) and (B).
Recognizing this task, the Commission declined in the Final Rule to
adopt any bright line tests when applying subparagraph (C). Simply put,
the common objective of subparagraphs (A) and (B), and therefore
subparagraph (C), is the identification of a wholesale marketplace
where QFs have alternatives to their local utility to sell their
electric energy. We believe the three-tiered structure of section
210(m)(1) indicates a finding by Congress that two particular market
designs provide those alternatives, while directing the Commission to
consider whether other market designs might as well.
47. Congress could have stated a broad, general finding to be made
by the Commission such as ``workably competitive markets.'' Instead,
Congress tailored subparagraphs (A) and (B) to establish criteria
specific to each market design that, in its view, provide sufficient
sales alternatives for QFs. Under these circumstances, we believe it
appropriate to use the market designs identified in subparagraphs (A)
and (B) as guides when analyzing whether an alternative market design
satisfies the
[[Page 35879]]
requirements of subparagraph (C). For example, the Commission found in
the Final Rule that the markets in ERCOT satisfy the statutory
requirements of subparagraph (C) because they are of comparable quality
to those described in subparagraph (A). We continue to believe that
finding is appropriate and note that no petitioner challenges it on
rehearing.
48. Finally, while it is true that EPAct 2005 did not repeal PURPA
or the Commission's obligation to encourage QF development, enactment
of section 210(m) of PURPA clearly changed the rights of QFs under
PURPA. The Commission has no discretion other than to terminate the
purchase requirement if it finds that a QF has nondiscriminatory access
to any of the markets described in section 210(m)(1)(A), (B) or (C). It
would be inappropriate for the Commission to ignore this mandate by
implementing section 210(m)(1) in a way that undermines the specific
standards of relief Congress chose to establish in the statute.
B. Nondiscriminatory Access to a Market
49. The Commission also must determine that a QF has
nondiscriminatory access to a PURPA section 210(m)(1) market in order
to terminate the purchase requirement. In the Final Rule, the
Commission adopted several presumptions to be used in determining
whether access to a particular market is available on a
nondiscriminatory basis in order to streamline processing of
applications for termination of the purchase requirement.
50. First, the Final Rule found that a QF's eligibility for service
under an OATT, or a reciprocity tariff filed by a non-public utility,
creates a rebuttable presumption that the QF has nondiscriminatory
access to the relevant market. Second, the Commission adopted a
rebuttable presumption that QFs interconnected with electric utility
members of a ``Day 2'' RTO/ISO have nondiscriminatory access to the
``Day 2'' market. Finally, regardless of available transfer capability
(ATC) under an OATT or location within a ``Day 2'' market, the Final
Rule establishes an additional rebuttable presumption that QFs with a
net capacity no greater than 20 MW do not have nondiscriminatory access
to wholesale markets.
51. These rebuttable presumptions were designed to work together to
facilitate prompt Commission review of requests to terminate the
purchase requirement within the 90-day time frame mandated in the
statute. Various petitioners challenge the adoption of these
presumptions on rehearing, which we address below.
1. The OATT
52. The Commission first established a rebuttable presumption that
a QF has nondiscriminatory access to a market if it is eligible for
service under a Commission-approved OATT, or Commission-filed
reciprocity tariff, and Commission-approved interconnection rules.\28\
If the Commission determines that a particular market meets the
criteria of section 210(m)(1)(A), (B), or (C), and a QF in that market
is eligible for service under an OATT or reciprocity tariff, a QF may
seek to rebut the presumption of access to the market by providing
specific and credible evidence that the QF does not have
nondiscriminatory access due to operational characteristics or
transmission constraints. If the QF is unable to make this
demonstration, the purchase requirement will be terminated.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ Transmission providers are required to provide
interconnection as well as transmission services on a
nondiscriminatory basis under their OATTs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
53. In the Final Rule, the Commission determined that only issues
other than issues related to the provision of open access transmission
under the OATT would be considered when analyzing whether the
presumption of nondiscriminatory access to markets has been rebutted.
The Commission rejected requests to allow a QF to litigate open access
implementation issues in the context of these 90-day applications,
concluding that complaint proceedings are the appropriate forum for
such disputes. The Commission also rejected arguments that it is
unreasonable to rely on a presumption that a Commission-approved OATT
provides nondiscriminatory access to markets in light of the then-
pending NOPR in the OATT reform rulemaking, Docket Nos. RM05-17, et
al., in which reforms to the pro forma OATT had been proposed.
Requests for Rehearing
54. Occidental challenges the Commission's reliance on an OATT to
create a rebuttable presumption that QFs have nondiscriminatory access
to the relevant wholesale markets. Occidental argues that the
Commission's actions in the OATT reform rulemaking have demonstrated
that, notwithstanding the existence of an OATT, there remain continuing
opportunities for undue discrimination by transmission entities.
Occidental contends that the Commission's statement in the Final Rule
that it had not found actual discrimination in the OATT reform
rulemaking is inconsistent with findings in the OATT reform NOPR that
deficiencies in the OATT needed to be addressed. In Occidental's view,
the Commission's determination in the OATT reform NOPR that there are
remaining opportunities for undue discrimination bear directly on the
finding that the Commission must make under section 210(m) that a
utility is administering its OATT in a nondiscriminatory manner.
55. Occidental argues that the Commission's determination that only
issues not related to the provision of open access transmission under
the OATT may be raised to rebut the presumption of nondiscriminatory
access is inconsistent with the statutory language of section 210(m)
and is a violation of due process. Industrial Parties assert that the
Commission must consider evidence of discrimination when analyzing
whether the presumption has been rebutted. Failure to do so would, in
their view, violate the Commission's statutory obligation to eradicate
discrimination.
56. Occidental further argues that the Commission should clarify
that QFs under section 210(m)(1)(B) and (C) have the same opportunity
to rebut the presumption of nondiscriminatory access as QFs under
section 210(m)(1)(A). Occidental notes that the Commission lists
several factors in the Final Rule as a possible rebuttal to a finding
of nondiscriminatory access to the markets set forth in subparagraph
(A), but that it is not clear if the factors are also relevant to the
question of whether the purchase obligation should be terminated under
subparagraphs (B) and (C). If the Commission does not grant
clarification, Occidental requests rehearing on this issue.
57. Cogeneration Association of California argues that existence of
an OATT is insufficient to guarantee nondiscriminatory access since it
may not provide physical transmission rights. Because QFs generate
electricity as a necessary by-product of their service to their thermal
hosts, Cogeneration Association of California contends that a
cogenerator must have a physical location to deliver the electricity.
Cogeneration Association of California argues that this requires
physical transmission rights that recognize the