Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity Markets, 43564-43620 [06-6494]
Download as PDF
43564
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
18 CFR Part 42
[Docket No. RM06–8–000; Order No. 681]
Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights
in Organized Electricity Markets
Issued July 20, 2006.
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
AGENCY:
The Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission is amending its
regulations under the Federal Power Act
to require transmission organizations
that are public utilities with organized
electricity markets to make available
long-term firm transmission rights that
satisfy certain guidelines adopted by the
Commission in this Final Rule. The
Commission is taking this action
pursuant to section 1233(b) of the
Energy Policy Act of 2005, [Pub. L. 109–
58, § 1233(b), 119 Stat. 594, 960 (2005).]
DATES: Effective Date: This Final Rule
will become effective August 31, 2006.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Udi
E. Helman (Technical Information),
Office of Energy Markets and Reliability,
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,
888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC
20426. (202) 502–8080.
Roland Wentworth (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Markets
and Reliability, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
(202) 502–8262.
Wilbur C. Earley (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Markets
and Reliability, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
(202) 502–8087.
Harry Singh (Technical Information),
Office of Enforcement, Division of
Energy Market Oversight, Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
(202) 502–6341.
Jeffery S. Dennis (Legal Information),
Office of the General Counsel, Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
(202) 502–6027.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
SUMMARY:
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Table of Contents
Paragraph
Nos.
I. Background .............................
A. The Development of
ISOs and RTOs ................
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Paragraph
Nos.
Paragraph
Nos.
Jkt 208001
3.
3.
B. Interest in Long-Term
Firm Transmission
Rights ...............................
C. Staff Paper on LongTerm Transmission
Rights ...............................
D. Energy Policy Act of
2005 .................................
E. Notice of Proposed Rulemaking .............................
II. Discussion .............................
A. Overview ........................
B. Definitions ......................
1. Organized Electricity Market ...........
2. Load Serving Entity
and Service Obligation ...........................
3. Long-Term Power
Supply Arrangement
4. Transmission Organization ....................
C. Commission Interpretation of EPAct 2005 Requirements .......................
D. Commission’s Approach, Regional Flexibility, and Regional
Seams Issues ...................
E. Guidelines for the Design and Administration
of Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights in
Organized Electricity
Markets ............................
Guideline (1)—Specify
Source, Sink and
Quantity ...................
Guideline (2)—LongTerm Hedge That
Cannot Be Modified
Guideline (3)—Rights
Made Available by
Expansions Go to
Parties That Pay for
the Upgrade ..............
Guideline (4)—Term of
Rights Must be Sufficient to Hedge LongTerm Power Supply
Arrangements ...........
Guideline (5)—Load
Serving Entities with
Long-Term Power
Supply Arrangements Have Priority
to the Existing System ............................
Guideline (6)—Rights
are Reassignable to
Follow Load .............
Guideline (7)—Auction
Not Required ............
Guideline (8)—Balance
Adverse Economic
Impacts .....................
F. Transmission Planning
and Expansion ................
G. Alternative Designs for
Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights .................
H. Miscellaneous Comments ...............................
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
6.
11.
14.
15.
16.
16.
24.
24.
34.
55.
63.
70.
84.
108.
108.
122.
185.
217.
273.
331.
361.
394.
429.
I. Implementation of the
Final Rule and Compliance Issues ......................
III. Information Collection
Statement ................................
IV. Environmental Analysis ......
V. Regulatory Flexibility Act
Certification ............................
VI. Document Availability ........
VII. Effective Date and Congressional Notification .................
496.
500.
501.
502.
505.
Before Commissioners: Joseph T.
Kelliher, Chairman; Nora Mead
Brownell, and Suedeen G. Kelly; Order
No. 681; Final Rule
1. In this Final Rule, the Commission
is amending its regulations to require
each transmission organization that is a
public utility with one or more
organized electricity markets to make
available long-term firm transmission
rights that satisfy each of the guidelines
established by the Commission in this
Final Rule. We take this action pursuant
to section 1233 of the Energy Policy Act
of 2005 (EPAct 2005), which added new
section 217 to the Federal Power Act
(FPA).1 This Final Rule will require
each transmission organization subject
to its requirements to file with the
Commission, no later than January 29,
2007, either (1) tariff sheets and rate
schedules that make available long-term
firm transmission rights that satisfy each
of the guidelines set forth in the final
regulations, or (2) an explanation of how
its current tariff and rate schedules
already provide for long-term firm
transmission rights that satisfy each of
the guidelines. A transmission
organization approved by the
Commission for operation after January
29, 2007 will be required to satisfy the
requirements of this Final Rule.
2. The guidelines adopted in this
Final Rule will give transmission
organizations the flexibility to propose
designs for long-term firm transmission
rights that reflect regional preferences
and accommodate their regional market
designs, while also ensuring that the
objectives of Congress expressed in new
section 217(b)(4) of the FPA are met. As
described in more detail below, the
Commission will allow regional
flexibility in setting the terms of the
rights, but long-term firm transmission
rights must be made available with
terms (and/or rights to renewal) that are
sufficient to meet the reasonable needs
of load serving entities to support longterm power supply arrangements used
to satisfy their service obligations.
458.
477.
479.
1 Pub. L. 109–58, § 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 957
(2005).
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
I. Background
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
A. The Development of ISOs and RTOs
3. In Order No. 888, the Commission
found that undue discrimination and
anticompetitive practices existed in the
provision of electric transmission
service in interstate commerce.2
Accordingly, the Commission required
all public utilities that own, control or
operate facilities used for transmitting
electric energy in interstate commerce to
file open access transmission tariffs
(OATTs) containing certain non-price
terms and conditions and to
‘‘functionally unbundle’’ wholesale
power services from transmission
services.3 In addition, the Commission
found in Order No. 888 that
Independent System Operators (ISOs)
had the potential to aid in remedying
undue discrimination and
accomplishing comparable access 4 and
set out 11 principles for assessing ISO
proposals submitted to the
Commission.5 Following Order No. 888,
several voluntary ISOs were established
and approved by the Commission.
4. In light of the creation of these ISOs
and other changes in the electric
industry, the Commission issued Order
No. 2000.6 In that order, the
Commission concluded that traditional
management of the transmission grid by
vertically integrated electric utilities
was inadequate to support the efficient
and reliable operation of transmission
facilities necessary for continued
development of competitive electricity
markets 7 and that opportunities for
2 Promoting Wholesale Competition Through
Open Access Non-discriminatory Transmission
Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded
Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities,
Order No. 888, 61 FR 21540 (May 10, 1996), FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,036 at 31,682 (1996), order on
reh’g, Order No. 888–A, 62 FR 12274 (March 14,
1997), FERC Stats & Regs. ¶ 31,048 (1997), order on
reh’g, Order No. 888–B, 81 FERC ¶ 61,248 (1997),
order on reh’g, Order No. 888–C, 82 FERC ¶ 61,046
(1998), aff’d in relevant part sub nom. Transmission
Access Policy Study Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667
(D.C. Cir. 2000), aff’d sub nom. New York v. FERC,
535 U.S. 1 (2002).
3 Under functional unbundling, the public utility
is required to: (1) Take wholesale transmission
services under the same tariff of general
applicability as it offers its customers; (2) state
separate rates for wholesale generation,
transmission and ancillary services; and (3) rely on
the same electronic information network that its
transmission customers rely on to obtain
information about the utility’s transmission system.
Id. at 31,654.
4 Order No. 888 at 31,655; Order No. 888–A at
30,184.
5 Order No. 888 at 31,730.
6 Regional Transmission Organizations, Order No.
2000, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089 (1999), order on
reh’g, Order No. 2000–A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶
31,092 (2000), aff’d sub nom. Public Utility District
No. 1 of Snohomish County, Washington v. FERC,
272 F.3d 607 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
7 Order No. 2000 at 30,992–93 and 31,014–15.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
undue discrimination continued to
exist.8 As a result, the Commission
adopted rules to facilitate the voluntary
development of Regional Transmission
Organizations (RTOs). The Commission
concluded that RTOs would provide
several benefits, including regional
transmission pricing, improved
congestion management, and more
effective management of parallel path
flows.9 In Order No. 2000, the
Commission established the minimum
characteristics and functions that an
RTO must satisfy to gain Commission
approval.10 Under Order No. 2000, the
Commission has approved the voluntary
formation of a number of RTOs.
5. Most of the RTOs and ISOs operate
organized markets for energy and/or
ancillary services in addition to
providing transmission service under a
single transmission tariff. Most of these
markets utilize a congestion
management system based on
Locational Marginal Pricing (LMP).
Congestion is defined as the inability to
inject and withdraw additional energy
at particular locations in the network
due to the fact that the injections and
withdrawals would cause power flows
over a specific transmission facility to
violate the reliability limits for that
facility. The market operator manages
congestion by scheduling and
dispatching generators that can meet
load in the presence of congestion.
Financially, in LMP markets the price of
congestion is measured as the difference
in the cost of energy in the spot market
at two different locations in the
network. When such price differences
occur, a congestion charge is assessed to
transmission users based on their nodal
injections and withdrawals. These price
differences can be variable and difficult
to predict. In order to manage the risk
associated with the variability in prices
due to transmission congestion, these
markets use various forms of financial
transmission rights (FTRs) 11 to allow
market participants who hold the rights
to protect against such price risks. In
most cases, these FTRs have terms of
one year or less. In general, load serving
entities receive FTRs through either
direct allocation or through a two-step
process in which the load serving entity
is first allocated auction revenue rights
(ARRs) and then either uses those rights
at 31,015–17.
at 31,024.
10 Id. at 31,106 et seq.
11 While ‘‘FTR’’ is sometimes used to refer to
‘‘firm transmission rights,’’ in this Final Rule we
use this acronym to refer to the various forms of
financial transmission rights that exist in organized
electricity markets. In some markets, these are
referred to as congestion revenue rights or
transmission congestion contracts.
PO 00000
8 Id.
9 Id.
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43565
to purchase FTRs, or has the ability
under the transmission organization
tariff to convert them to FTRs.12
B. Interest in Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights
6. In recent years, interest in longterm firm transmission rights in
organized electricity markets has
increased, stemming in large part from
a desire of some market participants to
obtain rights that replicate the
transmission service that was available
to them prior to the formation of the
organized electricity markets and
remains available today in regions
without organized electricity markets.
The principal concern of these market
participants is the inability to obtain a
fixed, long-term level of service under
pricing arrangements that hedge the
congestion cost risk that they face in the
organized electricity markets.
7. There are several important
differences between transmission
service under the Order No. 888 pro
forma Open Access Transmission Tariff
(OATT) and transmission rights in
organized electricity markets that use
LMP and FTRs.13 However, the
differences that are most relevant for
purposes of this Final Rule concern the
management of congestion, the recovery
of congestion costs and the availability
of long-term service arrangements.
8. Under the OATT, the transmission
provider in the first instance manages
congestion by redispatching its own or
its customers’ network resources as
needed to accommodate a transmission
constraint; the OATT provides no
mechanism by which firm point-topoint transmission customers can
participate directly in congestion
management.14 However, in the
organized electricity markets that use
LMP, the transmission organization
manages congestion through the use of
locational prices that are determined by
bids and offers by markets participants
at given locations. This means that all
available resources under an LMP
system can participate in redispatch for
congestion management because they all
receive the congestion price signal. As
a result, a transmission organization in
a region with an organized electricity
market is less likely to have to invoke
12 For a more detailed discussion, see Long-Term
Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity
Markets, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 71 FR
6693 (Feb. 9, 2006), FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,598
at P 27 (2006) (NOPR). As we noted in the NOPR,
ARRs confer the right to collect revenues from the
subsequent FTR auction.
13 A detailed discussion of transmission rights in
traditional and organized markets was presented in
the NOPR at P 15–33.
14 The transmission provider may also need to
curtail service to certain customers.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43566
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
transmission loading relief procedures
and service curtailments than a
transmission provider under the OATT.
9. The recovery of congestion costs
also differs greatly between regions with
and without organized electricity
markets. In regions where transmission
service is provided under the OATT, a
transmission customer that takes
network service or firm point-to-point
transmission service is not charged
directly for the costs of the redispatch
that may be required to accommodate its
use of the transmission system. For
example, a firm point-to-point
transmission customer is allowed to
take service up to its contractual
entitlement while paying only a fixed
demand charge. Also, although a
network customer must pay a share of
any redispatch costs that the
transmission provider and other
network customers incur, its cost
responsibility is determined after the
fact as a load ratio share of the total
redispatch costs that are incurred on
behalf of all users of the system over a
given time period. While this type of
pricing may not present the customer
with a price signal that accurately
reflects all of the costs occasioned by
the customer’s use of the system, it does
provide price certainty. In addition,
both network service and firm point-topoint transmission service can be
obtained under long-term contracts.
These attributes of OATT transmission
service result in a less volatile price for
transmission service over the long-term,
which in turn can help facilitate the
planning and financing of large
generation facilities and other long-term
power supply arrangements.
10. In contrast, a transmission
organization in a region with an
organized electricity market recovers
congestion costs measured as
differences in the locational price of
energy. Because locational prices
include a congestion cost component
(which can be positive, negative or
zero), a participant in an organized
electricity market faces the prospect of
paying a congestion charge for many of
its transactions. Locational pricing and
price-based congestion management
provide the market participant with
much of the information it needs to
make cost effective decisions regarding
energy consumption and use of the
transmission system (as well as
investment in new generation and
transmission upgrades). However, the
FTRs that transmission organizations
currently provide to hedge congestion
charges for using existing transmission
capacity (as opposed to incremental
transmission expansions) are generally
available for terms of only one year or
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
less. This can create uncertainty for the
market participant who wants to
procure supplies on a long-term basis
because it will not know from year to
year with any degree of certainty
whether its award of FTRs will be
sufficient to meet its needs. Some
market participants have expressed
concern that this uncertainty makes it
more difficult to finance long-term
power supply arrangements.
C. Staff Paper on Long-Term
Transmission Rights
11. In May 2005, the Commission
released a Staff Paper that provided
background and solicited comments on
whether long-term transmission rights
were needed in the ISO and RTO
markets, and if so, how to implement
them.15 A number of commenters on the
Staff Paper argued that the failure of
transmission organizations to offer
transmission rights with terms greater
than one year is a key deficiency in the
markets that produces increased
financial risk due to congestion price
uncertainty, the failure of forward
energy markets to form, and barriers to
investment in new generation capacity.
Most of the parties in this group stressed
that not all transmission capacity
should be given over to long-term rights,
but that there should be an amount
sufficient to cover at least base-load
generation resources and perhaps
renewable energy generators.
12. A second group of commenters on
the Staff Paper largely agreed with the
first that long-term rights should be
introduced, but argued that this should
take place within the framework of
existing FTR market designs and follow
a cautious, incremental approach. They
also supported limiting the quantity of
system capability given over to longterm FTRs for at least an initial period.
13. Finally, some respondents felt that
long-term rights should not be
introduced at this time. These parties
were concerned that the introduction of
multi-year rights could introduce
inequity and inefficiency into the
organized electricity markets because
such rights will reduce the availability
of FTRs with terms of one year or less
that can be used to hedge shorter-term
transactions. They also assert that
introducing long-term rights could
cause cost shifts if holders of long-term
rights are given congestion risk coverage
greater than that accorded to other
parties.
15 Notice Inviting Comments On Establishing
Long-Term Transmission Rights in Markets With
Locational Pricing and Staff Paper, Long-Term
Transmission Rights Assessment, Docket No.
AD05–7–000 (May 11, 2005) (Staff Paper).
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
D. Energy Policy Act of 2005
14. On August 8, 2005, EPAct 2005 16
became law. As noted above, section
1233 of EPAct 2005 added a new section
217 to the FPA, which provides:
The Commission shall exercise the
authority of the Commission under this Act
in a manner that facilitates the planning and
expansion of transmission facilities to meet
the reasonable needs of load-serving entities
to satisfy the service obligations of the loadserving entities, and enables load-serving
entities to secure firm transmission rights (or
equivalent tradable or financial rights) on a
long-term basis for long-term power supply
arrangements made, or planned, to meet such
needs.17
Section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005
requires:
Within 1 year after the date of enactment
of this section and after notice and an
opportunity for comment, the Commission
shall by rule or order, implement section
217(b)(4) of the Federal Power Act in
Transmission Organizations, as defined by
that Act with organized electricity markets.18
E. Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
15. On February 2, 2006, the
Commission issued a NOPR that
proposed to amend its regulations to
require each transmission organization
that is a public utility with one or more
organized electricity markets to make
available long-term firm transmission
rights that satisfy guidelines established
by the Commission.19 As discussed in
more detail below, the NOPR proposed
eight guidelines, and sought comments
on various issues raised by the
introduction of long-term firm
transmission rights in the organized
electricity markets.
II. Discussion
A. Overview
16. In adopting this Final Rule, the
Commission seeks to provide increased
certainty regarding the congestion cost
risks of long-term transmission service
in organized electricity markets that will
help load serving entities and other
market participants make new
investments and other long-term power
supply arrangements. The guidelines we
adopt in this Final Rule are designed
and intended primarily to ensure that
16 Pub.
L. 109–58, 119 Stat. 594
L. 109–58, § 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 958.
18 Id. at 960. Transmission organization is defined
in EPAct 2005 as ‘‘a Regional Transmission
Organization, Independent System Operator,
independent transmission provider, or other
transmission organization finally approved by the
Commission for the operation of transmission
facilities.’’ Pub. L. 109–58, § 1291, 119 Stat. 594,
985. Below, we adopt this definition with a minor
modification for purposes of this Final Rule.
19 See supra note 12.
17 Pub.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
the long-term firm transmission rights
that are made available by transmission
organizations that are subject to the rule
have characteristics that will support a
long-term power supply arrangement.
These guidelines provide a framework
within which transmission
organizations and their market
participants can design and implement
long-term firm transmission rights in the
organized electricity markets that are
compatible with the design of those
markets, in particular retaining the
advantages of price-based congestion
management, and meet the reasonable
needs of market participants.
17. Many of the comments received
by the Commission express concern that
the provision of long-term firm
transmission rights will result in a
drastic redistribution of transmission
rights, with transmission organizations
required to provide long-term rights to
load serving entities regardless of
feasibility or impact on other market
participants. This concern is
unfounded. While this Final Rule
unequivocally requires transmission
organizations to offer long-term firm
transmission rights with characteristics
that will support long-term power
supply arrangements, in most cases,
offering such rights should not require
major changes in allocations or
allocation procedures.20 Our intent with
regard to the existing transmission
system is that load serving entities be
able to request and obtain transmission
rights up to a reasonable amount on a
long-term firm basis, instead of being
limited to obtaining exclusively annual
rights.21 Offering such rights should not
force transmission organizations to
provide rights to the existing system to
one party that are infeasible. We expect
that transmission organizations will be
able to integrate long-term firm
transmission rights into their existing
procedures for assessing the feasibility
of requests for transmission service.
18. While it is difficult to generalize,
given the flexibility afforded in this
Final Rule, we expect that in most
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets the
process for obtaining a long-term firm
transmission right will not be
substantially different from the current
20 As we discuss in more detail below, while we
do not believe major changes to existing allocation
procedures will be necessary, Congress did not
intend to protect existing or future allocation
methodologies from the implementation of section
217(b)(4) of the FPA. See new section 217(c) of the
FPA, Pub. L. 109–58, § 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 958–59.
21 Capacity available would be limited to that
which is generally available and excludes capacity
that is the exclusive right of a participant, e.g., a
participant that paid for such capacity and obtained
FTRs for that payment.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
procedures. Most transmission
organizations will be able to use their
current allocation/auction systems to
allow load serving entities to nominate
source-to-sink transmission rights on a
longer-term basis than is currently
available. Transmission organizations
will then assess those requests for
feasibility and award a feasible set of
transmission rights, as they do today.
This Final Rule also allows the
transmission organization to place
reasonable limits on the total amount of
capacity it will offer as long-term rights.
Thus, this Final Rule does not
necessarily guarantee that a load serving
entity will be able to obtain long-term
firm transmission rights to hedge its
entire resource portfolio or be able to
obtain all the long-term firm
transmission rights it requests. Once
long-term rights are awarded to a load
serving entity, however, this Final Rule
requires that they be fully funded over
their entire term, as discussed in
guideline (2) below.
19. As we noted in the NOPR and
reaffirm in this Final Rule, transmission
organizations must provide the
opportunity for market participants to
obtain long-term firm transmission
rights that are not currently available by
supporting an expansion or upgrade of
grid transfer capability. The
Commission’s policy is that market
participants that request and support an
expansion or upgrade in accordance
with their transmission organization’s
prevailing rules for cost responsibility
and allocation must be awarded a longterm firm transmission right for the
incremental transfer capability created
by the expansion or upgrade. The
transmission organization tariffs must
clearly and specifically provide for this
arrangement, if they do not already.
Guideline (3) addresses this
requirement. This will enable load
serving entities to obtain long-term
rights that they may have requested but
not received due to infeasibility.
20. Moreover, in this Final Rule we
also require transmission organizations
with organized electricity markets to
explain how their transmission system
planning and expansion policies will
ensure that long-term firm transmission
rights, once allocated, remain feasible
over their entire term.
21. Together, these provisions will
ensure that transmission systems are
expanded where necessary to ensure the
continued feasibility of allocated longterm firm transmission rights, while also
giving market participants an explicit
right to obtain new incremental
transmission rights on a long-term basis,
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43567
in accordance with the prevailing cost
allocation methodology in the region.22
22. We understand that specifying
and allocating long-term firm
transmission rights supported by
existing transfer capability will raise
difficult issues that must be addressed
by transmission organizations and their
stakeholders as proposals are developed
to comply with this Final Rule. As we
discuss in more detail, we believe that
the approach we adopt in this Final
Rule will give transmission
organizations and their stakeholders
sufficient flexibility to design long-term
firm transmission rights that fit their
prevailing market design while also
ensuring that the rights have certain
fundamental properties necessary to
achieve Congress’s objectives in section
217(b)(4) of the FPA. We also clarify
below that while each guideline permits
flexibility in its implementation,
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets must
satisfy each of the guidelines in this
Final Rule.
23. This Final Rule largely adopts the
overall approach as well as the specific
guidelines and definitions proposed in
the NOPR. In response to the comments
received, however, the Commission has
made the following changes to the
proposal, as discussed in this preamble:
• Guideline (3) (Rights Made Available by
Expansion Go to Parties That Pay for the
Upgrade): We have removed the requirement
that the term of long-term rights from
expansion be equal to life of facility or a
lesser term requested by the party paying for
the upgrade. Based on the comments on the
difficulty of defining life of facility, we will
defer to transmission organizations to
develop terms based on existing market rules
and stakeholder needs. We encourage
transmission organizations to harmonize the
terms for long-term rights awarded for new
capacity with the terms of long-term rights to
existing transmission capacity as much as
possible.
• Guideline (4) (Term of Rights Must Be
Sufficient To Hedge Long-Term Power
Supply Arrangements): We have added a
provision that transmission organizations
and stakeholders may determine the length of
terms and use of renewal rights to provide
long-term transmission rights, but must offer
coverage for at least a 10-year sequence. Our
objective is to balance regional flexibility in
defining terms of rights with the need to
ensure that those terms are sufficient to allow
load serving entities to hedge their long-term
power supply arrangements.
• Guideline (5) (Load Serving Entities With
Long-Term Power Supply Arrangements
Have Priority to the Existing System): We
have revised this guideline in two respects.
First, we have eliminated the preference for
load serving entities with long-term power
22 We are not requiring any ‘‘obligation to build’’
that does not already exist under Order No. 888.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43568
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
supply arrangements and replaced it with a
broader preference for load serving entities in
`
general vis-a-vis non-load serving entities.
This broader preference is fully supported by
the statute and better meets the needs of
organized electricity markets. We believe that
Congress’s intent in enacting section 217 was
to provide long-term firm transmission
service to load serving entities and that load
serving entities in general should be ‘‘first in
line’’ for long-term transmission rights when
existing capacity is limited. As originally
proposed, guideline (5) could have
disadvantaged load serving entities who do
not engage in long-term power supply
arrangements, a result that we do not believe
Congress intended. Proposed guideline (5)
could have also presented difficult
administrative burdens for transmission
organizations, including the burden of
evaluating power supply contracts to
determine if they qualify for the preference.
In addition to addressing these concerns,
broadening the preference also makes it
possible for transmission organizations to
apply the same basic principles for allocating
long-term firm transmission rights that they
currently use for the initial allocation of
short-term firm transmission rights, or
auction revenue rights. As a result of this
change in the guideline, load serving entities
will not be required to provide evidence of
a long-term power supply arrangement.
We have also revised guideline (5) to allow
transmission organizations to place
reasonable limits on the amount of existing
transmission capacity made available for
long-term firm transmission rights. We have
done so in recognition of the expected
reluctance of transmission organizations to
commit all of their existing grid capacity to
long-term firm transmission rights due to
uncertainty regarding load growth, changes
in power flows and the full funding
requirement of this Final Rule. This will also
help to accommodate load serving entities
that prefer short-term rights. In addition,
commenters claim that the principal need for
long-term firm transmission rights is to
support long-term power supply
arrangements for base load generation, not
peaking or intermediate generation.
• Guideline (8) (Balance Adverse
Economic Impacts): We have elected not to
adopt this guideline in the Final Rule. This
guideline is not needed as it requires, in
effect, nothing more than adherence to the
FPA requirement that public utility tariffs
must be just and reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory. Moreover, it could have been
misinterpreted to require long-term firm
transmission right proposals to meet a
different or higher standard, something the
Commission did not intend or believe that
Congress intended.
• Definition of ‘‘Long-Term Power Supply
Arrangement’’: Because we have deleted the
reference to ‘‘long-term power supply
arrangements’’ from guideline (5), that term
is only used in guideline (4), relating to the
term of long-term firm transmission rights.
The Final Rule removes the specific
definition of long-term power supply
arrangements proposed in the NOPR, and
addresses issues related to our definition of
long-term power supply arrangements under
guideline (4).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
• Transmission Planning and Expansion:
This Final Rule requires that each
transmission organization with an organized
electricity market implement transmission
system planning and expansion procedures
to accommodate long-term firm transmission
rights that are allocated or awarded to ensure
that they remain feasible over their entire
term. We also require each such transmission
organization to make its planning and
expansion practices and procedures publicly
available, including both the actual plans and
any underlying information used to develop
the plans.
B. Definitions
1. Organized Electricity Market
24. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed to define ‘‘organized
electricity market’’ as ‘‘an auction-based
market where a single entity receives
offers to sell and bids to buy electric
energy and/or ancillary services from
multiple sellers and buyers and
determines which sales and purchases
are completed and at what prices, based
on formal rules contained in
Commission-approved tariffs, and
where the prices are used by a
transmission organization for
establishing transmission usage
charges.’’ 23 The Commission stated that
it proposed this definition to ensure that
the Final Rule in this proceeding
applies to any transmission organization
that is the transmission provider in its
region and has a day-ahead and/or realtime bid-based energy market,
administered by the transmission
organization itself or by another entity.
We sought comment on the scope of this
proposed definition.
Comments
25. AMPA 24 and Public Power
Council both argue that the proposed
definition is too narrow and should be
expanded to include ‘‘Day 1’’ RTO/ISO
markets, non-RTO/ISO markets, and
other forms of ‘‘organized markets’’
(which can include bilateral markets
that use a form contract).25 Public Power
Council argues that the proposed
definition could lock the Commission
into adopting the types of markets
described in the definition to the
exclusion of other types of markets, and
that section 217 of the FPA does not
support the Commission’s narrow
reading.
at P 8.
list of commenters on the NOPR and the
acronyms used to refer to them in this preamble is
attached as Appendix A.
25 NRECA, while not recommending any change
to the proposed definition, notes that the issues
raised over the availability of long-term firm
transmission rights also arise in transmission
organizations without Day 2 markets and on the
systems of non-independent entities.
PO 00000
23 NOPR
24 A
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
26. Other commenters argue that the
definition should be narrowed. TAPS,
for example, asserts that the Final Rule
should not apply in regions where the
OATT provides for long-term physical
transmission rights, particularly the
Southwest Power Pool. According to
TAPS, the last clause of the definition
of organized electricity markets (‘‘where
the prices are used by a transmission
organization for establishing
transmission usage charges’’) excludes
SPP because the prices produced by its
imbalance market will not establish
transmission usage charges. TAPS
requests that the Commission clarify
that as currently designed SPP will not
be subject to the Final Rule.
27. PG&E, EPSA and TAPS all state
that because the proposed rule primarily
addresses markets that use locational
market-based congestion management
mechanisms like LMP and have FTRs,
the Final Rule should clearly state that
it only applies to those markets, and
only addresses long-term financial
transmission instruments. PG&E
recommends that the Commission issue
a parallel rule providing for long-term
transmission rights in markets that do
not use a market-based congestion
management mechanism.
28. In reply comments, NRECA
opposes proposals to narrow the
definition of organized electricity
market, arguing that the need for longterm firm transmission rights and the
language of the statute are not limited to
transmission organizations with
locational pricing structures.
29. APPA states that it supports the
proposed definition of organized
electricity market, but suggests that it be
revised to replace ‘‘auction-based
market’’ with ‘‘a centralized market’’
because use of ‘‘auction-based’’ implies
that buyers and sellers in RTO markets
have more choice and autonomy than
they do in practice.
Commission Conclusion
30. We will adopt the definition of
organized electricity market proposed in
the NOPR with one modification.
Specifically, we modify the first clause
of the definition to state that organized
electricity market ‘‘means an auctionbased day ahead and real time
wholesale market * * *.’’ We make this
modification to clarify the application of
this Final Rule and ensure that the
definition captures the transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets using LMP and FTRs to which
Congress directed the Commission to
apply this Final Rule to in section
1233(b) of EPAct 2005. Today, those
electricity markets do not offer financial
transmission instruments supported by
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
existing capacity with terms longer than
one year, and thus entities are not able
to obtain a ‘‘firm’’ transmission right on
a long-term basis in those markets as
section 217(b)(4) of the FPA directs. As
a result, they are appropriately the focus
of this Final Rule.
31. The Commission will not expand
the definition to include other RTO/ISO
regions (sometimes called ‘‘Day 1’’
markets), non-RTO/ISO transmission
providers, or any other electricity
market structure. Applying the Final
Rule to non-RTO/ISO markets would
not be appropriate because EPAct 2005
requires us to implement section
217(b)(4) in this rulemaking in
‘‘transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets,’’ and nonRTO/ISO transmission providers by
definition are not transmission
organizations.26 And while Public
Power Council is correct that there may
be other electricity market structures,
the definition we adopt here is only for
the purposes of this Final Rule and is
crafted to ensure that the appropriate
entities are subject to the Final Rule.
Additionally, as we noted in the NOPR,
non-RTO/ISO transmission providers
and other RTO/ISOs offer long-term
physical transmission service under the
Order No. 888 OATT without rates that
vary with congestion costs.27 The
Commission recently issued a NOPR in
Docket Nos. RM05–25–000 and RM05–
17–000 that would institute reforms to
the OATT. It is more appropriate to
consider in that rulemaking any issues
related to the application of section
217(b)(4) of the FPA to the other
markets identified by commenters,
particularly issues related to
coordinated, open and transparent
transmission system planning.
32. In response to TAPS, we clarify
that SPP is not subject to this Final Rule
because its current market design does
not fit within the definition of organized
electricity market that we adopt for
purposes of this rule.
33. Finally, we decline to revise the
‘‘auction-based’’ language as APPA
requests. This language simply
26 This is not to say that there might not in the
future be types of transmission organizations other
than ISOs and RTOs approved by the Commission
that operate transmission facilities and provide
transmission service. The new FPA definition of
transmission organization leaves open this
possibility. At the current time, however, RTOs and
ISOs are the only such organizations approved by
the Commission.
27 While transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets are also expected to
have OATTs that meet the requirements of Order
No. 888, the total cost of transmission service in
those transmission organizations varies with the
cost of congestion, and such transmission
organizations only offer FTRs to hedge congestion
costs with short-terms.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
recognizes that the organized electricity
markets Congress intended to be subject
to this Final Rule are those that utilize
auction mechanisms for the buying and
selling of electric energy. We note that
we are adopting this definition for the
purposes of this Final Rule only, and do
not intend that it will necessarily apply
in other contexts.
2. Load Serving Entity and Service
Obligation
34. We proposed to define ‘‘load
serving entity’’ and ‘‘service obligation,’’
for purposes of the proposed rule,
exactly as Congress defined those terms
in new section 217 of the FPA.
Specifically, we proposed to define load
serving entity as ‘‘a distribution utility
or electric utility that has a service
obligation.’’ 28 We proposed to define
service obligation as ‘‘a requirement
applicable to, or the exercise of
authority granted to, an electric utility
under federal, State or local law or
under long-term contracts to provide
electric service to end-users or to a
distribution utility.’’ 29
Comments
35. APPA, E.ON, NRECA, PG&E and
Public Power Council all express
support for the proposed definitions.
36. Several commenters (including
Industrial Consumers, CAISO, NARUC,
National Grid and SDG&E) argue that
the proposed definitions in the NOPR
would exclude several entities that
should be eligible for long-term firm
transmission rights because they are not
a ‘‘distribution utility’’ or ‘‘electric
utility.’’ These entities include
industrial customers who serve their
own load pursuant to state law, several
types of retail service providers,
community aggregators, and various
non-public utilities. The comments
generally seek clarification that all of
these various entities are ‘‘load serving
entities’’ for purposes of this rule.
37. More specifically, Industrial
Consumers and Alcoa explain that
while many large industrial customers
are permitted under state law to selfsupply their own load, usually by
registering as a retail provider, not all of
these states use the term ‘‘load serving
entity.’’ Industrial Consumers argue that
entities who have qualified as retail
electric providers under state law meet
the definition of ‘‘electric utility’’ under
28 NOPR at P 7, citing Pub. L. 109–58, § 1233, 119
Stat. 594, 957. EPAct 2005 defines electric utility
as ‘‘a person or Federal or State agency (including
an entity described in section 210(f)) that sells
electric energy.’’ Pub. L. 109–58, § 1291, 119 Stat.
594, 984.
29 NOPR at P 7, citing Pub. L. 109–58, § 1233, 119
Stat. 594, 958.
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43569
EPAct 2005, and request that the
Commission unambiguously state that
entities who are qualified to serve retail
load under state law, including those
self-supplying, are load serving entities
for purposes of the Final Rule and thus
qualify for long-term firm transmission
rights.
38. Regarding retail service providers,
several commenters (including CAISO,
EEI, NARUC and National Grid) seek
clarifications regarding whether various
types of service providers in retail
access states are load serving entities
under the proposed definition. NARUC
notes that states with retail choice
programs either may have multiple
sellers of electricity to end users, or may
use an auction process whereby the
distribution utility takes delivery of the
power supply and bills the cost to
customers, making it the only seller.30
To protect and accommodate these
choices made by the states, and to be
consistent with Congress’ intent that the
protections in section 217 of the FPA be
available to all customers, it asks the
Commission to clarify that all of these
entities are ‘‘electric utilities’’ and/or
‘‘distribution utilities,’’ thereby making
them load serving entities and eligible
to obtain long-term firm transmission
rights.31 OMS, noting specifically that
Illinois utilities will soon be required to
use an auction process to procure
supply and that auction winners under
this format would not meet either
definition, asks the Commission to
revise the definition of load serving
entity to replace ‘‘a distribution utility
or electric utility’’ with ‘‘an entity,’’ and
revise the definition of service
obligation to replace ‘‘electric utility’’
with ‘‘entity.’’ EEI and National Grid
both note that under certain retail access
structures service obligations (including
the default service obligation) may be
reassigned for terms that are less than
the term of long-term firm transmission
rights. EEI asserts that the proposed
definition of load serving entity should
be clarified to be simply the distribution
utility, unless its service obligation has
been reassigned, while National Grid
suggests that the load serving entity
30 National Grid notes that pursuant to state law,
its distribution utilities have at various times been
required to contract with wholesale suppliers to
meet their load obligations (including congestion
cost exposure), while in other retail choice
programs those responsibilities have been directly
assigned to retail suppliers.
31 In its reply comments, NARUC reiterates its
request, further stating that the Commission should
clarify that vertically-integrated utilities, municipal
utilities and cooperatives in traditionally regulated
states, power suppliers in retail states, and
distribution utilities or auction winners in other
states are all ‘‘electric utilities’’ and/or ‘‘distribution
utilities,’’ and thus eligible to obtain long-term firm
transmission rights.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43570
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
should be the electric utility when it
holds the service obligation, and the
distribution utility in the first instance.
National Grid also asserts that the
Commission should clarify that the term
‘‘electric utility’’ is defined in section
3(22) of the FPA (any ‘‘person or Federal
or State agency * * * that sells electric
energy’’), which would encompass both
municipal utilities and merchant
suppliers not normally subject to state
regulation.
39. Santa Clara asserts that the
definition of load serving entity should
include non-public utilities (as defined
in section 201(f) of the FPA), subsidiary
agencies of non-public utilities, and
entities in which non-public utilities
hold an interest (such as joint action
agencies), since each either serve load
under statutory obligations to serve or
facilitate such service. Similarly,
California DWR and MWD argue that
the Commission should revise the
definition of load serving entities to
include water pumping entities.32 They
assert that in new section 217(g) of the
FPA, Congress recognized a need to
expand the definition of load serving
entity to include such entities.33 To
comply with section 217(g), California
DWR and MWD contend that the
Commission should revise the proposed
definition to define load serving entity
to mean ‘‘a distribution utility, or an
electric utility that has a service
obligation, or other wholesale
transmission user that owns generation
facilities, markets the output of federal
generation facilities, or holds rights
under one or more wholesale contracts
to purchase electric energy, for the
purpose of meeting a service
obligation.’’ 34
40. MSATs seek clarification that as
stand-alone transmission companies
that do not own generation or
distribution facilities, buy or sell energy,
serve loads or act as transmission
customers or market participants, they
are not considered load serving entities
under the Commission’s proposed
regulations.
41. Ameren asks the Commission to
clarify that the definition of service
32 MWD notes that its water pumping operations
require large amounts of power (roughly 2–3
percent of California’s total energy requirement),
and that these operations require long-term
transmission rights to achieve reliable water
delivery.
33 Specifically, section 217(g) provides that ‘‘[t]he
Commission shall ensure that any entity described
in section 201(f) that owns transmission facilities
used predominately to support its own water
pumping facilities shall have, with respect to the
facilities, protections for transmission service
comparable to those provided to load serving
entities pursuant to this section.’’ See Pub. L. 109–
58, § 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 959.
34 Reply Comments of California DWR at 9.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
obligation includes future obligations,
and not just obligations existing at the
effective date of the Final Rule, which
it states will provide certainty and
reassure load serving entities that longterm firm transmission rights will
continue to be made available in the
future.
42. Commenters (including CAISO,
PG&E and NU) also raise issues and seek
clarification specifically with regard to
the application of the service obligation
definition in retail access frameworks,
and particularly seek clarification as to
whether a default service obligation is a
‘‘service obligation.’’ According to
CAISO, these clarifications are
important because they will impact the
eligibility rules for long-term firm
transmission rights and the rules for
transferring those rights as end-users
switch providers. Commenters such as
PG&E assert that entities holding the
default service obligation, even though
they may not be serving the load now,
must be able to plan to meet that load
should they be required to serve it in the
future. Coral Power states that the
definition of service obligation should
be expanded because as proposed by the
Commission, it only applies to
distribution companies or entities that
provide electric service to end-users
under contracts. It argues that the
definition should include wholesale
power suppliers that provide hedging
services to competitive retail suppliers
or that have assumed load obligations
under default service or retail access
programs.
43. Commenters (including NU and
PG&E) also raise issues with the ‘‘longterm contracts’’ language in the
definition, arguing that it has the
potential to discriminate against load
serving entities in retail access
jurisdictions, since such entities do not
typically enter into long-term power
supply contracts. NU argues that in New
England, the definition would favor
municipal utilities (whose customers
are not included in retail access
programs) and utilities from outside the
region that serve load through New
England resources.35 Accordingly, it
asks that the Commission narrow the
definitions to limit eligibility for longterm firm transmission rights to entities
that serve customers within the same
region.
Commission Conclusion
44. In the Final Rule, the Commission
is adopting the definitions of load
serving entity and service obligation
provided by Congress in EPAct 2005
and proposed in the NOPR. We believe
PO 00000
35 Comments
Frm 00008
of NU at 3–4.
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
using these definitions as Congress
provided them will most closely
effectuate the intent of Congress in
section 217(b)(4) of the FPA. We will,
however, offer several clarifications.
45. At the outset, we note that the
definition of load serving entity is
important in this Final Rule only in that
it establishes a priority in the allocation
of long-term firm transmission rights
when necessary under guideline (5). It
does not determine eligibility for longterm firm transmission rights, as some
commenters suggest. All market
participants are eligible for long-term
firm transmission rights.
46. In response to National Grid, we
clarify that the term ‘‘electric utility,’’ as
used in the definition of load serving
entity, is defined in section 3(2) of the
FPA as ‘‘a person or Federal or State
agency (including an entity described in
section 201(f)) that sells electric
energy.’’ 36 This expansive definition
will cover many of the entities for
which commenters seek clarification as
to their status as load serving entities.
47. With regard to large industrial
customers who self-supply their own
load, while some of these entities may
not technically ‘‘sell * * * electric
energy,’’ we construe them to be load
serving entities for purposes of this
Final Rule, to ensure that Congress’s
objectives in section 217 of the FPA are
fulfilled. Thus, transmission
organizations should treat them as such
when complying with this rule.
48. With regard to non-public
utilities, the Commission notes that the
definition of electric utility discussed
above, as amended by EPAct 2005,
includes ‘‘an entity described in section
201(f)’’ of the FPA, i.e. non-public
utilities. As a result, they are within the
definition of load serving entity,
provided, of course, that they have a
service obligation. Additionally, in
response to California DWR and MWD,
we note that the definition of load
serving entity provided by Congress
appears to already capture water
pumping entities, which are non-public
utilities. New section 217(g) of the FPA
provides that ‘‘[t]he Commission shall
ensure that any entity described in
section 201(f) that owns transmission
facilities used predominately to support
its own water pumping facilities shall
have, with respect to the facilities,
protections for transmission service
comparable to those provided to load
serving entities pursuant to this
section.’’ 37 In light of this Congressional
36 16 U.S.C. 796(22) (2000), as amended by EPAct
2005, Pub. L. 109–58, § 1291(b)(1), 119 Stat. 594,
984.
37 Pub. L. 109–58, § 1291(b)(1), 119 Stat. 594, 984.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
directive, we clarify, to the extent
necessary, that water pumping entities
with the characteristics described in
section 217(g) are load serving entities
for purposes of this Final Rule.
49. MSATs request that we clarify that
stand-alone transmission companies are
not load serving entities for purposes of
this rule. We clarify that as described by
MSATs, stand-alone transmission
companies that do not own generation
or distribution facilities, buy or sell
energy, serve loads or act as
transmission customers are not load
serving entities for purposes of this
Final Rule. We emphasize, however,
that this clarification should not be read
broadly to suggest that other types of
stand-alone transmission companies
(either existing or that might be
developed) with different characteristics
from those described by MSATs will not
be load serving entities under this Final
Rule. The Commission will consider
these issues on a case-by-case basis, as
necessary.
50. In response to those seeking
clarifications regarding various types of
retail service providers, we note that
many retail service providers will be a
‘‘person * * * that sells electric
energy,’’ thus making it an electric
utility and, consequently, they can be a
load serving entity provided they have
a service obligation. The Commission
cannot decide here, however, whether
each possible entity operating in state
retail electric markets will meet the
definition of load serving entity. We
agree with NARUC, however, that
Congress intended to broadly protect the
ability of load serving entities with
service obligations to obtain
transmission service. Thus,
transmission organizations should
ensure that different types of retail
service providers that have service
obligations are accommodated when
implementing the Final Rule.
51. As noted above, commenters
raising issues regarding the application
of the service obligation definition in
retail access frameworks focus primarily
on the default service obligation, which
generally (with variation from state-tostate) requires the entity subject to that
obligation to provide electric service to
customers who do not have another
supplier (either because they did not
choose one or because their supplier left
the market). Under the definition
provided by Congress, a default service
obligation only becomes a service
obligation for purposes of this rule
when the entity holding the default
obligation is actually required to serve
the load, i.e. when the competitive
supplier either stops serving the load or
the load switches to the default
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
supplier. A default service obligation
only becomes ‘‘a requirement applicable
to, or the exercise of authority granted
to’’ the default supplier when it must
actually serve the load. We understand
the concerns expressed by PG&E and
others that a utility holding the default
service obligation must plan to serve
that load should it be required to do so
in the future. Transmission organization
rules currently provide that auction
revenue rights (ARRs) or FTRs will
generally ‘‘follow the load’’ in instances
where load switches suppliers;
guideline (6), discussed below, also
requires that long-term firm
transmission rights allocated to load
serving entities be reassignable. As a
result, when default suppliers assume
the service obligation, they will receive
transmission rights that they can use to
serve the default load. While we are
aware that those transmission rights
may not match the resources that the
default supplier will use to serve the
load, this is a problem that already
exists today, and is not a result of our
adoption of Congress’s definition of
service obligation. Transmission
organizations may consider whether any
rules are necessary (such as allowing or
requiring holders of long-term
transmission rights to turn back those
rights for reallocation) to deal with this
problem.
52. We decline to revise the
definitions of load serving entity and
service obligation to replace
‘‘distribution utility or electric utility’’
and ‘‘electric utility’’ with ‘‘an entity,’’
as requested by OMS. Congress chose to
use these terms to limit these
definitions, and we are not persuaded to
change them here, and do not believe
such a change is necessary to address
OMS’s concern. While OMS may be
correct that auction winners under
Illinois’ procurement mechanism may
not meet these definitions, the Illinois
utilities that procure electric energy
under this mechanism and resell it to
their customers (under their service
obligation) presumably meet the
definitions of load serving entity and
service obligation, and thus should be
able to obtain long-term firm
transmission rights to deliver that
energy to load. Similarly, we decline to
define load serving entity to be only the
distribution utility, unless its service
obligation has been reassigned, as
requested by EEI, or to be the
distribution utility in the first instance,
as requested by National Grid. This
would limit the definition provided by
Congress, which chose to include
electric utilities (other than distribution
utilities) that have service obligations in
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43571
the definition, and we are unsure how
these revisions would address EEI and
National Grid’s concerns. As we note
above, when load serving obligations are
reassigned, the new entity serving that
load will be a load serving entity and
have a service obligation under the
definitions in this Final Rule, and
associated transmission rights will
‘‘follow’’ that load. Any problems
associated with transmission rights
whose term is longer than the
transferred service obligation may be
addressed in proposals to implement
this rule; revising these definitions do
not appear to resolve such concerns.
53. In response to Ameren, we clarify
that the definition of service obligation,
as written by Congress and adopted by
the Commission in this Final Rule,
includes future service obligations and
not simply those existing on the
effective date of this rule. Nothing in
that definition, or in section 217(b)(4)’s
charge that the Commission exercise its
FPA authority in a manner that
facilitates the planning and expansion
of transmission facilities and enables
load serving entities to obtain long-term
firm transmission rights, suggests that
service obligations should be limited to
those existing as of the effective date of
this rule.
54. Finally, we will not revise the
definition in response to the concerns
raised by NU and PG&E regarding the
‘‘long-term contracts’’ language in the
definition of service obligation. The
definition provides that a service
obligation is either ‘‘a requirement
applicable to, or the exercise of
authority granted to, an electric utility
under Federal, State, or local law or
under long-term contracts * * *.’’
(emphasis added). Thus, having a longterm contract to serve load is not
necessary to have a service obligation
under this definition. Load serving
entities in retail access jurisdictions will
be interpreted to have a service
obligation under this rule if they are
either required, or have been given
authority, under state law to provide
electric service. Thus, we do not believe
the definition results in any
discrimination against load serving
entities in those jurisdictions or gives
any favor to municipal utilities not
included in retail access programs.
3. Long-Term Power Supply
Arrangement
55. We noted in the NOPR that while
new section 217(b)(4) of the FPA
requires the Commission to exercise its
authority to enable load serving entities
to obtain long-term firm transmission
rights ‘‘for long-term power supply
arrangements made * * * or planned’’
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43572
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
to meet service obligations, Congress
did not define ‘‘long-term power supply
arrangements’’ in the legislation.38
Based on language in section 217(b)(1)
of the FPA, we proposed to define longterm power supply arrangements as ‘‘the
ownership of generation facilities, rights
to market the output of Federal
generation facilities with a term of
longer than one year, or rights under
one or more wholesale contracts to
purchase electric energy with a term of
longer than one year, for the purpose of
meeting a service obligation.’’ 39
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Comments
56. NRECA and PG&E support the
proposed definition. Public Power
Council also supports the proposed
definition with two ‘‘editorial
suggestions.’’ First, it suggests removing
the phrase ‘‘with a term of longer than
one year’’ after ‘‘Federal generation
facilities’’ because it is redundant.
Second, it suggests replacing the word
‘‘rights’’ where it appears before the
phrase ‘‘to market the output of Federal
generation facilities’’ with ‘‘authority or
obligation,’’ since federal Power
Marketing Agencies (like BPA) have a
statutory obligation, rather than a
‘‘right,’’ to market the output of their
facilities.40
57. Commenters taking issue with the
proposed definition addressed three
primary issues: (1) The ‘‘longer than one
year’’ language, (2) whether the
definition should include specific
criteria, and (3) whether the definition
unduly discriminates against load
serving entities in retail access states.
58. APPA argues that the Commission
should not define ‘‘long-term power
supply arrangements’’ as ‘‘longer than
one year,’’ and should instead
harmonize this definition with
minimum term of long-term firm
transmission rights discussed in
guideline (4). PJM and TAPS also state
that this language is unreasonable, and
argue that ‘‘long-term power supply
arrangements’’ should be defined as
those with a minimum term of 10 years.
According to TAPS, this change would
appropriately limit the availability of
long-term rights to those long-term
power supply arrangements most poorly
served by annual FTRs, particularly
baseload and renewable power
arrangements with terms longer than 10
years.
59. Some commenters suggest that the
Commission revise the definition of
38 NOPR at P 9 citing Pub. L. 109–58, § 1233, 119
Stat. 594, 958.
39 NOPR at P 9.
40 Public Power council notes that the
Commission could also interpret rights as a
description of these statutory obligations.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
‘‘long-term power supply arrangements’’
to require that they have certain specific
characteristics. CAISO and PG&E, for
example, suggest that to make more
transparent the process of validating
requests for long-term rights, ‘‘long-term
power supply arrangements’’ should
designate specific resources. Others
argue that to prevent inefficient
allocations of long-term firm
transmission rights, the Commission’s
definition should require ‘‘long-term
power supply arrangements’’ to be firm
for their entire term, specify specific
amounts of energy, and be for both
capacity and energy. Wisconsin Electric
suggests that the definition exclude
peaking facilities. Wisconsin Electric
also asks that the Commission clarify
that long-term leasing arrangements or
other arrangements, in addition to
ownership, qualify as ‘‘long-term power
supply arrangements.’’
60. In response to CAISO, CMUA
states that while it agrees that contracts
with flexible points of delivery are an
implementation issue that must be
addressed, it is concerned that CAISO’s
proposed modification is too narrow.
According to CMUA, if CAISO’s
proposed modification would make
long-term transmission rights available
only for unit contingent contracts, it
would create upheaval in the bilateral
markets of the West, where power
supply contracts with multiple
resources are common.
61. NSTAR suggests that the
combination of this definition and
guideline (5) results in a long-term firm
transmission right that is not available
to (and thus unduly discriminates
against) load serving entities that
provide default service in retail access
states because such entities do not enter
into ‘‘long-term power supply
arrangements,’’ as defined in the rule.
According to NSTAR, these entities do
not generally own generation and do not
enter into long-term power supply
contracts either because of the variable
nature of their service obligation from
year to year or because state regulatory
requirements limit them to short-term
power purchase agreements. According
to NSTAR, requiring long-term power
supply arrangements (including
generation ownership or purchased
power contracts) would conflict with
section 217’s overall purpose to protect
the transmission rights of all end users
and deal a blow to competitive retail
electric markets by benefiting long-term
rights holders at the expense of retail
access loads holding shorter-term rights.
NSTAR suggests that the Commission
correct this problem by adding ‘‘or other
arrangements for the purpose of meeting
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
a service obligation on a long-term
basis’’ to the definition.
Commission Conclusion
62. As discussed in more detail
below, the Commission is removing
from guideline (5) the requirement that,
in order to have priority in the
allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights from existing
capacity, a load serving entity must hold
long-term power supply arrangements.
Therefore, that term is only used in the
final regulations in guideline (4),
relating to the term of long-term firm
transmission rights. Accordingly, we are
removing the definition of long-term
power supply arrangements from the
Final Rule, and will generally discuss
issues related to our definition of longterm power supply arrangements under
guideline (4), particularly with regard to
the length of such arrangements. The
discrimination arguments raised by
certain parties in response to the
proposed definition are discussed under
guideline (5).
4. Transmission Organization
63. In the NOPR, we proposed to
define ‘‘transmission organization’’ as
‘‘a Regional Transmission Organization,
Independent System Operator,
independent transmission provider, or
other independent transmission
organization finally approved by the
Commission for the operation of
transmission facilities.’’ 41 This
proposed definition is similar to the
definition of transmission organization
provided by Congress in EPAct 2005,
except that we added the term
‘‘independent.’’ We explained in the
NOPR that we added ‘‘independent’’
because we interpret section 1233(b) of
EPAct 2005 to require that long-term
firm transmission rights be made
available by independent entities that
are approved by the Commission (either
currently or in the future) to operate
transmission facilities and have
organized electricity markets.
Comments
64. EPSA, PG&E and PJM all support
the Commission’s proposal to include
‘‘independent’’ in the definition of
transmission organization.
65. APPA and AMPA, while
supportive of the Commission’s
addition of the word ‘‘independent’’ to
the definition of ‘‘transmission
organization’’ provided by Congress,
note that this addition raises questions
regarding the level of independence
required to be considered a
‘‘transmission organization.’’ Both raise
41 NOPR
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
at P 6.
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
the question of whether ICT’s are
‘‘transmission organizations.’’ APPA
argues that an ICT should not be
considered an independent
transmission organization because it is
employed and paid solely by the
transmission-owning utility. APPA
adds, however, that it assumes the
Commission will apply a ‘‘flexible, yet
vigilant’’ standard to determine the
independence of transmission
organizations.42 AMPA, for its part,
asserts that given the broad intent of
EPAct 2005, the Commission should
consider applying the NOPR to all
organized electricity markets with
independent transmission providers, to
ensure that all load serving entities will
receive protection for their service
obligations and long-term price
certainty.
66. Public Power Council, on the
other hand, specifically opposes the
addition of the word ‘‘independent,’’
arguing that it unduly restricts the
definition adopted by Congress, which
intended that any organization finally
approved by the Commission for the
operation of transmission facilities
(whether or not independent) would fall
under the statute. According to Public
Power Council, Congress instead chose
to qualify ‘‘other transmission
organization’’ with the phrase ‘‘finally
approved by the Commission for the
operation of transmission facilities,’’
meaning any such transmission
organization falls under the statute
whether or not it is independent.
for purposes of this Final Rule that it
believes comports with Congress’s
intent, expressed in section 1233(b) of
EPAct 2005, that the Commission act
specifically with regard to transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets.
68. In response to comments
concerning the level of independence
required to be a transmission
organization, we note that prior to
approving transmission organizations
(such as RTOs and ISOs) with organized
electricity markets, the Commission
makes specific findings, based on
established standards, that the entity is
independent from market participants.
We do not believe any further
determination or separate standard is
required for purposes of this rule.
69. With regard to comments seeking
to clarify whether proposed
independent coordinators of
transmission are transmission
organizations under this Final Rule, we
note that these proposals are still
developing. Moreover, to date none of
these proposed entities has proposed to
implement an organized electricity
market as defined in this Final Rule. As
a result, the Commission will not
address whether such entities meet the
definition of transmission organization
unless and until such time as they
propose to establish an organized
electricity market.
Commission Conclusion
67. The Commission will adopt the
definition of transmission organization
proposed in the NOPR. In section
1233(b) of EPAct 2005, Congress
narrowed the Commission’s
implementation efforts to
‘‘Transmission Organizations * * *
with organized electricity markets,’’
even though the overall directive of
section 217(b)(4) applies more broadly.
We believe that it is reasonable to
interpret the more focused directive in
section 1233(b) as principally requiring
that the Commission implement section
217(b)(4), through rulemaking, in the
current independent RTOs and ISOs
that operate centralized markets for the
purchase of electric energy and/or
ancillary services, and any similar
transmission organizations that are
created in the future. This does not
mean, however, that the requirements of
section 217(b)(4) will not apply to other
transmission providers. The
Commission is simply adopting a
definition of transmission organization
70. In addition to the comments
below regarding our flexible approach
in the NOPR, several entities submitted
comments generally addressing our
interpretation of the requirements of
new section 217(b)(4) of the FPA and
section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005 with
respect to long-term firm transmission
rights in organized electricity markets.
Comments regarding specific
interpretations of the statutory
requirements that we made in
connection with the proposed
guidelines are addressed elsewhere in
this Final Rule.
42 Comments
VerDate Aug<31>2005
at APPA at 11.
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
C. Commission Interpretation of EPAct
2005 Requirements
Comments
Long-Term Transmission Rights from
Existing Capacity
71. Some commenters, particularly
Cinergy, Coral Power and NYISO, argue
that the Commission misinterprets
section 217(b)(4) and section 1233(b) of
EPAct 2005 as requiring the long-term
firm transmission rights be made
available from existing capacity. They
assert that those provisions only require
the Commission to exercise its authority
to facilitate the planning and expansion
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43573
of transmission facilities in a manner
that allows load serving entities to
secure long-term transmission rights.
Thus, they contend that the Commission
inappropriately gives independent effect
to the second clause of the statute
(‘‘enables load serving entities to secure
firm transmission rights * * * on a
long-term basis’’), when the true thrust
of the law is its first clause (‘‘[t]he
Commission shall exercise * * * [its]
authority * * * in a manner that
facilitates the planning and expansion
of transmission facilities * * *’’). The
second clause, they contend, only
modifies the first.
72. In reply comments, APPA, New
England Public Systems, NRECA,
Peabody, and TAPS urge the
Commission to reject Cinergy’s
interpretation of the statute. In general,
they state that the Commission correctly
reads section 217(b)(4) as providing two
directives: (1) Facilitating transmission
planning and expansion, and (2)
enabling load serving entities to obtain
long-term transmission rights for their
long-term power supply arrangements.
TAPS argues, for example, that nothing
in the statute’s long-term rights clause
restricts such rights to new capacity, as
Cinergy and others suggest, and further
asserts that such a reading would
inappropriately ‘‘sell short’’ and render
both the long-term rights and planning
provisions a nullity. Similarly, APPA
contends that if planning and expansion
were all Congress sought to address, it
would not have included the second
clause of section 217(b)(4).
Need To Require Long-Term Financial
Rights
73. Cinergy and others note a
difference between long-term
transmission rights and long-term FTRs.
According to Cinergy, load serving
entities can already acquire long-term
transmission rights, and Congress would
have used ‘‘and’’ instead of ‘‘or’’ if it
intended to require RTOs to also
provide long-term FTRs.43 IPL similarly
argues in its reply comments that the
creation of long-term firm transmission
rights or long-term financial
transmission rights is not statutorily
mandated, and as a result must be
justified in the record, since it is a
‘‘stark departure from past practices.’’ 44
IPL states that section 217(b)(4) is
properly implemented by ensuring that
load serving entities can obtain either
firm or financial transmission rights on
a long-term basis.
74. In response to these arguments,
APPA argues that the term ‘‘firm
43 Comments
44 Reply
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
of Cinegry at 14.
comments of IPL at 7.
01AUR2
43574
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
transmission rights’’ was meant to refer
to the physical transmission rights that
exist in non-transmission organization
markets (since the statute covers all
regions), and that the inclusion of the
phrase ‘‘or equivalent tradable or
financial rights’’ was intended to
address the FTRs used in transmission
organization markets. According to
APPA, the network service contract and
associated payment toward the fixed
cost of the transmission system does not
cover transmission congestion costs.
Only an FTR covers these costs and
‘‘firms up’’ the total cost of transmission
service, APPA contends. Finally, it,
along with NRECA and TAPS, state that
if Cinergy’s assertion that transmission
organizations already provide long-term
transmission rights in compliance with
the statute is correct, then section
217(b)(4) was unnecessary and did
nothing.
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Disruption of Current Market Designs or
Allocation Methods
75. Some entities, including IPL,
Midwest ISO and NYISO, argue that
Congress did not intend for the
Commission, when implementing
section 217(b)(4), to disrupt current
market designs or existing transmission
rights allocation methodologies. Of
these entities, some argue that nothing
in section 217 suggests that the
Commission require major changes to
the existing auction-based FTR systems,
and that it would be consistent with
section 217 for the Commission to allow
transmission organizations to retain
their current systems so long as they
offer long-term financial transmission
rights. Midwest ISO, for example,
asserts that section 1233(c) of EPAct
2005 provides that Congress did not
intend for the Commission to disrupt
existing market designs that already
offer long-term FTRs. Similarly, NYISO
asserts that nothing in section 217
requires major changes to auction-based
FTR systems, noting that this section
expressly recognizes that financial
rights can be equivalent to physical
rights and expressly protects established
FTR allocation systems. According to
NYISO, the Commission could,
consistent with section 217, allow
transmission organizations and their
stakeholders to retain their current
systems so long as they offer long-term
FTRs. IPL states, in part, that Congress
was aware of the current transmission
rights constructs in the organized
markets, and by using the phrase ‘‘or
equivalent tradable or financial rights,’’
‘‘at the very least left open the
possibility that the Commission might
use existing financial rights designs to
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
achieve the statutory objectives.’’ 45
NYISO also contends that nothing in
section 217 requires transmission
organizations to offer any rights with
longer terms than they already do,
noting that section 217 only requires
that rights be ‘‘long-term’’ without
saying what that means. PJM, while
generally supportive of the
Commission’s NOPR, nevertheless notes
that section 217(c) preserved existing
FTR allocation methodologies, and
argues that Congress sought to
complement rather than replace current
transmission rights allocation methods.
76. NYAPP, in reply comments,
objects to NYISO’s contention that
nothing in section 217 requires
transmission organizations to offer any
rights with longer terms than they
already do, arguing that this
interpretation would render section
217(b)(4) a nullity.
77. Midwest TDUs notes in its reply
comments that Midwest ISO is subject
to a specific directive to consider the
preservation of existing transmission
rights. Specifically, Midwest TDUs
point out that under section 217(c),
which shields the other established
transmission organizations from the
impact of section 217(b)(1) through
(b)(3), Midwest ISO is subject to that
section’s ‘‘provided, however’’ clause,
thus requiring the Commission to take
into account existing rights held by a
load serving entity as of January 1, 2005
(prior to the commencement of the
Midwest ISO organized electricity
market).
Commission Conclusion
78. As noted above, many of the
specific interpretations of section
217(b)(4) of the FPA made by the
Commission are discussed below with
regard to the guidelines adopted in this
Final Rule. However, in this section we
address more general comments
regarding our interpretation in the
NOPR of the requirement of section
217(b)(4) and section 1233(b) of EPAct
2005.
79. First, the Commission believes it
correctly interpreted section 217(b)(4) of
the FPA as containing two separate
directives: (1) To exercise its authority
to facilitate planning and expansion of
transmission facilities, and (2) to enable
load serving entities with long-term
power supply arrangements used to
meet their service obligations to obtain
firm transmission rights on a long-term
basis. We conclude that this
interpretation of the statute is the most
PO 00000
45 Id.
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
reasonable.46 Cinergy’s interpretation of
the relevant statutory language as
requiring only that the Commission
facilitate planning and expansion of
transmission facilities in a manner that
that allows load serving entities to
secure long-term transmission rights is
unreasonable in light of the actual
statutory language used by Congress.
When it drafted section 217(b)(4),
Congress separated the first clause
(requiring that the Commission exercise
its FPA authority to facilitate the
planning and expansion of transmission
facilities) and the second clause (‘‘and
enables load serving entities to secure
firm transmission rights * * * on a
long-term basis’’) with a comma,
indicating two separate requirements.
The comma is also followed with the
word ‘‘and,’’ further suggesting that
Congress intended them as two separate
directives. No language in the statute
suggests that the two clauses are part of
a single directive to the Commission.
80. Moreover, a reading of section 217
in its entirety suggests that Congress
intended for the Commission to both
facilitate planning and expansion and
enable that load serving entities can
obtain long-term firm transmission
rights. As a whole, section 217 is
directed to protecting the ability of load
serving entities with native load service
obligations to obtain firm transmission
service to satisfy those service
obligations.47 Directing transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets to provide long-term firm
transmission rights from both new and
existing capacity is fully consistent with
this statutory directive. Furthermore, if
Congress only intended to direct the
Commission to facilitate planning and
expansion of transmission facilities in a
manner that enables load serving
entities to obtain long-term firm
transmission rights, it would not have
included the long-term firm
transmission rights language in a
second, separate clause. Finally, the
directive in section 1233(b) of EPAct
that the Commission implement this
provision within one year in
transmission organizations with
46 See e.g., Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. NRDC, Inc.,
467 U.S. 837, 844–45 (1984) (noting that where
Congress has expressly left a gap for an agency to
fill, the agency’s interpretation of the statute is
giving weight unless it is ‘‘arbitrary, capricious, or
manifestly contrary to the statute’’); see also Acosta
v. Gonzales, 439 F.3d 550, 552–53 (9th Cir. 2006)
(noting that courts defer to agency regulations that
are based on a permissible construction of the
statute).
47 Common principles of statutory interpretation
support reading section 217 as a whole to ascertain
its intent. See. e.g., United States v. Andrews, 441
F.3d 220, 223, (4th Cir. 2006) (noting that statutory
phrases are not construed in isolation, and are
instead read as a whole).
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
organized electricity markets (where
only annual rights to existing capacity
are available) strongly suggests that
Congress intended for the Commission
to direct such transmission
organizations to begin offering long-term
rights from existing capacity. A
reasonable interpretation is that
Congress believed FTRs to capacity at
the time of enactment were not
sufficiently long, and therefore directed
the Commission to make longer-term
rights to existing capacity available.
81. We disagree with comments
suggesting that section 217(c)
immunizes existing market designs and
transmission rights allocation methods
from the implementation of section
217(b)(4). The ‘‘savings clause’’ in
section 217(c) specifically provides that
‘‘[n]othing in subsections (b)(1), (b)(2),
and (b)(3)’’ of section 217 shall affect the
existing or future methodologies of
certain transmission organizations; that
clause expressly omits subsection (b)(4)
from its protections. As a result, section
217 permits the Commission to require
changes to existing market designs and
transmission rights allocation methods
if necessary to implement section
217(b)(4). This does not mean that the
Commission will require such changes
or that section 217(b)(4) requires
changes to existing designs and
allocations in all cases; if a transmission
organization can offer long-term firm
transmission rights that satisfy each of
the guidelines in this Final Rule while
retaining its current systems, it may do
so. We emphasize, however, that
transmission organizations must
provide long-term firm transmission
rights that satisfy each of the guidelines
in this Final Rule even if doing so
requires changes to existing systems.
82. Additionally, we disagree with
suggestions that transmission
organizations already provide long-term
firm transmission rights, and that
creation of long-term financial
transmission rights in this rulemaking is
unnecessary. While transmission
organizations may provide firm
‘‘physical’’ transmission rights on a
long-term basis, the cost of transmission
service in transmission organizations
that use LMP to manage congestion is
dependent on the cost of that
congestion. We agree with APPA that
for a transmission right to be ‘‘firm,’’ it
must be firm as to both quantity and
price. In the LMP context, this means
‘‘firm transmission rights’’ must be firm
as to both the ‘‘physical’’ component of
the right and the ‘‘financial’’ component
of the right. FTRs can hedge congestion
costs (when matched to the physical
path of the transmission right) and make
transmission rights in an LMP system
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
‘‘firm,’’ but are currently only available
for one year. As a result, to comply with
the directives of section 217(b)(4) and
section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005,
transmission organizations with LMP
and FTRs will need to offer FTRs with
longer terms to truly enable load serving
entities to secure firm transmission
rights on a long-term basis. Further, we
disagree with Cinergy’s contention that
the ‘‘or equivalent tradable or financial
rights’’ language in the statute suggests
that transmission organizations can offer
either long-term physical rights or longterm financial rights. Rather, we agree
with APPA that this language was
intended to address the FTRs used in
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets and
congestion management systems
(primarily LMP) that impact the cost of
transmission service. We read this
language as requiring the Commission to
exercise its FPA authority to enable all
load serving entities to obtain firm
transmission rights on a long-term basis,
whether they are located in a region
with more traditional ‘‘physical’’
transmission rights or a region that uses
LMP and FTRs.
83. Finally, we disagree with NYISO’s
contention that section 217 does not
require transmission organizations to
offer transmission rights with longer
terms than those they currently offer.
While some transmission organizations
could in theory have sufficiently longterm transmission rights and thus would
not be required to offer longer terms, if
the current transmission rights offered
by all transmission organizations were
sufficient, it is unclear why Congress
would have included the second clause
of section 217(b)(4) at all. Moreover, it
is reasonable to conclude that Congress
believed not all transmission
organizations were offering sufficient
long-term firm transmission rights given
that it focused the Commission’s
attention in section 1233(b) of EPAct
2005 on those entities, and given the
fact that long-term firm transmission
rights are available today in regions
without transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets. We
believe it is reasonable to conclude that
Congress was aware that the current
terms for transmission rights offered by
transmission organizations were
insufficient and drafted section
217(b)(4) of the FPA and section 1233(b)
of EPAct 2005 together to require that
they offer rights with longer terms.
D. Commission’s Approach, Regional
Flexibility, and Regional Seams Issues
84. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed a flexible regional approach to
satisfying the requirements of section
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43575
1233(b) of EPAct 2005. Specifically, we
proposed to establish a set of guidelines
for the design and administration of
long-term firm transmission rights in
organized electricity markets. Following
the establishment of these guidelines in
the Final Rule, we proposed to allow
each transmission organization subject
to the rule to develop specific long-term
firm transmission right designs through
its usual stakeholder process that would
fit the prevailing regional market design.
85. We stated that this flexible
approach was appropriate because there
is no ‘‘one size fits all’’ long-term firm
transmission right design that could be
implemented in each of the various
transmission organization markets.
However, we stated further that flexible
regional development must occur
within guidelines, to ensure that the
specific long-term firm transmission
rights ultimately proposed by
transmission organizations have certain
properties that are fundamental to
meeting the objectives of section
217(b)(4) of the FPA. Nonetheless, the
NOPR stated our intent that the
guidelines form only a framework for
further, more specific development of
long-term firm transmission right
designs through the usual stakeholder
process of each transmission
organization, and noted that the
guidelines should provide enough
flexibility to allow transmission
organizations and their stakeholders to
develop a specific long-term firm
transmission right design that fits the
prevailing market design and meets the
needs of market participants in that
region.
86. Finally, we noted the potential
that this flexible regional approach
could lead to regional seams issues, and
sought comments on any features of
long-term firm transmission rights that,
if not consistent across transmission
organizations, could interfere with the
effective operation of regional markets.
Comments
87. Several commenters, including
Industrial Consumers, Kentucky PSC,
LADWP, LIPA, Midwest ISO, MSATs,
NARUC, National Grid, NYDPS, NYISO,
PJM, Public Power Council, SoCal
Edison, and Wisconsin Electric all
support the Commission’s proposal to
develop guidelines, as opposed to
specific long-term firm transmission
rights designs, to allow for regional
flexibility. Many of these commenters
argue that regional flexibility is
essential, given that each transmission
organization has developed its own
market design to meet the needs of its
stakeholders and to accommodate
regional differences (including different
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43576
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
operating practices). They contend that
regional flexibility is also necessary to
honor the transitions already agreed to
by transmission organization
stakeholders.
88. While the commenters were
virtually unanimous that a ‘‘one-size fits
all’’ approach to implementing longterm firm transmission rights would not
be appropriate, the comments raise
issues regarding the amount of
flexibility that the Commission should
provide. Some commenters, including
Dominion, EEI, ISO–NE, and NSTAR
argue for more flexibility, including
flexibility within the requirements of
each guideline. For example, EEI states
that the Commission should issue only
‘‘basic principles’’ that focus on
‘‘reasonable outcomes,’’ and should
treat the guidelines as ‘‘a general
direction for future action’’ instead of
imposing them as prescriptive
requirements.48 EEI also suggests that
the Commission alter the general
direction under section (d) of the
proposed regulations to provide that
‘‘[t]ransmission organizations * * *
should to the extent they find
reasonable given their existing
arrangements make available long-term
transmission rights that satisfy the
following guidelines.’’ 49 Further, EEI
contends that no single guideline can or
should be mandatory, and that
transmission organizations and their
stakeholders should be given the first
opportunity to balance the guidelines to
best meet market participant needs.
ISO–NE argues that section 217(b)(4)
permits substantial flexibility, since it
does not require several design features
(including creating a ‘‘perfect hedge’’ for
load serving entities, a particular length
of term, or a priority mechanism.) New
York Transmission Owners argue that
the Commission should clarify that the
guidelines are not binding or mandatory
obligations, and that they do not
predetermine any particular result or
design for long-term firm transmission
rights.
89. Some commenters in New
England and New York, including NU
and Coral Power, note that there has not
been great demand for long-term firm
transmission rights in those regions.
Accordingly, NU argues that the
Commission should allow regional
flexibility in determining the extent to
which such rights are needed.50 In
reply, New England Public Systems
48 Comments
of EEI at 11.
at 18.
50 NU notes in reply comments that a working
group has been formed within NEPOOL to ‘‘address
whether the development of [long-term
transmission rights] in New England can be
accomplished.’’ Reply Comments of NU at 1.
49 Id.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
assert that the clear statutory directive
makes arguments regarding the lack of
interest in long-term rights or the lack
of need for such rights irrelevant.51
90. NSTAR states more generally that
imposing a Final Rule on long-term firm
transmission rights that is inconsistent
with the structure of a transmission
organization market, particularly a welldeveloped market reflecting an
extensive history of market operations,
would be ‘‘disruptive and counterproductive.’’ 52 Accordingly, NSTAR
advocates that the Final Rule allow the
greatest latitude possible to stakeholders
in established transmission organization
markets to develop rules for long-term
firm transmission rights. It argues that
section 217(c) of the FPA (stating that
subsections (b)(1), (b)(2) and (b)(3) do
not affect existing or future transmission
right allocation methodologies)
recognizes the historical practices
followed by transmission organizations
and permits the Commission to defer to
such practices, even if they are deemed
to differ from practices embodied in
subsections (b)(1) through (b)(3) of
section 217.53
91. Reliant states that the Commission
should recognize ongoing stakeholderdriven efforts in several existing
transmission organizations to develop
long-term firm transmission rights, and
provide sufficient leeway for such
markets to provide access to long-term
rights.
92. BPA states that in general it
supports the Commission’s flexible
approach, and states that the
Commission should allow sufficient
flexibility so as not to preclude
formation of transmission organizations
with regionally-developed
characteristics, such as the developing
proposals in the Northwest.54 It argues
that the Final Rule should address how
the guidelines will apply to
transmission organizations in the
process of forming organized electricity
markets.
93. Midwest ISO states that the
Commission should consider the
detrimental effect some of the proposed
guidelines could have on Midwest ISO
market participants and should ensure
that the terms it ultimately adopts allow
sufficient flexibility to ensure that they
can work in the Midwest ISO markets.
51 Reply Comments of New England Public
Systems at 6–7.
52 Comments of NSTAR at 11.
53 New England Public Systems argues in
response to NSTAR that section 217(c) does not
provide any basis for the wide flexibility NSTAR
advocates, since that section expressly omits
reference to section 217(b)(4).
54 See also Reply Comments of BP Energy at 10
(agreeing).
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
94. Others, including APPA, New
England Public Systems and TAPS,
argue that regional flexibility should not
be offered too broadly. They assert that
the Commission should make clear that
the Final Rule gives regions the
flexibility to decide how to implement
long-term rights, but not the flexibility
to decide whether to implement them at
all. NRECA also supports some regional
flexibility, but states that there must be
adequate minimum guidelines to ensure
that the objectives of section 217 of the
FPA are met. APPA and TAPS both
assert that the Commission explicitly
require transmission organizations to
fully comply with the provisions of the
Final Rule, and also suggest that the
Commission consider renaming the
guidelines ‘‘requirements’’ or
‘‘standards’’ to ensure that there is no
implication that the guidelines are only
advisory and may be disregarded.
Similarly, PG&E, while also supportive
of the Commission’s approach,
recommends that the Commission
further require transmission
organizations ‘‘to fulfill the guidelines
of the ultimate rule to the maximum
extent compatible with the realities of
their market and legal environment.’’ 55
95. Some commenters, including
Midwest TDUs and Industrial
Consumers, express concern that the use
of stakeholder procedures will not result
in the development of long-term firm
transmission rights that satisfy the
intent of the Commission and Congress.
Midwest TDUs express concern that
‘‘the stakeholder process will be used to
eviscerate long-term rights’’ given the
Midwest ISO’s ‘‘evident resistance to
long-term rights’’ and the opposition of
some Midwest ISO stakeholders.56 They
state further that ‘‘[i]mplementation of
these Congressionally-mandated rights
in a manner that achieves their crucial
purpose cannot depend on TDU’s ability
to overcome Midwest ISO’s resistance or
out-vote other stakeholders.’’ 57
Industrial Consumers state that they and
other industrial and customer groups
have had concerns that some
transmission organization stakeholder
processes do not have the proper
balance to guard against one side of the
market gaining an upper hand over the
other. Accordingly, Industrial
Consumers recommend that the
Commission provide guidance to ensure
that the stakeholder processes used to
develop long-term firm transmission
rights will include a balanced
composition of stakeholders, and
require each compliance filing to
55 Comments
of PG&E at 5.
Comments of Midwest TDUs at 6–7.
57 Id. at 7.
56 Reply
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
include a statement by the transmission
organization that the stakeholder
process was fair and impartial and did
not discriminate against load and load
serving entities.
96. With regard to the potential for the
Commission’s flexible approach to
create regional seams issues, comments
address both the potential for seams
between transmission organizations and
between transmission organization
regions and non-transmission
organization regions. Some commenters,
including APPA and PG&E, note that
different term lengths for long-term firm
transmission rights and different
processes for the allocation of long-term
rights (including different timetables)
are two areas where seams could arise.
TAPS states that the Commission
should require transmission
organizations to provide a mechanism
that allows load serving entities to
obtain long-term transmission rights
that cross seams and ensure that those
rights continue if new or different seams
emerge, and should require
transmission organizations to coordinate
their schedules for allocating long-term
rights that cross seams. BPA also notes
the possibility that a load serving
obligation might be met with a resource
outside the transmission organization,
and states that in such situations ‘‘the
transmission organization should
continue to provide long-term
transmission service for such deliveries
under existing and renewed
transmission contracts.’’ 58
97. TAPS and Wisconsin Electric
express specific concerns regarding the
potential for seams to develop between
Midwest ISO and PJM. TAPS contends
that the Commission should require
close coordination between Midwest
ISO and PJM with regard to the
definition of long-term firm
transmission rights and the process for
obtaining such rights, arguing that a
load serving entity should be able to
obtain rights crossing the border on a
consistent timeline (ideally through a
single process) to support a commitment
to baseload resources needed in both
transmission organization regions.
Wisconsin Electric argues that there
must be consistency between the two
regions with regard to the allocation of
long-term firm transmission rights to
ensure that a ‘‘financial wall’’ does not
develop, which would inhibit the ability
to flow energy under long-term
contracts between the regions.
98. MidAmerican states that the
Commission should require compliance
filings to address resulting seams and
how they will be resolved.
58 Comments
VerDate Aug<31>2005
Commission Conclusion
100. In this Final Rule, the
Commission adopts the guidelines
approach and the allowance for regional
flexibility set forth in the NOPR. This
approach will appropriately recognize
regional differences in market design,
while ensuring that long-term firm
transmission rights have certain
properties that are fundamental to
satisfying the mandate of Congress in
section 217(b)(4).
101. In response to comments seeking
additional flexibility, we emphasize that
we are adopting the guidelines approach
to ensure that transmission
organizations have the flexibility to
design long-term firm transmission
rights that fit their prevailing market
design. This flexibility is not intended
and should not be interpreted to allow
59 In response, CAISO notes that it has not and
will not discourage such parties from participating.
of BPA at 5.
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
MidAmerican, as well as NARUC, also
note that these issues can and should be
addressed in the Joint Operating
Agreements and Seams Operating
Agreements between transmission
organizations. NARUC urges the
Commission to clarify that tariff
provisions designed to award long-term
transmission rights will not adversely
impact these seams agreements, and
clarify that long-term rights granted
within a transmission organization will
not confer rights on the holder outside
that market. According to NARUC, these
clarifications are necessary to ensure
that costs for upgrades or expansions are
not transferred between transmission
organizations or a transmission
organization and non-transmission
organization utility and to ensure that
transmission rights in other regions are
not adversely impacted.
99. Comments also generally
addressed seams that might arise
between transmission organizations and
non-transmission organization regions.
APPA, for example, notes that nontransmission organization regions use
physical rights, and as a result financial
and physical rights must coexist to
ensure that future power supply and
transmission service arrangements are
not adversely impacted. CMUA states
that because CAISO operates a market
based on financial rights, while the rest
of the Western Interconnection consists
of bilateral markets with physical rights,
any regional stakeholder process to
develop long-term firm transmission
rights in CAISO should include the
Western Electricity Coordinating
Council (WECC), neighboring control
areas and relevant transmission owners
in the West.59
Jkt 208001
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43577
transmission organizations the latitude
to decide whether long-term firm
transmission rights should be
implemented at all. Congress has
directed in both section 217(b)(4) of the
FPA and section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005
that load serving entities have the
ability to obtain long-term firm
transmission rights to meet their
reasonable needs to satisfy their service
obligations. Congress also specifically
directed that such rights be
implemented in the transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets, through section 1233(b)’s
charge that the Commission implement
section 217(b)(4) within one year in
those regions. As a result, the
implementation of long-term firm
transmission rights by transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets is mandatory.
102. We reject comments suggesting
that the guidelines be treated as merely
general directives. As noted above, the
guidelines are intended to ensure that
long-term firm transmission rights have
certain properties we believe are
necessary to fulfill Congress’ directives.
Particularly, the guidelines are designed
to ensure that the long-term firm
transmission rights are truly ‘‘longterm’’ and ‘‘firm,’’ and that they can be
used to deliver the output of long-term
power supply arrangements to load
serving entities, as section 217(b)(4)
requires. As a result, transmission
organizations must satisfy each of the
guidelines when complying with the
Final Rule. We have modified the
proposed regulatory text to clarify this
requirement.
103. With regard to flexibility within
each guideline, the Commission
believes that each of the guidelines
already provides sufficient flexibility to
allow transmission organizations to
satisfy them in a manner that fits their
individual market design. Each of the
guidelines state basic, fundamental
properties that long-term firm
transmission rights must possess, but
are not prescriptive market design
mandates. Thus, while proposals to
comply with this Final Rule must satisfy
each of the guidelines, we believe each
of the guidelines may be satisfied in any
number of ways, and we do not intend
that the guidelines predetermine any
particular design.
104. In response to comments
suggesting that there has been little
demand for long-term firm transmission
rights in New York and New England,
we note that we agree with New
England Public Systems that regardless
of the level of interest in such rights,
Congress has mandated that they be
available to meet load serving entities
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43578
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
reasonable needs. Thus, while we are
adopting a flexible approach, that
flexibility does not extend to deciding
whether such rights are needed, as NU
suggests it should. The fact that only a
few stakeholders in a particular region
seek long-term firm transmission rights
can be a design consideration, however,
as we discuss in more detail elsewhere
in this Final Rule.
105. BPA asks that the Commission
address how the guidelines will apply
to transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets that are
being developed, and asks that we retain
sufficient flexibility so that regional
efforts to develop a transmission
organization in the Northwest are not
precluded. As we state above, we
conclude that the guidelines approach
in the Final Rule provides enough
flexibility to ensure that long-term rights
can be developed with regional
characteristics while still meeting the
statutory objectives of section 217(b)(4).
Entities in the process of forming
transmission organizations should take
into account the requirements of this
Final Rule and how the market designs
they file will satisfy the rule.
106. In response to the comments of
Industrial Consumers and Midwest
TDUs regarding the use of stakeholder
procedures to develop specific longterm firm transmission rights proposals,
we do not believe it is necessary to
specifically direct that any particular
stakeholder procedures be used.
Transmission organizations have
Commission-approved procedures in
place that specify the stakeholder
process and conditions and criteria by
which they may file proposals with the
Commission. Comments suggesting that
such procedures are flawed are outside
the scope of this proceeding.
107. Regarding the potential for
regional seams, the comments indicate
that seams are most likely to develop
where the terms of long-term rights and
the procedures (including timelines) for
allocating such rights are not
sufficiently coordinated. We agree with
commenters that transmission
organizations should consider these
issues when complying with the Final
Rule. Additionally, we agree that
revising the already existing seams
agreements between transmission
organizations, if necessary, could be one
vehicle to address seams issues related
to long-term rights that arise between
transmission organizations.
Accordingly, we direct each
transmission organization to explain in
its compliance filing how its proposal
addresses potential seams issues,
particularly with regard to the term of
the long-term rights offered and the
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
procedures and timelines for obtaining
such rights. With regard to potential
seams between transmission
organizations, each transmission
organization should also explain why it
has or has not elected to revise its seams
agreements.
E. Guidelines for the Design and
Administration of Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights in Organized
Electricity Markets
Guideline (1)—Specify Source, Sink and
Quantity
108. As proposed in the NOPR,
guideline (1) stated that the long-term
firm transmission right should be a
point-to-point right that specifies a
source (injection node or nodes) and
sink (withdrawal node or nodes), and a
quantity (MW). The discussion of this
guideline pointed out that flowgate
rights were not precluded from
consideration as long as they could
hedge a point-to-point transmission
schedule.
Comments
109. Guideline (1) is generally
supported by commenters. Most
commenters recognize that current
transmission organization market
designs for specifying and allocating
transmission rights largely adopt the
source point and sink point
requirements of guideline (1). But there
are exceptions. In particular, some
commenters note that ISO–NE does not
allocate auction revenue rights on a
point-to-point basis.
Flexibility in Source and Sink
Designation
110. Several commenters request that
guideline (1) explicitly recognize nodal
aggregations, such as zones or hubs, as
sources and sinks.60 ISO–NE notes that
spot market purchases by load are
priced on a zonal basis in its system and
that allocation of zone-to-zone long-term
transmission rights would be more
desirable than allocation of point-topoint rights. PJM Public Power
Coalition, Public Power Council and
Strategic Energy request that guideline
(1) should not be interpreted to require
that long-term rights are tied to specific
generation resources, but rather to
points or aggregates on the transmission
system. Several commenters note that
the boundary nodes can serve as sources
or sinks.
111. Other source/sink designation
issues pertaining to guideline (1) were
raised by commenters that are, or will
be, transmission customers but that are
60 See, e.g., AEP, Coral Power, IPL, ISO–NE,
NEPOOL, Reliant and TAPS.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
located outside the transmission
organization markets. SMUD stresses
that in California, long-term rights must
be developed for transmission
customers that use through and out
service. SMUD argues that the
Commission should require that
allocation criteria for long-term rights
will not be dependent upon where load
is located, but rather on whether, by its
use of the system, the customer will
make substantial contribution to
recovery of the transmission system’s
fixed costs.
Consistency of Current Market Rules
With Guideline 1
112. Some commenters state that the
current rules for allocating ARRs and
auctioning FTRs in ISO–NE are not
consistent with guideline (1) in
combination with guideline (7). New
England Public Systems notes that
under the ISO–NE market rules, most
ARRs are allocated among congestionpaying load serving entities on a zonal
load ratio share basis. Each such load
serving entity is paid the auction
clearing price of an average FTR in the
zone times the ratio of its peak load to
the zonal peak load. This rule does not
offer assurance that the revenues
received will be sufficient to enable the
load serving entity to acquire a specific
point-to-point FTR across a particular
congested path. New England Public
Systems thus requests that the
Commission confirm that in New
England, FTRs awarded under the
current rules cannot simply be extended
in term. Instead, under guidelines (1)
and (7), ISO–NE should provide either
the allocation of point-to-point longterm transmission rights or point-topoint long-term ARRs that can be
converted to long-term transmission
rights.
Other Issues
113. CMUA, NRECA and SMUD argue
that guideline (1) should be modified
and clarified so that it does not rule out
long-term rights with properties of
Order No. 888 network service rights for
network transmission customers. In
particular, these commenters argue that
long-term firm transmission rights
should afford the customer the
flexibility to change receipt and delivery
points without penalty. In contrast,
Cinergy argues that long-term rights
should not be allowed to have
characteristics of Order No. 888 network
rights.
114. CMUA and SMUD request that
guideline (1) not limit the ability of
transmission organizations to consider
other types of rights that meet the
commercial needs of load serving
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
entities. In particular, they discuss
contractual rights that are
‘‘bidirectional’’ in nature to support
seasonal power supply arrangements in
the West and for which they propose
option transmission rights in each
direction of the transaction.
115. There were several
miscellaneous comments on guideline
(1). PJM states that the Final Rule would
benefit from clarification that there are
no requirements with respect to the
nature of the right—i.e., physical versus
financial—and explicitly state that this
issue will be determined by the regions.
We address this issue in Section II.F,
‘‘Alternative Designs for Long-Term
Firm Transmission Rights.’’ APPA
requests that as part of compliance with
guideline (1), each transmission
organization should be required to
establish rules that prevent gaming of
the long-term rights allocation by
swapping of generation resources. This
issue was raised by several other parties
in conjunction with guideline (5) and
we address it there.
Commission Conclusion
116. We will adopt guideline (1)
without modification. The primary
objective of guideline (1), consistent
with section 217(b)(4), is to allow a load
serving entity to obtain a long-term firm
transmission right for purposes of
hedging congestion charges associated
with delivery of power from a long-term
power supply arrangement to its load.
Moreover, as several commenters noted,
guideline (1) is largely consistent with
existing designs for FTRs in the
organized electricity markets operated
by transmission organizations.
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Flexibility in Source and Sink
Designation
117. We clarify that guideline (1)
permits specification of long-term firm
transmission rights to hedge zonal or
hub pricing where, for example,
congestion prices are calculated using a
weighted average of the locational
marginal prices within a zone.
Guideline (1) also permits specification
of long-term transmission rights from
points on the network, such as
boundary locations, that are not the
locations of specific generators. For
customers with through and out service,
we would expect that transmission
organizations will establish long-term
firm transmission rights corresponding
to the terms and conditions of existing
transmission contracts. However, if
quantity limits are established for the
allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights, then rules may be
needed to determine the eligibility of
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
43579
through and out service, based, for
example, on historical usage patterns.
efficient nominations and equitable
allocations.
Consistency of Current Market Rules
with Guideline (1)
118. Based on the comments, only
ISO–NE has adopted a financial rights
model for transmission rights that does
not directly allocate rights that are
point-to-point to eligible market
participants. We will require ISO–NE to
adopt rules for allocation of long-term
firm transmission rights that are
consistent with guidelines (1) and (7).
However, as discussed below, we note
that ISO–NE does not have to provide
the same allocation rules for short-term
rights as it does for long-term rights.
119. We understand that in some
organized electricity markets,
particularly in regions with substantial
divestiture of generation capacity and
retail choice such as that of ISO–NE,
hedging particular generation resources
with financial transmission rights is not
the prevailing approach; rather, buyers
and sellers have adopted portfolio
approaches to power supply contracts
and hold financial transmission rights
based on their expected revenues from
congested transmission paths rather
than on their ability to hedge specific
resources. We do not intend for this
Final Rule to obstruct that business
model, but note that other entities in
these regions are not following such a
business model. As a result, they seek
transmission rights that hedge
congestion charges associated with
delivering power from particular
generators to their load. Guideline (1) is
intended to support the ability of load
serving entities to obtain point-to-point
long-term transmission rights that will
hedge particular long-term power
supply arrangements. Guideline (7) is
intended to support the ability of load
serving entities to obtain such rights
without having to purchase the rights in
an auction. We will thus require all
transmission organizations to offer longterm firm transmission rights that are
consistent with these guidelines. This is
not to say that transmission
organizations like ISO–NE must adopt
new allocation rules and apply them for
both short-term rights and long-term
rights. To the extent that a transmission
organization can satisfy requests for
long-term firm transmission rights
under these guidelines, but stakeholders
prefer remaining with existing rules for
short-term rights, we will consider
proposals that use such a ‘‘two-track’’
approach. At the same time, as we
discuss in guideline (2), there might be
advantages to harmonizing at least some
rules between short-term and long-term
rights to ensure that the rules encourage
Other Issues
120. We will not modify guideline (1)
to require allocation of long-term
transmission rights with properties of
Order No. 888 network service, as
requested by NRECA and SMUD. In
general, we have not precluded any
design that stakeholders could agree on,
but we do require that designs support
equitable allocation of transmission
rights (see discussion in Section II.F,
‘‘Alternative Designs for Long-Term
Firm Transmission Rights’’). The right
to change receipt and delivery points
without penalty could, under most rules
for allocation of financial transmission
rights, deprive other load serving
entities of their eligible rights.61 Hence,
the rules in organized electricity
markets generally require parties that
are converting Order 888 network rights
to financial rights to select a fixed
distribution of source points for their
total MW eligibility over their network
resources.
121. We will not modify guideline (1)
to explicitly support ‘‘bidirectional’’
transmission rights. CMUA defines such
rights as ‘‘option’’ rights in either
direction. We discuss the difficulties in
allocating option rights equitably in
Section II.F, ‘‘Alternative Designs for
Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights.’’
There are other solutions. Sufficient
granularity of the transmission rights
specified as obligation rights would
allow the rights to better track the power
flows in contractual arrangements.
Guideline (1) also does not preclude
flowgate rights, which have option
properties. All of these approaches, and
possibly others, could be used to
address situations where power flows
change direction on a regular basis.
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Guideline (2)—Long-Term Hedge That
Cannot Be Modified
122. As proposed in the NOPR,
guideline (2) stated that the long-term
firm transmission right must provide a
hedge against locational marginal
pricing congestion charges (or other
direct assignment of congestion costs)
for the period covered and quantity
specified. Once allocated, the financial
coverage provided by the right should
not be modified during its term except
in the case of extraordinary
circumstances or through voluntary
61 For example, consider a load serving entity that
is eligible for 100 MW of FTRs and that requests
that the entire quantity is sourced at each of four
network resources that it has historically used, each
of which is capable of providing the full amount,
thus encumbering up to 400 MW of transmission
capacity.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43580
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
agreement of both the holder of the right
and the transmission organization. We
refer to the provision that the payments
from the rights should not be
prorationed (with the exceptions as
mentioned) as ‘‘full funding.’’
123. The NOPR sought comments on
how to fully fund the long-term rights.
Since the transmission organization is
revenue neutral, fully funding the rights
requires that a revenue shortfall is
collected from some set of market
participants to make holders of the
rights whole. The NOPR asked whether
such charges should be allocated to
transmission owners that are
responsible for maintaining and
expanding the transmission capacity
supporting the long-term firm
transmission rights when the revenue
shortfalls are due to inadequate
maintenance or expansion. The NOPR
further asked for comment on whether
there are appropriate methods for
allocating such charges that also provide
appropriate incentives for transmission
usage, maintenance and expansion. The
NOPR also noted that payments to
already awarded long-term rights may
be prorationed in the case of
extraordinary circumstances, such as a
sustained unplanned outage of a large
transmission line. Such situations may
require alternative rules for financial
settlement of the rights.
Comments
124. Guideline (2) drew strongly
opposing views with regard to full
funding for the term of the long-term
transmission right and the question of
who should pay to support full funding.
Some commenters opposed full funding,
arguing that it is not a viable option.
Those who held this view also typically
argued that full funding should be an
option to be determined on a regional
basis, and should not be mandated by
the Commission. Other commenters
strongly supported full funding. Among
the latter commenters, and among those
that opposed full funding but
recognized that the Commission may
nevertheless require it, there was
significant disagreement over the set of
market participants that should pay to
provide the full funding guarantee and
under what conditions. In particular,
transmission owners were strongly
against the proposal that they should
provide a ‘‘backstop’’ to support full
funding and rejected arguments that
such a rule would have a positive
incentive effect on transmission
maintenance and investment.
125. There was general support for the
proposal that extraordinary
circumstances may result in a
suspension of full funding, but several
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
commenters requested clarification on
what constitutes such circumstances.
Full Funding: Criticisms and
Alternative Proposals
126. Several commenters oppose the
proposed full funding requirement.62
OMS and Midwest ISO state that full
funding is inequitable, would cause
significant cost shifting between market
participants, and is beyond the scope of
section 217(b)(4). Midwest ISO argues
that requiring a ‘‘perfect’’ hedge clearly
exceeds a load serving entity’s
‘‘reasonable’’ needs. Moreover, cost
shifting would take place because, if
entities eligible for long-term firm
transmission rights have priority in the
allocation of transmission rights (as
proposed in guideline (5) in the NOPR),
they may limit the quantity of shortterm rights available. Further, Midwest
ISO is concerned that other parties may
have to pick up revenue shortfalls
associated with the long-term rights.
127. EEI, IPL, Midwest ISO, MSATs
and OMS argue that full funding is a
higher level of certainty for transmission
rights than was available historically.
Outside the organized markets, firm
point-to-point and network transmission
service have never been fully
guaranteed. Rather, they have always
been subject to potential curtailment
through TLRs. They have also been
subject to rate increases and redispatch
costs. EEI argues that a long-term right
that strives to provide a ‘‘perfect hedge’’
would be too expensive and that the
Commission should instead aim for
balance in the protection offered. IPL
argues that section 217(b)(4) does not
mandate a zero-risk solution for load
serving entities, but rather to address
their reasonable needs. IPL suggests that
the Commission interpret what
properties of financial transmission
rights would provide reasonable risk
mitigation equivalent to firm
transmission rights under the OATT.
128. TAPS replies to such arguments
by noting that it is seeking full funding
only for long-term firm transmission
rights used to deliver the output of
baseload resources. Hence, for the
remaining transmission usage, the
holder would be exposed to uncertainty
over the allocation of rights and hence
congestion cost exposure.
129. Midwest ISO argues that full
funding is not always necessary to
provide a full hedge. This is because the
revenues from point-to-point FTRs used
to hedge congestion charges associated
with a particular resource or portfolio of
62 These include CAISO, EEI, IPL, ISO–NE,
Midwest ISO, MSATs, NU, OMS, SoCal Edison and
Xcel.
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
resources can be either greater than or
less than the congestion charges paid by
transmission customers.
130. CAISO argues that each
transmission organization should be
allowed to determine the rules for
revenue sufficiency of financial
transmission rights in a manner that
best weighs the equities in each regional
market. Similarly, CPUC is concerned
that establishing a long-term revenue
guarantee at the start of the CAISO’s
LMP markets will ‘‘tie the hands’’ of the
CAISO if it needs to adjust the market
design to improve implementation.
131. ISO–NE, which does not
currently fully fund transmission rights,
emphasizes the difficulty of assigning
funding responsibility. ISO–NE urges
the Commission to conserve
stakeholder, transmission organization
and Commission resources by not
creating new sources of conflict in a
region.
132. AEP argues that by creating fully
funded long-term rights, guideline (2)
does not provide flexibility to recognize
system changes over the long-term.
Similarly, IPL states that locking in
rights shifts risks between parties rather
than mitigating risk and may create
greater risks over time. The transmission
organization should be allowed to predefine methodologies to adapt the rights
to changing circumstances.
133. A number of commenters argue
that full funding could provide
disincentives for investment in
transmission. For example, AEP argues
that when doing proper planning and
with the right incentives, the
transmission organization must be
continuously revising its forecasts of
transmission and generation availability
(e.g., additions and retirements) to meet
load growth. This will change the
electrical configuration of the grid. By
fixing transmission rights over the longterm with the full funding revenue
requirements, the transmission
organization could inhibit construction
of new facilities that would provide
greater benefits to customers.
134. Xcel argues that providing full
funding in the event of a long-term
change in grid capability could result in
a perpetuation of windfall revenues or
severe losses for holders of transmission
rights and unjust socialization of those
costs across the industry.
135. AF&PA believes that guideline
(2) may be extremely difficult to
implement in a nondiscriminatory
fashion because of valuation issues
associated with estimates of congestion
cost for extended periods.
136. As an alternative to full funding,
several commenters argue that in the
event of revenue shortfalls, prorationing
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
of payments should be the rule for longterm rights (as it is currently for annual
FTRs in organized markets other than
NYISO). NU argues that treating longterm rights differently from short-term
rights would be discriminatory. Reliant
argues that any prorationing of
transmission rights payments due to
revenue shortfalls should be allocated
on a MW by MW basis to all
transmission rights regardless of their
terms. Beyond this principle, the
Commission should let regional
approaches determine the details.
Cinergy and SoCal Edison state that in
the event of revenue shortfalls,
payments to holders of long-term rights
should be rationed on a pro-rata basis.
SoCal Edison argues that holders of
long-term rights should factor the risk of
revenue prorationing into the prices that
they pay to procure those rights and into
their long-term energy and capacity
contracts.
137. In light of these concerns, a
number of commenters argue, for
various reasons, that the Commission
should not mandate full funding, but
rather leave it to regions to determine
whether or not to pursue full funding.63
138. MSATs propose that full funding
could be a voluntary insurance made
available by third-party providers for an
insurance premium. MSATs request that
this option be considered in the Final
Rule.
139. OMS argues that the full funding
guarantee for long-term rights will make
such rights more valuable relative to
annual rights, assuming that the latter
remain subject to prorationing. OMS
argues that there could be two possible
consequences: First, transmission
organizations will be extremely
conservative in the quantity of longterm rights that they allocate, and
second, there will be a significant
reduction in rights available for the
annual allocation. Load serving entities
will seek long-term rights and if the
transmission organization cannot honor
all requests, significant cost shifts will
result. Hence, OMS proposes that fully
funded long-term rights should be
assessed a risk premium.
140. Ameren argues that rather than
attempt to address the issue of revenue
insufficiency through full funding
guarantees, the solution is to address
flaws in the transmission organization’s
simultaneous feasibility model. Ameren
argues that if the modeling was more
accurate, the allocation of financial
transmission rights would be less likely
to become revenue inadequate and
uplift would be minimized. Ameren
63 See, e.g., CAISO, CPUC, EEI, IPL, NEPOOL,
NU, OMS, and Reliant.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
prefers that any remaining uplift
associated with transmission rights
should be assigned pro rata over all
financial transmission rights holders.
Full Funding: Support and Clarification
141. A number of commenters are
supportive of full funding of long-term
rights.64 However, there were
differences in the scope of coverage that
they proposed and how the costs of full
funding would be allocated.
142. NYISO states that it is already in
compliance with guideline (2) because
its financial transmission rights
(Transmission Congestion Contracts) are
already fully funded, with transmission
owners paying any revenue shortfalls.
However, New York Transmission
Owners argue that the transmission
rights allocated in New York to support
native load are not currently consistent
with guideline (2) because they are
allocated annually and the quantities
may not be the same each year. To fix
the quantities from year to year, they
argue that NYISO would presumably
have either to reduce the quantity
allocated, create counterflow rights, or
eliminate the simultaneous feasibility
test, all of which could create
congestion rent shortfalls in the dayahead market. New York Transmission
Owners argue that each of these choices
is ‘‘unpalatable’’ and would upset the
result of negotiations among them that
led to the current allocation
methodology. Hence, they argue that it
is critical that the Commission ensure
that NYISO and stakeholders have
flexibility in the development of the
rules for long-term rights.
143. TAPS argues that the full funding
guarantee would place the burden on
the transmission organizations to be
accountable for the performance of the
transmission rights that they allocate.
TAPS further argues that to provide true
certainty, guideline (2) should be paired
with ‘‘requirements that (1) the full cost
associated with securing long-term
rights (and applicable renewals) be
established with reasonable certainty up
front; and (2) RTOs broadly allocate
responsibility for funding revenue
shortfalls for long-term rights consistent
with guideline (2)’s price stability
goal.’’ 65
144. New England Public Systems
argue that full funding is consistent
with the underlying principles of Order
No. 888 and with section 217(b)(4).
Under Order No. 888, holders of
transmission contracts have the right to
64 See, e.g., Alcoa, Allegheny, APPA, BP Energy,
CMUA, Coral Power, Industrial Consumers, New
England Public Systems, NCPA, NRECA, NYISO,
Peabody, PJM, PG&E, and TAPS.
65 Comments of TAPS at 15.
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43581
renew service when contracts expire,
and transmission providers are required
to plan and expand facilities to meet
transmission customer needs.
Transmission providers also bear
redispatch costs, which provided a
further incentive to expand
transmission capacity to accommodate
known or predictable uses. APPA
similarly argues that full funding is
consistent with section 217(b)(4). This is
because that requirement is intended to
provide financial certainty over the
transmission component of the ‘‘all in’’
cost of a long-term generation resource.
145. A number of commenters,
including TAPS, Public Power Coalition
and Wisconsin Electric, propose that
long-term rights should be allocated for
a limited quantity of load serving
entities’’ load, specifically base-load. A
few commenters, such as TAPS, also
include rights to renewable generation
resources. Hence, full funding would
only extend to that quantity of rights.
PJM agrees that a limited application of
full funding is feasible.
146. A number of parties note that full
funding will require a consistent
approach to transmission planning and
expansion to minimize the potential for
cost shifting. We address the
relationship of long-term firm
transmission rights and transmission
planning and expansion in Section II.E,
‘‘Transmission Planning and
Expansion.’’
147. BPA suggests that while
locational marginal pricing may not be
the congestion pricing model adopted in
the Pacific Northwest, the principles
underlying guideline (2) should be
upheld. BPA argues that cost stability
for long-term transmission should
prevail over concerns about equity and
fairness of the allocation of long-term
rights and associated costs among
market participants.
Full Funding Cost Allocation
148. On the proper allocation of
responsibility for revenue shortfalls,
several commenters supporting full
funding argue that some or all of the
revenue shortfalls encountered by longterm rights should be funded by
transmission owners. Industrial
Consumers argues that transmission
organizations cannot manage risks
associated with financial transmission
rights, and that such risks can only be
managed by transmission owners.
149. A few commenters that support
the assignment of full funding uplift to
transmission owners argue for limits on
the obligations of transmission owners.
PJM Public Power Coalition states that
transmission owners should be held
accountable for inadequate maintenance
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43582
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
practices or poor system planning and
any resulting long-term rights funding
shortfall should be assigned to them.
Similarly, BP Energy argues that
revenue shortfalls should be assigned to
transmission owners only if they are
due to negligence. NRECA and TAPS
argue that the assignment of revenue
shortfalls to transmission owners is
appropriate only if the transmission
owner fails to fulfill in good faith the
transmission organization’s instruction
to plan and construct transmission
facilities. Absent that situation, TAPS
argues that funding responsibility
should be broadly shared by all users of
the transmission grid on a pro rata basis,
since the failure is the transmission
organization’s failure to plan and
expand the system.
150. Most transmission owning
utilities and some other commenters
argue that transmission owners should
not be required to fully fund long-term
rights (under most circumstances).66
First, several of these commenters note
that when a transmission owner joins a
transmission organization, it cedes
short-term control (e.g., redispatch) of
the transmission system, and as a result
cannot manage any parties’ exposure to
congestion charges. Second, in the
planning process, it is the transmission
organization that must undertake the
planning for upgrades and approve new
transmission facilities to reduce
congestion. Third, decisions of siting
authorities and input of stakeholders
significantly affect location of new
facilities and when they are brought online. Fourth, due to the nature of power
flows in a large regional transmission
organization, it may be difficult to
determine exactly which transmission
owners are responsible for changes in
transmission capability. Fifth, just as
important to revenue adequacy as
building new facilities is the design of
the transmission rights and the
modeling used in their allocation.
Under most transmission organization
rules, transmission owners cannot
directly reduce the quantity of rights
that are allocated or auctioned to
manage their exposure to full funding
uplift charges (although some
commenters note that guideline (2) may
create an incentive for the transmission
owner to do so indirectly by providing
the transmission organization with
conservative ratings for transmission
facilities). Moreover, transmission
organizations control the development
and implementation of the models that
66 See, e.g., AEP, Ameren, BP Energy,
Constellation, Dominion, Duquesne, EEI, IPL,
Midwest ISO, MSATs, NU, NSTAR, PG&E, SoCal
Edison and Xcel.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
underlie FTR allocation. Sixth,
transmission transfer capability is often
affected by factors outside the
transmission owners’ and transmission
organization’s control, such as loop
flow. Seventh, transmission owners
would need the ability to raise
transmission rates to cover funding
obligations, through FERC and/or state
commissions. IPL notes that since a
proposed transmission facility (required
for purposes of transmission rights held
by others) may have limited local
benefits, state approvals may be difficult
to obtain.67 Finally, IPL and PG&E argue
that requiring transmission owners to
fully fund long-term rights would serve
as an incentive for transmission owners
to leave transmission organizations.
151. IPL and Reliant argue that the
Commission should not attempt to use
the revenue sufficiency rules for longterm rights as an incentive for
transmission investment, which is better
addressed through separate
incentives.68 MSATs argue that the
Commission cannot shift costs to
transmission owners ‘‘based solely on
the mere theory that doing so might
create some potentially worthwhile
incentives.’’ 69 MSATs argue that those
supporting making transmission owners
the ‘‘backstop’’ funders of long-term
rights have failed to provide a
‘‘sustainable justification’’ for such a
requirement.70 Ameren argues that
second guessing transmission owners’
business decisions after a transmission
outage or bottleneck would only distract
attention and effort from planning,
funding and designing needed
expansions and repairs. For the reasons
stated above, IPL and PG&E state that
assigning full funding to transmission
owners is arbitrary and unreasonable
because it not consistent with cost
causation principles.
152. MSATs note that transmission
owners that are transcos (firms that own
regulated transmission assets only)
would be particularly problematic
because such firms do not hold FTRs.
MSATs ask that the Commission
recognize that such a requirement
would directly conflict with the transco
67 For example, Allegheny argues that if the
Commission requires full funding by transmission
owners, it must also establish a mechanism that
allows for automatic pass-through of the costs to
ratepayers.
68 For example, IPL cites the Commission’s
rulemaking efforts with regard to establishing
Electric Reliability Organizations and Transmission
Pricing Reform, and also the work of Midwest ISO’s
Regional Expansion Criteria and Benefits (RECB)
Task Force. Comments of IPL at 6.
69 Comments of MSATs at 11 (citing North
Carolina v. FERC, 584 F.2d 1003, 1014 (D.C. Cir.
1978) (emphasis in the original)).
70 Reply Comments of MSATs at 9.
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
business model for two primary reasons.
First, transcos are neither transmission
customers nor market participants.
Hence, requiring transcos to take a
position in the transmission rights
markets would be inconsistent with
their business model. It would also be
inequitable to transcos. Second, transcos
rely on a revenue stream that is far more
concentrated than that of a vertically
integrated utility. MSATs claim that the
liability associated with underfunded
transmission rights could exceed a
transco’s total transmission servicedependent revenue in some cases.
153. Allegheny argues that while it
can support full funding, the
transmission organization should be
responsible for providing full funding
through its transmission customers.
Allegheny recommends that this charge
be assessed on all long-term firm and
network transmission customers. In a
similar vein, PG&E argues that while
full funding is desirable, it should be
allocated to transmission organization
customers, who benefit from long-term
investment in energy infrastructure.
154. Several commenters propose that
only the holders of long-term
transmission rights be collectively
allocated the costs of any revenue
inadequacy associated with the rights.71
For example, Duquesne recommends
that holders of transmission rights be
allocated any costs associated with
deficiencies in transmission revenues,
because these parties benefit from the
transmission rights markets. IPL argues
that pro rata sharing of funding
shortfalls by all load serving entities
with long-term rights is the only
reasonable approach in the absence of a
clear cost-causation relationship.
155. Midwest ISO proposes that to the
extent that market participants should
be responsible for long-term rights
revenue shortfalls, a mechanism to
ensure such cost recovery should be
made part of ‘‘economic’’ transmission
upgrades. Economic upgrades should be
defined to include those required to
maintain FTR feasibility based on a
cost-benefit analysis. In contrast, APPA
argues that the transmission planning
process should take account of longterm rights and designate transmission
facilities to maintain the feasibility of
the rights as ‘‘reliability’’ upgrades.
156. TAPS argues that assignment of
revenue shortfalls to holders of longterm rights would be the equivalent of
pro-rationing the rights. Similarly, in its
reply comments, APPA argues that
holders of long-term rights should not
be assigned funding shortfalls due to the
71 See, e.g., Duquesne, E.ON, IPL, MSATs,
NSTAR, and SoCal Edison.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
failure of the transmission organization
to plan for and ensure construction of
necessary transmission facilities. APPA
also notes that holders of long-term
rights that are not transmission owners
are least able to ensure that the
transmission system can support them.
157. A number of parties express
concern that funding of transmission
rights may not be equitable between
long-term and short-term rights.72
CAISO argues that when considering
rules for revenue inadequacy, long-term
rights should not have elevated status
over short-term rights. They maintain
that even holders of long-term rights
will typically hold some level of shortterm rights. In parts of the West, where
patterns of supply have a great deal of
annual variability, giving longer-term
rights preferential status will be
inequitable with respect to the holders
of short-term rights.
158. Cinergy, Midwest ISO and Suez
are concerned that the funding
guarantees in guideline (2) will shift
costs from long-term contract holders to
short-term contract holders. They argue
that such cost-shifting will be unduly
discriminatory and preferential and
violate the Federal Power Act. Reliant
agrees that cost-shifting will occur and
proposes that the Commission provide a
forum for discussion of ‘‘best practices’’
to maximize the availability of shortterm and long-term rights to all
customers.
159. In reply, APPA argues that
because long-term firm transmission
rights support long-term power supply
arrangements, and the holders of such
rights would be committed to paying a
share of transmission fixed costs over
the period of the rights, there is a legal
and policy rationale for giving long-term
rights more protection from proration or
revenue insufficiency than holders of
short-term rights.
Definition of Extraordinary
Circumstances
160. Several commenters supported
generally the inclusion of the exception
to full funding under ‘‘extraordinary
circumstances.’’ 73 No commenters
argued against such an exception,
although several asked for clarification.
ISO-NE encourages the Commission to
clarify the definition of ‘‘extraordinary
circumstances’’ that would permit
modification of the financial coverage
provided by long-term transmission
rights.
161. TAPS asks that the definition of
‘‘extraordinary circumstances’’ be
72 See, e.g., CAISO, Cinergy, Midwest ISO,
NSTAR, Reliant and Suez.
73 In support, see BP Energy, NYISO, and PJM
Public Power Coalition.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
clarified such that it is only applied in
the event of a catastrophic regional
problem such as a widespread blackout
or a massive force majeure event. TAPS
argues that the example in the NOPR of
a sustained unplanned outage of a large
transmission line is ‘‘precisely the type
of situation when an LSE should not be
stripped of its long-term rights.’’ 74
TAPS argues that in the event of a
sustained line outage, long-term rights
should remain fully funded and the
shortfall uplifted, for example, on a load
ratio basis. Similarly, APPA argues that
the suspension of full funding should
take place only if the situation should
be ‘‘truly extraordinary’’ and not a
contingency that should have been
anticipated in routine transmission
planning.
162. NRECA is concerned that the
exception for ‘‘extraordinary
circumstances’’ will undermine the
certainty that guideline (2) is supposed
to confer. NRECA requests that the
Commission clarify when this exception
would apply or remove it from the
guideline.
Other Issues
163. BP energy argues that the full
funding rule could result in market
gaming in the event of a transmission
outage. BP Energy suggests that the
Commission consider the methodology
to limit gaming adopted by ERCOT and
the Texas PUC. When there is a revenue
insufficiency, ERCOT limits the
payment on an oversold FTR to its
‘‘legitimate hedge’’ value as established
by substituting the resource’s marginal
cost for the LMP at the source
(generation) node of the FTR. Any
remaining revenue shortfall is uplifted
to all FTR holders.
Proposed Revisions of Guideline 2
164. Several commenters propose
revisions to guideline (2). EEI proposes
to revise the guideline to state that the
rights are financial, apply only to dayahead congestion charges, and are
subject to the transmission
organization’s rules and terms
established prior to the introduction of
long-term rights. EEI suggests that the
guideline specify that the long-term
right ‘‘should’’ rather than ‘‘must’’
provide a fully funded hedge.
165. In their reply comments, APPA,
NRECA and TAPS oppose EEI’s
proposed revisions, arguing that they
seek to weaken guideline (2) and
frustrate Congress’s purpose in enacting
section 217(b)(4). In particular, they
argue that EEI seeks to make full
funding non-mandatory and subject to
74 Comments
PO 00000
Frm 00021
of TAPS at 16.
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43583
the transmission organization’s existing
rules rather than the Commission’s
guideline. In addition, NRECA argues
that the rights should not be limited to
financial rights or to day-ahead markets.
166. In addition to removing the
requirement of full funding, IPL
proposes adding the requirement that
‘‘revenue shortfall funding shall be
shared by all load serving entities that
receive allocations of long-term
financial transmission rights unless the
transmission organization identifies a
clear cost causation relationship that
warrants other treatment and develops
an appropriate allocation methodology
through the stakeholder process and
specifies that methodology in its tariff
and contractual arrangements.’’ 75
167. PJM proposes that guideline (2)
be revised such that the ‘‘quantity
specified’’ in the guideline is modified
by ‘‘such quantity to reflect, at a
minimum, the baseload requirements of
LSEs, as determined by the respective
transmission organization/ISO
regions.’’ 76
Commission Conclusion
168. We will adopt guideline (2) with
minor modifications.77 Given that the
term full funding has become shorthand
for the financial coverage requirements
of this guideline, we add this term in
parentheses. Finally, because under
market designs approved heretofore it is
financial rights that provide revenues
explicitly, we specify that the full
funding requirement applies to financial
long-term rights.
169. Thus guideline (2) as adopted in
this Final Rule reads as follows:
The long-term firm transmission right must
provide a hedge against locational marginal
pricing congestion charges or other direct
assignment of congestion costs for the period
covered and quantity specified. Once
allocated, the financial coverage provided by
a financial long-term transmission right
should not be modified during its term (the
‘‘full funding’’ requirement) except in the
case of extraordinary circumstances or
through voluntary agreement of both the
holder of the right and the transmission
organization.
Requirement of Full Funding
170. We believe that the full funding
requirement satisfies Congress’ express
directive in section 217(b)(4) that load
serving entities with service obligations
be able to obtain ‘‘firm’’ transmission
rights or their equivalent on a long-term
basis. In our view, ‘‘firmness’’ in this
75 Comments
of IPL at 8.
Comments of PJM at 4.
77 PJM’s suggestion that the guideline incorporate
quantity restrictions on the allocation of long-term
firm transmission rights is addressed under
guideline (5).
76 Reply
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43584
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
context refers primarily to two
properties of the long-term transmission
rights: stability in the quantity of rights
that a load serving entity is allocated
over time and ‘‘price certainty’’ for the
load serving entity that seeks to hedge
congestion charges associated with a
particular generation resource or
transmission path. If the rights are
financial, which they are in almost all
organized electricity markets, the latter
property essentially requires
minimizing the uncertainty in the
ability of the rights’ holders to cover
congestion charges with the revenue
from their transmission rights over the
term of the rights. In our view, the
objective of less uncertainty in revenues
over the period of financial long-term
rights will be aided by full funding.
Hence, we find that full funding is
consistent with the objectives of section
217(b)(4).
171. Full funding may have additional
positive effects. By stabilizing the
expected congestion hedge offered by
the right, full funding should assist in
financing generation investments that
are dedicated to particular loads and
assume consistent use of particular
transmission paths over long periods,
such as base-load plants. Stabilizing the
expected value of the long-term rights
may also improve their tradability.
Further, the transmission organization
and transmission owners may have
incentives to minimize any resulting
uplift through improved transmission
system operations, planning and
investment. We recognize that there
may also be negative incentives from
full funding, depending on how any
uplift costs are allocated. For example,
a transmission owner with long-term
rights that poorly maintains its
transmission network and causes more
instances of deratings that result in
congestion revenue shortfalls could be
partially subsidized by other
transmission owners that have better
maintained systems. As we discuss
below, transmission organizations and
their stakeholders have latitude to
propose a full funding uplift allocation
to provide better transmission
maintenance incentives, if they so
choose.
172. There are also methods that
could be used to minimize exposure to
uplift caused by full funding. First, all
current organized electricity markets
that allocate financial transmission
rights bank congestion surpluses
(congestion revenues collected in excess
of payments owed to transmission right
holders) in a reserve fund over time so
as to pay transmission rights in periods
of congestion revenue shortfall. For
example, in PJM, payments to
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
transmission rights are only prorationed when the surplus fund is
exhausted. If there is surplus remaining
at the end of the year, it is distributed
to market participants. This same
principle could be applied to long-term
financial rights, except that the surplus
would be retained across multiple years.
Second, as a few commenters suggested,
a premium could be charged for fully
funded long-term rights, which the
transmission organization could
additionally apply to such a reserve
fund to minimize uplift charges or to set
up an insurance policy for the rights
holders themselves. Finally, as we
discuss elsewhere in this Final Rule,
transmission expansion provides a
hedge against congestion revenue
shortfalls.
173. A number of commenters,
including AEP and IPL, are concerned
that full funding will reduce the
transmission organization’s flexibility in
adjusting holdings of transmission
rights over time as system conditions
change and perhaps render some rights
infeasible. AEP is concerned that this
might adversely affect transmission
investment. While we appreciate these
concerns, we must note that the purpose
of this Final Rule is to provide more
assurance regarding congestion charge
hedges over a longer time frame than is
available now. This necessarily implies
a decreased ability to adjust holdings of
transmission rights over time. This Final
Rule allows substantial latitude to
transmission organizations regarding
such things as setting terms and renewal
rights for long-term firm transmission
rights, placing limits on the amount of
capacity made available to those rights,
and allowing full funding to be relaxed
under extraordinary circumstances. We
believe this strikes an appropriate
balance between assuring long term
congestion charge hedges and reliable
operation of the grid. We encourage
transmission organizations and
stakeholders to consider other measures
that allow the transmission organization
to deal with revenue insufficiencies
over time.
174. Several commenters argue that
the Commission should not establish
financial rights that offer some load
serving entities a ‘‘perfect hedge’’
financially that is superior to the
physical rights that they held prior to
the formation of the organized market.
We agree. We do not envision full
funding as a perfect hedge. Since the
transmission organization is revenue
neutral, costs associated with the full
funding guarantee must be allocated on
some basis among market participants.
Our guidelines do not establish a subset
of load serving entities that would be
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
exempt from such costs, although we
discuss how the costs should be
distributed in the paragraphs that
follow.
Full Funding Cost Allocation
175. In general, we will allow
transmission organizations the
discretion to propose a method for
allocating any uplift charges that result
from fully funding long-term firm
transmission rights. However, certain
options proposed by commenters could
result in unreasonable outcomes. We
discuss some of these below.
176. One approach proposed by
commenters would be to charge uplift
necessary to support full funding
directly to the load serving entities that
hold the long-term firm transmission
rights that have been made infeasible.
Such a rule would largely undercut the
relative congestion price certainty
provided by full funding and would
hence probably not be a reasonable
outcome.
177. A second related approach
would be to charge uplift to support full
funding to a subset or the full set of load
serving entities that hold long-term firm
transmission rights. In this case, the
degree to which the full funding
requirement was adversely impacted
would depend on the size of the set. In
some regions, a small group of load
serving entities may opt for long-term
rights, in which case this rule could
have almost the same impact as
assignment of uplift directly to the
holders of the rights made infeasible. On
the other hand, if most load serving
entities in a region opted for long-term
rights (up to their eligibility), then the
distribution of uplift charges over the
set of rights holders would have a lesser
impact and could be reasonable from all
parties’ perspective. Further, if
transmission organizations decide to
apply full funding also to short-term
transmission rights, as discussed below,
another potentially reasonable approach
would be to distribute uplift charges
over holders of both short- and longterm rights.
178. Both the NOPR and many of the
comments on the NOPR discussed the
possible assignment of uplift necessary
to support full funding to transmission
owners. Commenters discussed several
variants, including the current NYISO
rules that assign all or most of such
uplift to support full funding of annual
FTRs to transmission owners, and other
more targeted proposals, such as the
assignment of uplift costs in relation to
performance of transmission
maintenance. The Commission will
allow regional discretion on these
options and will examine the
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
reasonableness of such proposals on a
case-by-case basis.
179. Some commenters argue that full
funding of long-term rights would cause
cost-shifting that would be unduly
discriminatory and preferential with
respect to short-term rights holders. We
find that section 217(b)(4) can be
reasonably interpreted to establish a due
preference for load serving entities that
seek to obtain long-term firm
transmission rights. We have explained
our interpretation of the relationship of
firmness and full funding. However, as
noted above, we encourage transmission
organizations to evaluate whether the
requirement to fully fund long-term
rights, should be paired with full
funding of short-term rights. Currently,
most transmission organizations proration payments to short-term FTRs in
the event of a revenue shortfall. When
fully funded long-term firm
transmission rights become available,
entities that would prefer to hold shortterm rights may have an incentive to
seek longer-term rights if the former are
not fully funded and depending also on
any other rules that affect the properties
of transmission rights. Providing the
same funding guarantee to all financial
transmission rights and focusing on
mechanisms to minimize the potential
for uplift, as discussed above, could
help load serving entities choose rights
with term lengths that best suit their
needs.
Definition of Extraordinary
Circumstances
180. As noted above, we will adopt
the provision in guideline (2) that
allows for full funding of long-term firm
transmission rights to be suspended in
the event of extraordinary
circumstances. This exception was
intended to relieve the burden on
parties that could be unreasonably
impacted by the full funding
requirement in such situations. There
was general support for this provision,
although a number of commenters
sought further definition and
clarification of extraordinary
circumstances so that the exception
would not be used to unreasonably
narrow the application of the full
funding requirement.
181. We agree with commenters that
if the extraordinary circumstances
exception is defined too broadly, it
could be used to unreasonably diminish
the value of full funding. Accordingly,
we clarify that the definition of
extraordinary circumstances, for
purposes of this Final Rule, is limited to
force majeure events that both render
the set of outstanding long-term
transmission rights infeasible and leave
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
the transmission organization revenue
inadequate, including both revenues
from collection of congestion charges
and availability of funds from a
congestion charge surplus fund.
182. In response to APPA, we further
clarify that transmission system
contingencies that were considered in
the allocation of transmission rights
should be excluded from the definition
of extraordinary circumstances. In
general, the allocation of transmission
rights will be subject to a contingencyconstrained simultaneous feasibility test
and hence such contingencies should
not lead to revenue inadequacy if they
occur as expected in the modeling
assumptions. We recognize that the set
of contingencies modeled by the
transmission organization may change
over time and this should be taken into
account in the allocation of
transmission rights. There may be
further restrictions on the definition of
extraordinary circumstances that are
needed, and we will consider these as
they are presented in compliance
proposals.
183. TAPS argues that the conditions
for suspension of full funding or
application of alternative funding rules
should be limited to ‘‘catastrophic’’
regional problems. TAPS is concerned
that otherwise, holders of long-term
rights will be exposed to congestion
charge risk in periods when they most
need coverage. While we recognize
TAPS’ concern, there is no obvious
standard approach to this issue and so
we find it more appropriate to allow
transmission organizations and
stakeholders to develop proposals. For
example, in the event of extraordinary
circumstances there could be a dollar
amount that the transmission
organization stakeholders agree to as an
upper limit for full funding uplift before
pro-rationing of payments to
transmission rights holders begins. In
addition, the rules for pro-rationing
payments may themselves include
averaging of uplift similar to full
funding. Finally, in all likelihood,
system emergencies that are
catastrophic will lead to a suspension of
market pricing and financial settlement
rules and long-term transmission rights
would presumably fall under those
rules.
Other Issues
184. In response to BP Energy’s
concerns about market gaming
associated with fully funded
transmission rights in the event of a
transmission outage, we will not
endorse the methods being adopted by
ERCOT, but will consider any approach
that transmission organizations propose
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43585
to ensure that the full funding guarantee
is not subject to market manipulation.
Guideline (3)—Rights Made Available
by Expansions Go to Parties That Pay for
the Upgrade
185. As proposed in the NOPR,
guideline (3) stated that long-term firm
transmission rights made feasible by
transmission upgrades or expansions
must be available upon request to any
party that pays for such upgrades or
expansions in accordance with the
transmission organization’s prevailing
cost allocation methods for upgrades or
expansions. The term of the rights
should be equal to the life of the facility
(or facilities) or a lesser term requested
by the party paying for the upgrade or
expansion. We also sought comment on
the appropriate rules in the event that
an entity that funds a capacity
expansion seeks rights on existing
transmission capacity to support a
request for long-term rights.
Comments
186. Guideline (3) was generally
supported by commenters, a number of
whom noted that it roughly paralleled
the existing rules for awards of
transmission rights to parties that fund
transmission upgrades and expansions.
Of the existing transmission
organizations, ISO–NE and PJM already
provide long-term incremental rights for
transmission upgrades, although their
rules for assignment of such rights
differ. New York ISO and Midwest ISO
are developing such rules.
187. ISO–NE states that it awards
auction revenue rights for transmission
upgrades consistent with the intent of
guideline (3) and that their term
continues as long as the costs of the
upgrades are supported or for the life of
the upgrade, if shorter. PJM states that
guideline (3) is generally consistent
with its current rules, but notes that its
rules for term lengths are slightly
different from the proposed guideline,
as discussed below.
188. New York ISO states that its tariff
provides for the creation of incremental
Transmission Congestion Contracts
(TCCs) for upgrades. However, LIPA
argues that NYISO has not finalized its
process for awarding expansion rights,
and that this has a negative impact on
parties that construct additional
transmission capacity.
189. As discussed above, Cinergy
takes issues with what it argues is the
Commission’s overly broad reading of
section 217(b)(4) of the FPA. Cinergy
urges the Commission to ‘‘provide a
clear distinction between rights
associated with transmission expansion
and those for other long-term uses’’ and
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43586
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
adopt a shorter term for long-term firm
transmission rights over existing
capacity, to provide a trial period to
assess impacts on the system.78
Similarly, NSTAR argues that only
customers who finance transmission
capacity expansion are entitled to longterm rights.
190. Conversely, New England Public
Systems and NRECA seek clarification
that load serving entities that are not
directly paying for upgrades or
expansion are not prevented from
obtaining long-term rights.
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Scope of Guideline 3
191. Many commenters ask that the
scope of guideline (3) be clarified. In
particular, commenters sought
clarification of the types of transmission
expansions the guideline was
describing.
192. IPL and Midwest ISO argue that
the long-term rights awarded for
expansions should be subject to the
same rules that will apply to other longterm rights. IPL proposes that guideline
(3) be modified to emphasize that rights
are awarded subject to the transmission
organization’s annual allocation
metholodogies. Midwest ISO argues that
rights for expansions should have no
more or less certainty in terms of MW
quantity or funding than any other longterm financial instrument.
193. Cinergy requests that guideline
(3) make clear that entities who fund
upgrades or expansions should ‘‘enjoy
the same rights to compensation and the
same access to existing transmission
capacity whether or not they are LSEs.’’
Cinergy also asks for clarification that
long-term rights for expansion are to be
made available only to entities that
make an upgrade for the purposes of
transmission service from generation to
load, and that such rights should not be
available for upgrades that are
undertaken through the transmission
organization planning process for pool
facilities.
194. Similarly, SDG&E requests that
the Commission clarify that the
recipients of long-term rights are those
that actually pay the revenue
requirements associated with the
expansion or upgrade. In particular,
SDG&E is concerned that third-party
transmission sponsors that seek revenue
recovery through rate base are not
awarded transmission rights. E.ON
argues that load serving entities that
request transmission upgrades but do
not fund such upgrades nor purchase a
78 Comments of Cinergy at 8. Cinergy states that
this approach would involve adopting guidelines
(1), (6) and (8) without modification, and guidelines
(3) and (4) with modifications (discussed below).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
long-term transmission contract should
not be eligible for long-term rights.
195. Several commenters, including
Industrial Consumers and TANC, seek
clarification that long-term rights will
not be awarded to transmission projects
that are subsequently rolled into rates.
196. A number of commenters raised
questions about the relationship of
guideline (3) and cost allocation
methods for transmission upgrades and
expansion. National Grid requests
confirmation that guideline (3) does not
require regions to revise their prevailing
cost allocation methods. National Grid
infers that guideline (3) refers to a
model of participant funding and
requests clarification that regions that
have not adopted participant funding do
not need to revise their methods. PJM
also argues that the Commission should
not disturb existing cost allocation
methodologies by addressing the issue
of participant funding versus
socialization of costs.
197. TAPS requests that the
Commission make clear that guideline
(3) does not tie the availability of longterm rights from new transmission
capacity to participant funding. TAPS
asks that at a minimum, the guideline
should make clear that where
transmission organizations have moved
to other methods of funding upgrades,
long-term rights should be available
from that capacity.
198. AEP cautions that because
transmission upgrades are lumpy in
nature, it is often difficult to assign
properly the costs of transmission
additions to those parties that receive
the benefits. AEP notes that due to the
difficulties in assigning such costs, there
may be free-riders. Consequently, the
transmission organization should
conduct a regional planning process that
identifies the upgrades and expansions
that provide the greatest benefit to the
region and funds this capacity through
regional rate design.
Term of Rights for Upgrades and
Expansion
199. Commenters differed over
guideline (3)’s provision that long-term
firm transmission rights allocated to the
builders of new transmission facilities
should be for the life of the facility.
AF&PA and NRECA supported the
proposal. However, other commenters
argued for a fixed term of a long period
rather than life of facility, which could
be difficult to define. PJM currently
offers rights for a maximum of 30 years
and argues that this places a realistic
term on the life of the facility and
balances the rights of the party paying
for the upgrade with market efficiency.
Midwest ISO and Xcel similarly argue
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
that awards should be of fixed terms
and not facility life. PJM Public Power
Coalition supports the PJM term of 30
years, but urges that holders of such
rights should be given the opportunity
to refuse the rights on an annual basis.
CAISO notes that once a transmission
project is built and energized, the
responsibility for its maintenance may
be transferred to a transmission owner
separate from the merchant sponsor.
Hence, CAISO recommends that the
Commission consider allowing
transmission organizations to develop
standardized terms of long-term
transmission rights to be allocated to
merchant transmission projects, rather
than require allocation for the life of the
facility.
200. Several commenters, including
EEI, National Grid and PG&E, suggest
that the transmission planning horizon
presented a natural limit to at least the
initial term of rights awarded for new
facilities. National Grid argues that
awards of rights for the life of facility
are impractical because transmission
plans currently are only 5–10 years in
length and hence any awards beyond
the planning horizon are ‘‘speculative.’’
Instead, rights should be granted for the
duration of the planning horizon and as
they expire, new rights can be
reconfigured and allocated based on the
capacity conditions and relative cost
contributions prevailing at the time.
Similarly, EEI and PG&E argue that
based on the planning horizon, the
terms of awarded rights should be the
shorter of the expected feasibility of the
transmission rights or the expected
lifetime of the new facility.
201. In reply comments, APPA,
NRECA and TAPS oppose arguments to
shorten the term of rights awarded for
expansion to the term of the planning
horizon of the organized market. APPA
notes that planning horizons could be
much shorter than the life of the
transmission facility for which the longterm rights holder has paid or the
duration of a long-term power supply
arrangement.
202. Cinergy argues that section
217(b)(4) does not specify awards of
rights for the life of new transmission
facilities and suggests instead that longterm rights should be awarded for the
repayment period of the initial
investment. At the end of this period,
according to Cinergy, the investor will
have recovered its investment and the
transmission expansion will be rolled
into the transmission charges paid by
transmission users. Cinergy also
suggests retiring the long-term rights on
a schedule that reflects the repayment of
the invested capital.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
Incremental Upgrades and Use of
Existing Capacity
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
203. In response to our question in the
NOPR regarding whether rights for
upgrades would require rights to the
existing transmission system to make a
long-term firm transmission right
feasible and whether specific rules were
necessary to accommodate such needs,
a number of commenters argued that the
Commission misunderstood the
procedures for awarding incremental
rights for expansion. For example,
NYISO notes that any awards for new
transmission facilities are evaluated in
terms of their incremental transmission
capacity, under which existing rights
will be simultaneously feasible with the
new rights. NYISO urges that the Final
Rule clarify that new firm transmission
rights can be awarded for increasing
transfer capacity that is feasible and that
does not render existing rights
infeasible. Similarly, Ameren and
Cinergy argue that for transmission
expansion, the default rule should be
that the entity that pays for the
expansion should be entitled only to
incremental rights. Such entities could
obtain rights to existing capacity
through subsequent reconfiguration
auctions.
204. Reliant states that entities that
fund expansions should unambiguously
receive the full allocation of rights
associated with the expansion and the
same non-discriminatory access to
obtain rights to existing capacity as all
other market participants. Further,
Reliant states that to the extent an
expansion needs access to the existing
capacity, each region should have the
flexibility to develop procedures to
account for how existing capacity can be
utilized to facilitate new investment.
205. Some commenters have other
questions about the relationship of
rights awarded for expansions and those
assigned on existing transmission
capacity. CPUC questions whether
awards for expansions might interfere
adversely with rights to existing
capacity awarded based on service
obligations. PG&E and SoCal Edison
request that the Commission clarify that
under guideline (3), parties that fund
transmission upgrades or expansions do
not obtain priority to existing
transmission capacity. Further, the final
rule should clarify the method for
determining the amount of rights made
feasible by the upgrade.
Other Issues
206. CAISO requests that the
Commission make clear within this
rulemaking that transmission
organizations have the responsibility
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
and authority for determining, based on
their own engineering studies, the
incremental transfer capacity added to
the grid by a merchant transmission
project.
207. OMS reads guideline (3) as
applying to cases where a load serving
entity requests a new or changed
designated network resource and is
required by the ISO to make
transmission upgrades. The OMS notes,
referring to Midwest ISO, that such
upgrades are based on zonal
deliverability and not on the ability to
grant transmission rights from the
resource to load. OMS argues that if the
generator is located distantly from load,
and the potential transmission rights for
the required upgrade are valuable, then
the entity eligible for those transmission
rights may nominate them in early tiers
of the nomination and thus take up
transmission capability that others may
need. That is, the process of awarding
transmission rights for capacity
deliverability upgrades may create a
result inconsistent with the goal of
allocating transmission rights on a
priority basis to parties that are seeking
to serve load. TAPS similarly argues
that the Commission must recognize
that transmission planning based on
point-to-point transmission rights is ‘‘at
odds’’ with the increasing reliance on
the aggregate deliverability standard for
network resource designation in
Midwest ISO. In reply comments,
Midwest ISO argues that deliverability
upgrades are related to the ability to
meet supply adequacy requirements and
not to guarantee the ability to receive
FTRs from point to point.
208. Midwest ISO argues that care
must be taken such that parties that
fund upgrades are not given the
opportunity to seek awards of rights in
excess of the actual change in
transmission capability.
209. APPA argues that load serving
entities that funded transmission
upgrades should be given the
opportunity to own the facilities (in
addition to collecting transmission
rights). CMUA also supports joint
ownership, but notes that in California,
such ownership may require long-term
rights of different kinds over the same
facility.
Commission Conclusion
210. We will modify guideline (3) in
the Final Rule to remove the proposed
requirement that transmission rights be
granted for the life of a new
transmission facility (the last sentence
of the proposed guideline). The revised
guideline will now read:
Long-term firm transmission rights made
feasible by transmission upgrades or
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43587
expansions must be available upon request to
any party that pays for such upgrades or
expansions in accordance with the
transmission organization’s prevailing cost
allocation methods for upgrades or
expansions.
Scope of Guideline (3)
211. Our intention in guideline (3)
was to address transmission rights
awarded to entities that fund
transmission upgrades and expansions
through direct cost assignment. Our
subsequent discussion in this section
applies only to such upgrades or
expansions. All transmission
organizations now allow transmission
customers to fund capacity expansions
and receive the transmission rights that
are made possible by those expansions,
although some of these transmission
organizations have yet to develop exact
term lengths and rules for awarding
such rights. Guideline (3) does not
address the award of transmission rights
made possible by transmission upgrades
that are rolled into transmission rates.
When such transmission upgrades come
into service, the transmission rights that
result from such investments will be
made available as rights from ‘‘existing
capacity’’ and are thus addressed in
guideline (4). Prevailing cost allocation
rules will apply.
Term of Rights for Upgrades and
Expansion
212. As noted, we will modify
guideline (3) by removing the last
sentence, which requires that the term
of a long-term transmission right
awarded for an upgrade or expansion is
equal to life of facility. Based on the
comments of PJM and other parties on
the difficulty of defining life of facility,
we will let transmission organizations
and stakeholders determine the
appropriate terms. However, we
encourage transmission organizations to
harmonize the terms for long-term rights
to existing transmission capacity and
new transmission capacity as much as
possible.
213. Some commenters, such as
National Grid, PG&E and EEI, argue that
the term of rights to new transmission
capacity should be shortened from the
terms offered currently (e.g., PJM
currently offers 30 year fixed terms)
because transmission planning horizons
are only 5–10 years. We believe that this
change would unnecessarily introduce
uncertainty into the development of
merchant funded transmission facilities
and, in most cases, it would not allow
the funding party to receive the full
benefits of its investment. Since the
rights awarded for expansion are
incremental rights, there is less
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43588
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
possibility that they will be made
infeasible by changes in the allocated
set of rights to the remainder of the grid.
214. In response to LIPA’s concern
that New York ISO has not finished its
rules for awards of long-term rights for
transmission expansion, this guideline
will require that transmission
organizations develop and file tariff
sheets and rate schedules for long-term
rights for the types of expansions
discussed in this section by the time
that they award long-term rights for
existing capacity.
Incremental Upgrades and Use of
Existing Capacity
215. We clarify that under guideline
(3), parties that fund transmission
upgrades and expansions will be
eligible for incremental transmission
rights and not entitled to obtain
transmission rights to existing
transmission capacity held by others.
However, each transmission
organization will need to establish rules
by which interconnection customers
that construct new generation facilities
and are eligible for long-term firm
transmission rights can obtain rights to
existing transmission capacity, as per
guidelines (4) and (5).
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Other Issues
216. We agree with OMS that rights
awarded for transmission expansions
made to support deliverability
requirements for generator
interconnection are not necessarily
consistent with rights to hedge
congestion charges associated with
delivering power from the generator to
load. This distinction between upgrades
to support reliability (e.g., to qualify as
a capacity resource) and those made to
support transmission usage has been
long-standing in the transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets. However, we do not believe
that the allocation of such transmission
rights to support deliverability upgrades
should interfere with the allocation of
rights to others, since the rights would
be incremental. Therefore, we will not
address the rules for awards of such
rights here.
Guideline (4)—Term of Rights Must be
Sufficient to Hedge Long-Term Power
Supply Arrangements
217. As proposed in the NOPR,
guideline (4) stated that long-term firm
transmission rights must be made
available with term lengths (and/or
rights to renewal) that are sufficient to
meet the needs of load serving entities
to hedge long-term power supply
arrangements made or planned to satisfy
a service obligation. The length of term
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
of renewals may be different from the
original term. The discussion of
guideline (4) emphasized that term
lengths and/or rights to renewal should
be sufficient to meet the needs of
transmission customers seeking to
hedge congestion charges associated
with long-term power supply
arrangements made or planned to satisfy
a service obligation.
218. The NOPR sought comment on
the appropriate lengths of terms,
whether regional flexibility in setting
term lengths is needed, or whether a
more specific set of terms (i.e.,
standardized, such as 10 years) should
be established by this rule. The NOPR
also sought comment on the
relationship between the term of the
long-term rights and the transmission
organization’s planning cycle and
whether the planning cycles should be
modified to accommodate the issuance
of long-term rights. On the issue of
rights to renewal, the NOPR allowed
that transmission organizations may
propose reasonable criteria regarding
the availability of renewal rights and the
price for renewal. Further, we proposed
that the transmission organization may
require minimum notice periods for
initiation, renewal, cancellation or
conversion that accommodate the
transmission organization’s planning
cycle or other administrative
considerations. The NOPR further
sought comments on the relationship
between rights to renew and
transmission planning.
Comments
219. Many commenters requested that
the Commission allow regional
flexibility when establishing the rules
for long-term firm transmission rights to
existing transmission capacity.79
However, as discussed below, some of
these parties made suggestions for
minimum terms and rules for renewal
rights.
220. Several of the transmission
organizations cautioned against the
Commission mandating term lengths.
Midwest ISO states that the
transmission organization must have
sufficient flexibility to define and
allocate long-term FTRs of different
terms. OMS argues that the coordination
of the term of the rights with the
planning process must be left to each
transmission organization. CAISO also
argued that many different
combinations of term lengths and
renewal rights could be implemented
79 See, e.g., Ameren, BPA, CAISO, Cinegy, EEI,
IPL, KY PSC, Medwest ISO, NARUC, NRECA,
NYISO, New York Transmision Owners, NU, OMS,
PJM, Reliant, SDG&E, SoCal Edison, Strategic, and
Wisconsin Electric.
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
that would meet the objectives of
Section 217(b)(4). Each transmission
organization should be allowed to
examine the appropriate rules with its
stakeholders.
221. In contrast, Santa Clara argues
that load serving entities should set the
terms that they need, and that
transmission organizations should be
required to accommodate those terms.
222. ISO–NE argues that guideline (4)
presents a number of concerns,
including the difficulty in analyzing the
feasibility of the rights, uncertainty over
how to evaluate load serving entities’
arrangements ‘‘planned’’ to satisfy a
service obligation, necessity for
administrative arrangements to review
long-term power supply arrangements
that qualify a load serving entity for
long-term rights and to monitor for
manipulation, and accounting for
potential terminations of and
modifications to such arrangements.
ISO–NE asks that because of the
difficulties in determining feasibility of
long-term rights, the Commission
should ‘‘avoid specifying excessive
terms lengths,’’ rather letting
transmission organizations and
stakeholders develop appropriate
proposals.
223. Reliant suggests that if the
stakeholder process is ineffective in
determining term lengths, then the
Commission may find it appropriate to
develop a more specific set of terms.
224. Cinergy argues that guideline (4)
goes beyond the intent of Section
217(b)(4), which it argues is directed
exclusively toward transmission
expansion. However, Cinergy agrees that
transmission organizations should
individually develop long-term rights.
Cinergy also objects to the notion that
the Section 217(b)(4) requires providing
load serving entities with hedges.
Comments on Specific Term Lengths
225. Some commenters propose
specific term lengths, ranging from
shorter to longer terms. Beginning with
proposals for shorter terms, Midwest
ISO asks that the definition of ‘‘longterm’’ be redefined to include terms of
one year to offer the transmission
organization maximum flexibility to
establish rights of short durations but
with renewal options that may suit
participants in retail choice states. DC
Energy proposes adding one year to the
term of FTRs each year to allow the
market to develop in an orderly and
incremental fashion. Strategic Energy
supports terms of two years as a starting
point.
226. CAISO discusses, for purposes of
illustration, the possibility of two year
rights with priority for renewal over
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
requests for new rights. SDG&E
recommends that one year CRRs are
implemented for the first year of the
CAISO MRTU project (‘‘Release 1’’),
with longer-term CRRs reserved for the
next phase of the market (‘‘Release 2’’).
227. CAISO further argues that
because transmission owners have the
ability to withdraw from the ISO with
a two-year exit notice, duration of
transmission rights longer than two
years is ‘‘potentially questionable
coverage as the CAISO will not be
capable of enforcing such instruments
upon a transmission owners’ exit.’’ 80
CAISO asks that the Commission
consider this issue. In reply comments,
SMUD notes that CAISO has signed 20
year firm transmission agreements with
WAPA on the Pacific intertie. SMUD
suggests that CAISO condition exit of a
transmission owner on honoring
existing contracts. It also notes that
since transmission organization
membership is voluntary, there is no
long-term rights construct that does not
involve the risk of exit.
228. NYISO argues that it is ‘‘quite
possible that one-year, two-year or fiveyear rights’’ will be sufficient to meet
the needs of transmission customers
with long-term power supply
arrangements. NYISO notes that it has
previously offered 2 and 5 year
Transmission Congestion Contracts, but
that market participant interest is
limited, due in part to the retail
competition in New York state. Coral
Power also supports terms in the one to
five year range. IPL supports terms of no
longer than three years, at least for an
initial period to gain market experience.
Similarly, Cinergy proposes an initial
trial period of rights with terms from 2–
5 years. Morgan Stanley proposes terms
ranging from three to five years. It
argues that terms shorter than three
years are not likely to be sufficient for
investor certainty, while terms longer
than five years will fail to create
sufficient liquidity to attract buyers and
increase the risk of revenue
insufficiency.
229. A number of commenters
suggested minimum terms. BPA
suggested a minimum term of 5 years to
support stability in transmission system
planning. Other commenters suggested a
10 year term, including AEP, APPA,
CMUA, PJM Public Power Coalition,
NCPA and TAPS. APPA suggests a
minimum term of 10 years outside of
retail access environments, and also
supports longer terms for transmission
rights to support new baseload and
renewable generation resources. PJM
Public Power Coalition also states that
80 Comments
VerDate Aug<31>2005
of CAISO at 13.
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
ideally, terms would span 20 to 30 years
or more, reflecting the terms of
financing.
230. PG&E supports fixed terms and/
or renewal rights that provide coverage
of 5 to 30 years, consistent with the term
and quantity of the service obligation.
PG&E further states that transmission
organizations should have the flexibility
to propose more granular rights to ease
administration and transfer when
appropriate as well as potentially to
increase the availability of short-term
rights during the effective term.
231. NRECA states that long-term
rights should have maximum periods
that match the term of the long-term
power supply arrangement. Central
Vermont, NYAPP, Redding, Santa Clara,
SMUD and Wisconsin Electric present
similar views.
232. A number of commenters
emphasized that the term of the longterm rights should be commensurate
with, or at least not exceed, the
transmission planning horizon.81 For
some commenters, such as Industrial
Consumers, this would be a maximum
term length with no opportunities for
renewal. For others, this would be the
basic term length with renewal rights.
Some observers, such as Industrial
Consumers, note approvingly that some
transmission organizations are
considering extending the planning
horizon from 5 years to 10 years.
National Grid requests that the
Commission clarify that the
‘‘sufficiency’’ standard under guideline
(4) ‘‘means nothing more than a term
based on rational planning studies.’’ 82
National Grid argues that terms beyond
such planning studies would make the
associated rights ‘‘purely speculative.’’
NU argues that rights with terms
extending beyond the planning horizon
would ‘‘unreasonably transfer risk of
congestion to participants who are not
in a position to control that risk.’’ 83
233. NRECA argues that the
transmission planning cycle should be
at least 10 years to provide adequate
support for infrastructure investment.
AEP and Allegheny support the
alignment of the term of long-term firm
transmission rights with the 10-year
transmission planning cycle that is
being developed by PJM. PJM Public
Power Coalition argues that
transmission planning cycles should be
modified to account for the terms of
transmission rights that extend beyond
current cycles.
81 See, e.g., Allegheny, Cinergy, DTE, EEI,
National Grid, NRECA, NU and Xcel.
82 Comments of National Grid at 21.
83 Reply Comments of NU at 4.
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43589
234. EEI supports the concepts of
long-term transmission rights with
terms commensurate with the length of
the planning horizon, but states that the
planning horizons are just one of a
number of issues that might be
considered in determining term length.
Other factors could include whether the
system is constrained, the length of time
it reasonably takes to expand the
system, existing uses of the system, and
the demand for long-term and shortterm rights on the system. Further,
stakeholders may consider the volume
of grandfathered rights and their
expiration dates, expected generation
retirements, and the nature of renewal
rights.
235. In contrast, CAISO does not see
a compelling reason for tying the terms
of transmission rights to the
transmission planning cycle. CAISO
argues that financial transmission rights
do not carry physical characteristics.
Hence, the problem of insuring their
value over the long-term is
fundamentally a cost allocation issue
and is only one of many factors to be
taken into account in assessing
particular transmission projects. CAISO
thus asks that the Commission allow
transmission organizations to consider
the issue of term length as a matter both
of market design and transmission
planning without imposing any specific
linkage between the two.
236. New England Public Systems
similarly argues that the creation of
long-term rights should not in and of
itself change the transmission
organization’s planning cycle. In its
reply comments, New England Public
Systems argues that long-term rights
should be integrated into the planning
process, becoming part of the baseline
for each planning cycle. In that sense, it
contends, the planning cycle should not
be a constraint on the term of the rights.
237. Similarly, IPL argues that
planning cycles can not be designed to
support financial transmission rights
because of the large number of variables
that determine a feasible allocation and
the likelihood of changes in those
variables over time. Hence, regardless of
whether the terms of the long-term
rights are linked to transmission
planning cycles, there will be a need to
periodically re-examine the feasibility of
particular allocations of rights and make
corresponding modifications in the
allocation if needed. IPL further argues
that this periodic evaluation and
revision of the rights would still allow
the holder an ‘‘adequate hedge.’’ IPL
supports this position by arguing that
the load serving entity is entitled only
to a reasonable hedge, not an absolute
guarantee that it will never bear
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43590
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
congestion costs. IPL proposes that
guideline (4) be revised to link term
length to the concept of a ‘‘reasonable’’
hedge and to limit the potential for
revenue shortfalls.84
238. PG&E argues that the relevant
issue in determining the length of the
term is not the planning horizon but
rather the term of the service obligation.
PG&E notes that ‘‘the Commission has
approved many contracts with terms
beyond ten years, and has never
suggested that such obligations should
be limited to the planning horizon.’’
Similarly, TAPS argues that the
transmission organization’s planning
horizon cannot be a basis for restricting
terms, including renewals, to a period
shorter than the load serving entity’s
resource commitment.
239. Finally, PG&E argues that the
effectiveness of long-term transmission
rights will be best served if the terms
have sufficient granularity, such as peak
and off-peak periods in the day, the
week, the month or season.
Renewal Rights, Minimum Notice
Periods and Termination
240. A number of commenters argue
that renewal rights can be used to
extend the period covered by long-term
transmission rights. Ameren suggests
that rather than prescribe a single term
length for all long-term rights,
transmission organizations should focus
on providing renewal rights. For
example, Ameren argues that FTRs with
annual rollover rights would be far more
flexible than long-term FTRs with set
terms. Ameren proposes that a load
serving entity with a power supply
arrangement of longer than one year be
given the option to roll over the FTR
each year subject to verification that the
power supply arrangement will be in
effect for the next year and the load
serving entity is nominating no more
than its forecast load for the subsequent
year. Ameren points out that this
approach is consistent with the auction
requirements in states with retail
choice, where load serving entities will
need access to long-term rights even
though their power supply contracts
will only be one-year in length.
241. Similarly, Cinergy argues that
one-year transmission rights with
renewal rights would ‘‘provide a
measure of long-term benefit while still
preserving the ability to modify the
underlying rights themselves on an
annual basis.’’ 85 Cinergy is also
concerned that entities with long-term
transmission rights not simply be able to
cancel the rights unilaterally. Instead,
the ‘‘rights must be relinquished in a
manner than allows the market to value
and ration them appropriately.’’ 86
242. TAPS supports Ameren’s
proposal for one-year rights with
assured rollover rights (but offers also
its own proposal for rolling 10-year
terms, discussed below). TAPS suggests
that such regional variations might be
acceptable as long as load serving
entities can achieve long-term price
stability for the full duration of their
long-term resource commitments.
Similarly, New England Public Systems
argues that the combination of term
lengths, renewal rights and cancellation
rights must be ‘‘sufficiently flexible’’ to
enable load serving entities to tailor
their long-term rights coverage to their
specific needs. It is willing to support
rights of short duration ‘‘so long as
LTTR renewal rights [are] sufficiently
robust to ensure the continuation by
[load serving entities] of needed
rights.’’ 87
243. TAPS, Industrial Consumers and
New England Public Systems support a
rolling 10-year term that affords the
holder unconditional renewal rights.
For example, in the first year, the holder
of the 10-year right would inform the
transmission organization whether it
wanted the right in year 11, in year two
whether it wanted the right in year 12,
etc. Industrial Consumers states that
there is a critical need that investors for
new base-load generation perceive that
firm transmission rights and renewal
rights are available for up to 20 years or
longer. Xcel similarly argues that at the
end of the initial term of long-term
rights, which could be up to the length
of the planning horizon, renewal would
take place on a one year basis as long
as the obligation to serve still exists.
244. Other commenters were
concerned that reliance on renewal
rights would erode the durability of
long-term rights. CMUA states that
renewal rights introduce uncertainty
over issues such as changes in rates,
changes in the simultaneous feasibility
test, and the incorporation of other
changes since the long-term right was
granted.
245. Industrial Consumers argues that
renewal rights should be limited to load
serving entities that can demonstrate
that the renewal is needed to support a
long-term power supply arrangement.
Similarly, BPA supports the principle
that renewal rights may be subject to
limitations that tie the long-term
transmission service to long-term power
supply arrangements, to ensure that
renewal rights are not over-allocated.
246. National Grid argues than any
renewal right should be ‘‘narrowly
tailored,’’ as any renewal beyond the
applicable planning horizons would be
‘‘just as speculative’’ as a long-term right
with an initial term beyond such
horizons.88 Instead, renewals would
have to be subject to evaluation and
reconfigured to reflect system
conditions through the renewal term.
247. NSTAR argues that renewal
rights for long-term rights are
discriminatory because the ‘‘guidelines
do not allow direct access load served
under short-term contracts to qualify for
long-term rights on a renewal basis,
even though the contracts under which
they are served will be extended into
the future or will be replaced by new
contracts.’’ 89 For example, under some
interpretations the guidelines could
allow a load serving entity with a 2-year
right to extend the right indefinitely
while the holder of a one-year right
would not be eligible for such renewals.
248. NYISO argues that the
Commission should allow auction-based
renewal systems, such as that offered by
NYISO. NYISO argues that renewal of
rights without market pricing would be
‘‘inimical to the design of auction-based
systems that are meant to fairly reallocate rights based on economics and
the interests of end-users.’’ 90 Moreover,
renewals without market pricing would
likely reduce the availability of
transmission rights because holders of
the rights could retain them
indefinitely. Another issue is that
through the annual auctions,
counterflow transmission rights are
purchased, making additional
transmission rights feasible. If the
counterflow rights were not renewed,
then at least some of the long-term
renewal rights would be rendered
infeasible. NYISO further argues that the
concept of a set ‘‘price’’ for renewal may
also be antithetical to the market
auction model that it employs, because
such prices may not be consistent with
the auction outcomes.
249. In contrast, TAPS argues that
renewals should be at no additional
cost. TAPS argues that firm delivery and
long-term rights are part of the ‘‘core
responsibility’’ of the transmission
provider and not an additional cost.
TAPS states that at an absolute
minimum, any renewal charges should
be fixed and fully disclosed by the
transmission organization before the
initial term begins.
86 Id.
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
89 Reply
at 35.
Comments of New England Public
Systems at 20.
of IPL at 12.
85 Comments of Cinergy at 33.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
88 Comments
87 Reply
84 Comments
Jkt 208001
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
of National Grid at 22.
Comments of NSTAR AT 9.
90 Comments of NYISO at 18.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
250. SMUD argues that rather than
renewal rights, the Commission should
allow holders of long-term rights the
ability ‘‘to apply the right of first refusal
protections accorded OATT customers
under Order No. 888.’’ 91
251. Regarding minimum notice
periods for renewal or cancellation.
APPA supports an ‘‘appropriate’’ notice
period. BPA argues that the minimum
notice period for exercising a right to
renew should be one year. Cinergy is
concerned that holders of the rights
should not be able to cancel them
‘‘unilaterally.’’ 92 Rather, the rights must
be relinquished in a manner that allows
the market to value and ration them
appropriately. Wisconsin Electric states
that any long-term protection should
terminate when a unit is taken out of
service or the agreements are
terminated, even if that is prior to the
expected life or term of the agreement.
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Other Issues
252. There was some concern among
commenters regarding the seams
implications of different term lengths
among organized markets. NRECA
expresses concern that adjoining regions
may assign different terms for long-term
rights that this will cause seams
problems. NRECA requests the
Commission require coordination
between adjoining transmission
organizations to ensure that the rights
are not ‘‘illogically matched’’ to their
supply arrangement.93
253. A number of commenters
emphasized the need for short-term
transmission rights to co-exist with
long-term rights. Allegheny stated that
the final rule should preserve the ability
of market participants to obtain
allocations of shorter-term rights,
including first priority FTR allocations
to historic resources. Cinergy is
concerned that in states with retail
choice, load serving entities would often
have to overcome state regulatory
obstacles to make long-term power
supply arrangements, needed to acquire
long-term transmission rights. This
would leave such entities limited to a
‘‘second-tier’’ allocation.
254. EEI proposes specific revisions
for guideline (4) to reflect consideration
of existing uses of the system. It suggests
that the availability of long-term rights
should be limited ‘‘to the extent
reasonable in light of the existing uses
of the system.’’ 94 In addition, it argues
91 Comments
of SMUD at 24.
of Cinergy at 34.
93 NRECA invokes the ‘‘affected systems’’
approach of the Commission’s generator
interconnection policies as the basis for this
requirement. Comments of NRECA AT 13.
94 Comments of EEI at 21.
92 Comments
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
that the term ‘‘should’’ should be
substituted for ‘‘must’’ with respect to
provision of the rights. Finally, it
suggests modifying the last sentence of
the guideline as follows (additions
underlined): ‘‘The length and conditions
under which the term of renewals is
offered may be different than the
original term.’’ APPA and NRECA
oppose EEI’s proposed modifications to
guideline (4). Both commenters are
concerned with the substitution of the
term ‘‘should’’ for ‘‘must’’, which they
argue is intended to weaken the
requirement.
Commission Conclusion
255. We will adopt guideline (4) with
a modification to indicate a 10-year
minimum term that transmission
organizations must be able to offer.
Transmission organizations and
stakeholders will have substantial
latitude to determine how to achieve
long-term coverage through
combinations of transmission rights of
specific terms and renewal rights along
with transmission planning and
expansion procedures that support longterm rights.
256. The revised guideline (4) reads as
follows:
Long-term firm transmission rights must be
made available with term lengths (and/or
rights to renewal) that are sufficient to meet
the needs of load serving entities to hedge
long-term power supply arrangements made
or planned to satisfy a service obligation. The
length of term of renewals may be different
from the original term. Transmission
organizations may propose rules specifying
the length of terms and use of renewal rights
to provide long-term coverage, but must be
able to offer firm coverage for at least a 10year period.
Term Lengths for Rights to Existing
Capacity
257. We agree with those commenters,
including most transmission
organizations, who state that this
guideline should not mandate a
standard term length for long-term firm
transmission rights. Given that there is
little experience with long-term
transmission rights in organized
electricity markets, and that different
regions may find that different
combinations of terms lengths and/or
renewal rights best fit their stakeholder
interests and pre-existing rules for
transmission rights, we will allow
regional flexibility in defining the terms
of long-term transmission rights that are
offered. However, section 217(b)(4) of
the FPA makes clear that long-term
transmission rights should be made
available to allow load serving entities
to hedge congestion charges associated
with deliveries from long-term power
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43591
supply arrangements. Hence, term
lengths must be sufficient to achieve
that objective, either alone or in concert
with renewal rights.
258. While we allow regional
flexibility in defining the terms of longterm firm transmission rights, we will
require that transmission organizations
make available transmission rights and
renewal rights that provide coverage for
a period of at least 10-years. This will
ensure that transmission rights are
offered that meet the reasonable needs
of load serving entities to obtain
transmission service for long-term
power supply arrangements used to
meet service obligations while allowing
transmission organizations and their
stakeholders flexibility in designing
rights that suit regional needs.
Transmission organizations can offer
this 10-year coverage through any mix
of term lengths and renewals that
stakeholders agree to, as long as the
coverage is ‘‘firm’’, meaning that the
quantity of the rights allocated is fixed
over the 10 year period and that the
rights are fully funded. Renewal rights
may be subject to provisions, such as
adequate notice, that address the
transmission organization’s planning
needs and adequate hedging of the load
serving entity’s long-term power supply
arrangements.
259. A number of commenters urged
that the term of rights remain relatively
short, for example, two to three years,
for at least an interim phase. Again, our
requirement for a minimum 10-year
coverage does not necessarily require
10-year transmission rights if no load
serving entity requests such rights.
Other commenters argued that the rights
should be of sufficient length, such as
a minimum of 5 years, to assist in
transmission planning. The 10-year
coverage period that we require here
will assist such planning, but we leave
it up to transmission organizations and
stakeholders to determine how best to
harmonize the long-term firm
transmission rights and transmission
planning cycles.
260. Further, as we note above with
regard to the proposed definition of
long-term power supply arrangements,
APPA, PJM and TAPS generally argue
that long-term power supply
arrangements should be considered
those with a minimum term of at least
10 years. This Final Rule focuses
primarily on providing long-term firm
transmission rights to cover power
supply arrangements with those lengths
of terms. Nonetheless, in different
transmission organizations, the
accommodation of other lengths of
power supply arrangements might be
considered important. Here, however,
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43592
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
our focus is providing load serving
entities with long-term power supply
arrangements to meet their service
obligations with the opportunity to
obtain long-term firm transmission
rights that will support the financing
and construction of new infrastructure.
Therefore, we find that setting a 10-year
minimum term as a benchmark is
appropriate, while also leaving the
transmission organizations with
sufficient flexibility to offer terms of
other lengths.
261. We emphasize that the 10-year
minimum term in this guideline is a
benchmark. The fundamental
requirement of this guideline is that
transmission organizations offer rights
with terms that are sufficient to hedge
long-term power supply arrangements.
In regions where such rights are
typically longer than this benchmark,
transmission organizations may need to
offer longer terms and/or renewal rights
beyond the initial term. Hence, we
expect that most transmission
organizations will develop rules to
either begin new 10-year coverage terms
at the end of each 10-year period or to
provide renewals on a rolling basis to
support long-term power supply
arrangements. We understand from the
comments that because of the likelihood
that transmission system changes will
take place over the 10-year period,
stakeholders may have to agree to some
reasonable process for modifications of
holdings of transmission rights in
between allocation periods. We will
consider proposals that address such
issues in the individual transmission
organization compliance filings.
262. PG&E urged sufficient granularity
in the terms of long-term rights, such as
monthly rights, daily peak and off-peak
rights, etc. We agree that more
granularity assists in creating
transmission rights terms that can better
fit actual transmission usage patterns,
and thus improves market efficiency.
Stakeholders and transmission
organizations must determine how
much granularity is desirable at the
introduction of long-term rights;
increased granularity can be introduced
over time.
263. In answer to NYISO’s concern
that entities in its service territory may
not desire long-term rights, we reiterate
that such rights must be offered and
available to load serving entities. As we
discuss above, EPAct 2005 mandates
that such rights be available.
264. While we recognize CAISO’s
concern that load serving entities
awarded long-term rights could
withdraw from the ISO’s market before
the termination of the right, we do not
see this as a limitation on granting rights
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
with terms greater than the notice
period for withdrawal. A transmission
organization may establish rules for
disposition and possible termination of
allocated rights in the event of a
withdrawal.
Other Issues With Renewal Rights,
Minimum Notice Periods and
Termination
265. Currently, load serving entities in
most organized electricity markets are
generally eligible to nominate financial
transmission rights or auction revenue
rights up to their peak load if they pay
transmission access charges. The
eligibility to nominate rights (or to
renew a load serving entity’s rights) is
currently long-term; it is available each
year to entities that serve load and pay
the access charges, but is subject to the
simultaneous feasibility test for
nominations or the results of an auction.
These latter requirements help ensure
revenue adequacy but introduce some
uncertainty into the actual year-to-year
awards of transmission rights that this
rule seeks to stabilize for some
percentage of eligible rights. Also, as
discussed in guideline (2), there may
not be full funding of the annual rights,
which adds further uncertainty as to
their value.
266. Some commenters suggest
additional restrictions or eligibility
requirements on renewal rights. Under
guideline (2), we discuss that full
funding of the rights may require, for
example, a premium payment. However,
to renew the rights for new terms, there
is not an obvious need for new
conditions. Given the current rules for
short-term rights, there should be little
to change in the renewal process when
long-term rights are offered as long as
the transmission system is being
planned and upgraded to accommodate
the rights. As suggested by APPA, to
renew allocated long-term rights, load
serving entities should be required to
commit to paying the transmission
access charges for the period of the
allocated right, whether an auction
revenue right or a financial transmission
right.
267. In response to NSTAR’s concern
that renewal rights for long-term firm
transmission rights are discriminatory
with respect to short-term rights, as we
note above, short-term transmission
rights are renewable each year for an
annual term.
268. We agree with commenters that
a minimum notice period should be
required for renewing a long-term right.
In general, the longer the term of the
right, the longer should be the minimum
notice period. We will allow
transmission organizations and
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
stakeholders to determine the specific
notice periods they will propose to
apply, however.
Other Issues
269. As noted above, several
commenters stated in response to the
proposed definition of long-term power
supply arrangements that the
Commission should require that such
arrangements have certain specific
characteristics, including specific
designation of generating resources. The
Commission will decline to adopt
specific criteria for long-term power
supply arrangements. First, as discussed
in more detail below, we are removing
from guideline (5) the requirement that
a load serving entity must hold ‘‘longterm power supply arrangements’’ to
receive an allocation priority, which
should alleviate concerns regarding the
difficulties associated with the
validation of such arrangements by
transmission organizations. Moreover,
the comments suggest that long-term
power supply arrangements may have
different characteristics in different
regions based on the prevailing
practices of load serving entities in
those areas. Accordingly, to the extent
transmission organizations and their
stakeholders believe that specification
of criteria for long-term power supply
arrangements remains necessary to
comply with the Final Rule, we will
allow the regions the flexibility to
develop such specifications and propose
them in compliance filings to this rule.
270. In response to NRECA’s concern
with seams issues, we discuss these
issues above with regard to regional
flexibility.
271. Several commenters seek to
revise guideline (4) to include
restrictions on the quantity of long-term
rights that can be obtained. We discuss
such restrictions under guideline (5).
272. With regard to EEI’s proposed
modifications of guideline (4), we agree
with APPA and NRECA that the
substitution of the word ‘‘should’’ for
the word ‘‘must’’ in the first sentence of
the guideline would weaken the
requirement. Hence, we will not adopt
that modification.
Guideline (5)—Load Serving Entities
with Long-Term Power Supply
Arrangements Have Priority to the
Existing System
273. As proposed in the NOPR,
guideline (5) stated that load serving
entities with long-term power supply
arrangements to meet a service
obligation must have priority to existing
transmission capacity that supports
long-term firm transmission rights
requested to hedge such arrangements.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
In the NOPR, the Commission noted
that, while section 217 does not require
that long-term firm transmission rights
be made available only to load serving
entities with service obligations, the
Commission interprets that section to
require that load serving entities with
long-term power supply arrangements to
satisfy a service obligation be given a
preference in securing long-term firm
transmission rights. Therefore, the
NOPR proposed that when rights
requested by eligible parties with
priority (or parties without priority that
are being accommodated) are not
simultaneously feasible given existing
transmission capacity, the transmission
organization may adopt methods to
allocate the requested rights to the
parties prior to granting such rights. The
NOPR asked for comments on such
methods, and on whether section 1233
of EPAct 2005 and new section 217(b)(4)
of the FPA support placing reasonable
limits on the award of long-term rights.
Section 217(b)(4) states that the
Commission must exercise its authority
to meet the ‘‘reasonable needs’’ of load
serving entities to satisfy their service
obligations.
274. Also, the NOPR noted that, in
making available long-term firm
transmission rights, the transmission
organization may have to incorporate
estimates of load growth into the award
of such rights. This raises the concern
that if the load growth assumptions are
overstated some load serving entities
could be awarded more long-term firm
transmission rights than needed, and
the associated transmission capacity
would not be available for allocation of
transmission rights to others. The NOPR
asked for comment on this issue and
any rules or other safeguards that
address it.
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Comments
General Arguments For and Against the
Proposed Priority
275. A number of commenters
support the proposal to give priority to
load serving entities with long-term
power supply arrangements to meet a
service obligation.95 For example, APPA
states that load serving entities that are
willing to make a long-term
commitment to pay their allocated share
of the RTO’s fixed transmission system
costs (including the costs of
transmission upgrades allocated to
customers under that RTO’s
Commission-approved transmission cost
allocation mechanism) should have a
priority claim on the transmission
95 See, e.g., SoCal Edison, Minnesota Power,
CMUA, FirstEnergy, APPA, Central Vermont,
Redding and SMUD.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
facilities for which they are obligated to
pay. FirstEnergy argues that the
Commission’s guidelines should grant
preferential access to load serving
entities with long-term power supply
arrangements in order to promote
development of generation and
transmission infrastructure, and to
dampen price volatility.
276. However, many commenters
oppose the priority granted in proposed
guideline (5),96 with some claiming that
the proposed priority would be unduly
discriminatory.97
277. Cinergy states that FPA section
217 does not require the Commission to
grant preferential rights to load serving
entities, and SDG&E states that there is
absolutely no statutory support for the
‘‘preference’’ or ‘‘priority’’ language of
guideline (5). According to SDG&E, a
much more faithful and economically
sound reading of the ‘‘meets the
reasonable needs’’ language of the
EPAct 2005 is that long-term purchasers
of power should be accommodated by
the new guidelines by providing
opportunities for them to secure longterm firm transmission rights, but they
should not be able to acquire such rights
at the expense of holders of power
supply arrangements of a shorter
duration. Morgan Stanley asserts that
the Commission has a fundamental duty
to prevent unduly discriminatory
practices in transmission access, and
allowing for a preference-based
allocation approach as part of the Final
Rule would run counter to such a duty.
Moreover, NYISO states that
interpreting section 217 to grant
preferences to certain classes of load
serving entities would contradict
section 206 of the Federal Power Act, as
well as Commission precedent and
policy against undue discrimination and
preferences in a competitive
marketplace.
278. Allegheny recommends that,
consistent with the process currently
used in PJM, firm transmission rights
should be allocated based on load and
be available to all load serving entities
serving that load. It believes that no
preference should be given in the firm
transmission right allocation process to
load serving entities with longer-term
power supply contracts to serve the
same load or to load serving entities that
were serving load first. BP Energy states
that, as currently written, guideline (5)
might be interpreted to permit a load
serving entity to displace an existing
96 See, e.g., Cinergy, Allegheny, Reliant, CAISO
and NSTAR.
97 See, e.g., AF&PA, Xcel, Allegheny, EEI,
NARUC, Morgan Stanley, BP Energy, Strategic
Energy, ISO–NE, NYISO, EPSA, SDG&E, Midwest
ISO, NYDPS and Constellation.
PO 00000
Frm 00031
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43593
holder simply because the existing
holder’s power supply arrangements last
for a shorter period of time.
279. Reliant states that, among the
unintended consequences of the
Commission’s proposal are that such a
preference: (1) Encourages load serving
entities to enter into sham long-term
agreements and other gaming, (2)
distorts the competitive playing field in
a manner that undermines and
complicates progressive retail choice
models, (3) forces load serving entities
to hold long-term rights to avoid being
shortchanged in the short-term
allocation processes, and (4) discourages
independent generation investment.
280. NSTAR states that the
deficiencies of the proposed rule can be
corrected by following the statutory
language. According to NSTAR, this
would be accomplished by redefining
‘‘long-term power supply arrangements’’
as contained in proposed section
41.1(a)(5) by deleting ‘‘or’’ and by
adding at the end of that provision the
following phrase: ‘‘or other
arrangements for the purpose of meeting
a service obligation on a long-term
basis.’’
281. With regard to the argument that
a load serving entity with a long-term
commitment to pay its allocated share of
the RTO’s fixed transmission costs is
deserving of priority access to long-term
firm transmission rights, BP Energy
claims that the argument is flawed
because all electric consumers end up
paying their allocated share, whether
they receive service underlain by longterm or shorter-term supply
arrangements. Also, National Grid
argues that establishing priorities to any
new long-term transmission rights based
on the length of terms of supply
transactions makes little economic or
operational sense. From the standpoint
of fundamental fairness, National Grid
believes that the allocation of
transmission rights should be based on
the relative contributions of the
customers to the costs of the
transmission system at the time the
rights are made available. Coral Power
believes that creating a perpetual
preference for remaining capacity based
on the theory that customers have paid
for some type of service in the past is
unreasonable.
282. Cinergy believes that if the
Commission permits load serving
entities to secure long-term transmission
rights to existing transmission capacity
on the basis of existing long-term
contracts, then it will not only separate
load serving entities as a favored class
above other transmission customers, it
will also create a favored class among
load serving entities themselves.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43594
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
283. Several commenters, however,
express the view that there is nothing
inherently unduly discriminatory about
the priority set forth in proposed
guideline (5).98 For example, NRECA
states that it is not discriminatory to
grant a higher priority to longer-term
transmission service; Order No. 888 has
done that for years. In any event,
NRECA argues that new section
217(b)(4) of the FPA requires that the
Commission regulate under the FPA in
a manner that enables load serving
entities to obtain long-term transmission
rights for their long-term power supply
arrangements; so the priority for longterm power-supply arrangements is
built into the statute, and there is no
undue discrimination, as section 217(k)
makes clear.
284. APPA states that assuming that a
situation were to arise in which the RTO
had insufficient rights available to grant
both full long-term firm transmission
right and firm transmission right
allotments, APPA does not believe that
it would constitute an ‘‘undue
preference’’ to fulfill the needs of longterm firm transmission right holders
first. New England Public Systems states
that what is unduly discriminatory is
the status quo, in which current market
rules provide those who enter into
short-term transactions the tools with
which to hedge their risks but deprives
load serving entities with longer-term
power supply arrangements of the tools
they need to hedge the risks they face.
According to New England Public
Systems, rectifying this situation cures
undue discrimination; it does not create
it.
Limits on Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights
285. A number of commenters that
either support, or do not oppose, the
priority for load serving entities as
proposed in guideline (5), state that it
may be reasonable to place limits on the
amount of capacity that can be allocated
as long-term firm transmission rights.99
However, New England Public Systems
submits that the specific nature and
terms of any such mechanisms are best
left to negotiation among the affected
stakeholders prior to the transmission
organizations’ compliance filings.
286. TAPS states that ‘‘reasonable
needs’’ of load serving entities in
organized markets must at least include
the long-term firm transmission rights
needed to support investment in
baseload and renewable resources.
98 See,
e.g., NRECA, TAPS, APPA, SMUD,
Redding, TANC and New England Public Systems.
99 See, e.g., New England Public Systems, AEP,
PJM, BPA, PJM Public Power Coalition and TAPS.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
While TAPS believes that long-term
firm transmission right coverage for
peaking resources is not necessary, it
states that intermediate resources are a
closer question. PJM argues that at some
baseline level of usage of the
transmission system it is reasonable to
expect long-term transmission rights to
be fully funded (absent significant
transmission system outages), as the
transmission system should be designed
and constructed to meet the baseline
requirements of all of its users.
287. E.ON believes that priority firm
transmission rights that would
otherwise fail the simultaneous
feasibility analysis should be allocated
on an equitably reduced basis to all
qualified load serving entities. However,
BPA states that, for a new transmission
organization forming in the Pacific
Northwest’s unique hydro-based system,
it supports granting long-term
transmission rights to all existing rights
holders, even if those rights are not
simultaneously feasible under the most
conservative assumptions possible.
288. Several commenters, including
some that do not support the priority of
guideline (5), state that, if the priority is
adopted, limits should be placed on the
amount of transmission capacity
allocated to long-term firm transmission
rights in order to protect those entities
that rely on short-term rights.100 For
example, DTE states that it expects the
introduction of long-term firm
transmission rights to reduce the
availability of short-term firm
transmission rights, and care should be
taken to ensure that current users of
short-term firm transmission rights are
not negatively affected. It argues that
allocations to other load serving entities
should be made only after distribution
utilities have been assured sufficient
long-term firm transmission rights to
meet their current and future native
load requirements.
289. Xcel proposes that no more than
50% of an entity’s peak load be eligible
for a long-term financial transmission
right. Xcel states that this value should
be static (i.e. should not allow for load
growth) based on a historical reference
year such as the year preceding the first
allocation. Strategic Energy suggests that
an RTO might limit long-term hedges to
the lowest daily system peak over the
previous planning period.
290. Some commenters do not agree
with proposals to limit the amount of
transmission capacity that is available
for long-term firm transmission
100 See, e.g., OMS, DTE, EEI, IPL, Reliant,
Strategic Energy and Xcel.
PO 00000
Frm 00032
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
rights.101 NRECA states that it does not
understand how such an approach does
not run afoul of the language of new
FPA section 217. Ameren states that the
preference that EPAct 2005 gives to load
serving entities with long-term power
supply arrangements to meet their
service obligations reflects Congress’
judgment that load serving entities
engaging in long-term contracting and
investment to meet their service
obligations should be supported with
access to long-term firm transmission
rights; therefore, Ameren submits that
this preference should not be
undermined by limiting capacity
available for long-term firm
transmission rights. TANC states that
the Commission should not allow
transmission organizations the ability to
limit the amount of transmission
capacity available to support long-term
firm transmission rights, but should
instead require transmission
organizations to actively manage the
level of long-term firm transmission
rights necessary to meet entities’ current
native load obligations, including load
growth estimates.
Rules for Determining Priority
291. Some commenters offer specific
recommendations concerning the rules
for determining when an entity is
entitled to receive priority with respect
to long-term firm transmission rights.102
For example, Public Power Council
recommends that, pursuant to section
217(d), the transmission rights not used
to meet service obligations may be
applied to other uses of the system.
According to Public Power Council, this
necessarily means that the transmission
rights must first be offered to load
serving entities and after their needs are
met, they are released to others.
292. PG&E argues that the preference,
at least with respect to initial
allocations, should be in accordance
with the term and quantity of the
service obligation, reflected as load
share in the future term. For those
transmission organizations that adopt
auctions to follow initial allocations,
PG&E recommends that stakeholders
should address the issue of whether
shortage of available long-term firm
transmission rights relative to demand
should trigger a validation procedure
such that load serving entities seeking to
meet long-term service obligations are
given preference, or whether the auction
price should determine priority.
101 See, e.g., NRECA, Ameren, Public Power
Council and TANC.
102 See, e.g., Santa Clara, Public Power Council,
PG&E, National Grid, Morgan Stanley, DC Energy,
Cinergy, BP Energy and Wisconsin Electric.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
293. Morgan Stanley states that it is
not necessarily opposed to the auction
revenue right allocation methodologies
that are based on the amount of load
served by a party. However, in Morgan
Stanley’s view, it is crucial that any
auction revenue right grants be
independent of the status of the
organization, i.e., whether it is a load
serving entity.
294. As to the definition of a ‘‘Longterm Power Supply Arrangement’’ that
would be eligible for the long-term
protections, DC Energy states that the
power supply agreement must be firm
for its term and must provide for energy
from one or more specific generators in
specific amounts. Wisconsin Electric
believes that a key eligibility criterion is
whether such arrangement includes not
just energy, but energy and capacity. It
claims that an energy only transaction
does not indicate long-term control of
the unit. Cinergy believes that
preferential access to existing
transmission capacity that is secured on
the basis of long-term power supply
arrangements should be limited to new
long-term power supply arrangements
for new generation.
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Using Long-Term Firm Transmission
Rights to Grandfather Existing Uses
295. A number of commenters address
the issue of whether or not historical
uses of the transmission system should
be given priority for granting long-term
firm transmission rights.103 FirstEnergy
states that the Commission’s proposal is
a reasonable response to the legislative
mandate so long as ‘‘a preference’’
means that current supply arrangements
are given a priority over past or
historical supply patterns no longer in
place. Coral Power states that the
guidelines are not being proposed
against a clean slate, noting that many
ISOs have already established
grandfathered arrangements. Coral
Power is concerned that a preference
could be used to needlessly expand
grandfather rights that were allocated to
electric utilities when the RTO/ISOs
were formed.
296. PJM states that, while it believes
it is fair to establish a historical load/
long-term firm transmission rights
preference, it also recognizes the need to
create a process to accommodate new
long-term rights to cover load growth
and new long-term contracts. PJM notes
that its long-term firm transmission
right proposal will address these issues.
103 See,
e.g., FirstEnergy, Coral Power, NYAPP,
NRECA, PJM, Santa Clara, Redding and Suez
Energy.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
43595
Eligibility Issues
297. A number of commenters offer
recommendations with respect to the
rules for determining which entities
should be eligible to receive priority in
the allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights.104 For example,
Manitoba Hydro submits that the
Commission should ensure that the
guidelines provide that if a market
participant other than a load serving
entity has a contractual obligation to a
load serving entity to provide
transmission rights and to take
associated congestion risk, it should
have priority to long-term transmission
rights in the same manner as would the
load serving entity.
298. ISO–NE contends that generators
may need these firm transmission rights
as much as load serving entities,
because generators’ bilateral contracts
with load can place the congestion risk
on the generator. In reply, New England
Public Systems states that if load
serving entities with service obligations
and long-term power supply
arrangements are given a priority in
obtaining long-term firm transmission
rights, contracts will be structured or
restructured in order to place the
congestion risk on the party that can
most effectively hedge it. NRECA states
that, if a load serving entity wishes to
sell its long-term firm transmission
rights for a period of years to a power
supplier that is also the transmission
customer, NRECA believes it should be
able to do so.
299. LIPA contends that the
guidelines in proposed section 40.1(d)
do not specifically incorporate the
standards of FPA section 217(b)(4) or
make clear that long-term firm
transmission rights must be available to
all market participants consistent with a
transmission organization’s individual
market design. LIPA states that, while
the availability of long-term firm
transmission rights to all participants
could be implied within the rule, and
while certain guidelines address
necessary elements of long-term firm
transmission rights to promote use of
such rights by load serving entities, the
existing ambiguity can be removed by
modification of the general rule.
300. Some customers argue that the
priority for long-term firm transmission
rights should extend to customers that
are outside the transmission
organization’s control area. E.ON claims
that, as currently proposed, utilities that
either do not belong to an RTO, or have
302. Many commenters claim that the
proposed priority would undermine
state-mandated retail access programs
and harm competitive retail
suppliers.105 Allegheny submits that the
Commission should not create a
situation in which load serving entities
that participate in state-mandated
supply procurement programs will be
given a lower priority in long-term firm
transmission right allocations.
Constellation claims that the preference
for longer-term supply resources would
discriminate against competitive retail
suppliers with service obligations in
two respects. First, vertically integrated
utilities with long-term resources could
receive a priority with respect to
capacity, blocking smaller retail
providers from gaining access or entry
to markets to compete effectively.
Second, a preference for longer-term
104 See, e.g., Manitoba Hydro, Coral Power,
CMUA, ISO–NE, New England Public Systems,
PPM Energy, Midwest ISO, NRECA, IPL, PJM and
LIPA.
105 See, e.g., Allegheny, Cinergy, Constellation,
Coral Power, Midwest ISO, Exelon, NARUC, OMS,
Suez Energy, NEPOOL, National Grid, NU and
NSTAR.
PO 00000
Frm 00033
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
no organized electricity market in which
they can participate, cannot expect any
priority in the allocation of long-term
firm transmission rights into or out of an
organized market. E.ON urges the
Commission to consider granting
priority to a load serving entity that
satisfies the provisions of FPA section
217(a), either owns or has firm rights to
the output of a capacity resource located
within the boundaries of an adjacent
RTO, and has acquired from that RTO
transmission service necessary to
deliver energy to the load serving
entity’s load located outside of the
adjacent RTO. TANC states that longterm firm transmission rights should be
provided first to entities with native
load service obligations that contribute
to the embedded cost of the
transmission systems, including entities
that may not be within the transmission
organization’s control area.
301. Industrial Consumers argues that
load serving entities in trust for loads,
or loads directly, should be allocated
short-term and long-term transmission
rights on a pro rata basis as necessary to
serve the total load. Alcoa states that
priority also should be extended
without discrimination to end users that
act as their own load serving entities.
CMUA adds that entities eligible in
California for long-term firm
transmission rights should include
California’s large state and local water
agencies, which represent a significant
portion of the state’s energy usage, and
are part of wholesale markets, but which
do not serve retail load.
Retail Access Issues
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43596
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
firm transmission rights would
discriminate against the shorter-term
firm transmission rights that allow
competitive retail providers with service
obligations to more closely match shifts
in their load, which, according to
Constellation, can occur frequently,
even daily.
303. Exelon notes that, in New Jersey
and Illinois, the state commissions have
determined that the public utilities
should procure customers’ requirements
through a competitive auction
procedure approved by the Commission.
Exelon states that the rules of the
auction preclude the utilities from
entering into contracts of more than a
few years’ duration.
304. Regarding the effect of long-term
firm transmission rights on retail access,
Redding, APPA and TAPS take a
different view. APPA states that the
desire of retail suppliers like
Constellation and the members of EPSA
for flexibility has to date prevented load
serving entities in retail choice regions
that wish to hedge transmission
congestion associated with their longterm base load and renewable resources
from doing so. APPA asserts that, while
suppliers in retail choice areas may
value flexibility, the associated shortterm arrangements do not support the
substantial new investments in
generation needed to meet resource
adequacy or fuel diversification needs.
Similarly, TAPS states that is bad policy
to force all load serving entities in all
states to share that fate (i.e., denying all
consumers the benefits of low cost
energy) simply because some states may
have concluded that is the right
decision for those serving retail load
within their state.
Obtaining Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights through Capacity
Expansions
305. Some commenters argue that the
long-term needs of load serving entities
should be met through the transmission
organization’s planning and expansion
process, not by granting priority access
to long-term firm transmission rights
supported by existing capacity.106
306. Constellation states that section
217(b)(4) requires the Commission to be
proactive in ensuring that the needs of
all load serving entities with a service
obligation (regardless of the duration of
that service obligation) are met through
planning and expansion of transmission
facilities and enabling load serving
entities to secure firm transmission
rights on a long-term basis, not to
extend an undue preference for existing
106 See, e.g., E.ON, Constellation, EPSA, NYISO
and Strategic Energy.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
transmission capacity to load serving
entities with long-term supply
arrangements at the expense of other
load serving entities with service
obligations. NRECA agrees that the
Commission does have an obligation
under section 217 to facilitate
transmission planning and expansion so
as to support long-term power-supply
and transmission arrangements.
However, NRECA asserts that the
Commission also has a specific duty to
act in a manner that ‘‘enables load
serving entities to secure firm
transmission rights * * * on a longterm basis for long-term power supply
arrangements.’’
Market, Efficiency and Gaming Issues
307. A number of commenters argue
that the proposed priority will impede
the development of competitive markets
and create inefficient economic
incentives.107 For example, EEI states
that long-term firm transmission right
holders will have the incentive to resist
infrastructure enhancements to the
system that adversely affect the value of
their long-term firm transmission rights.
Also, SDG&E contends that, on
transmission paths that are expected to
have relatively higher levels of
congestion, e.g., where the transmission
rights are expected to be more valuable,
an incentive is created to enter into
long-term commodity transactions in
order to secure the priority. According
to SDG&E, such incentives are
misplaced and could distort efficient
contracting decisions. NYISO believes
that rather than having an incentive to
contract for the least cost resources to
meet their load, load serving entities
would have an incentive to enter into
contracts on the ‘‘wrong’’ side of
binding transmission constraints,
because they would receive valuable
transmission rights as a reward for
executing such contracts.
308. Other commenters take the
opposite view, arguing that the
proposed priority would lead to more
efficient investment decisions and lower
costs in the long run.108 FirstEnergy
states that the availability of long-term
service is needed to facilitate
investment in new generation capacity
and transmission infrastructure.
309. APPA argues that the primary
role of long-term firm transmission
rights would be to support base load
and renewable generation resources
needed to support load serving entity
service obligations. Those resources are
107 See, e.g., EEI, EPSA, Reliant, Exelon,
Constellation, SDG&E, NYISO and Midwest ISO.
108 See, e.g., APPA, NYAPP, NRECA, DWR,
CMUA, FirstEnergy and New England Public
Systems.
PO 00000
Frm 00034
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
not sited based on whether they are on
the ‘‘right’’ or ‘‘wrong’’ side of a
constraint, but on a myriad of factors,
including proximity to fuel sources,
access to rail transportation and
availability of renewable resources (e.g.,
wind or geothermal). APPA states that
the failure of RTOs to offer long-term
firm transmission rights is stifling
investment in base load and renewable
generation resources, and in the
associated transmission facilities
needed to bring these resources to loads.
310. Several commenters express
concern that the proposed priority
would create an incentive for load
serving entities to acquire excess longterm firm transmission rights in order to
sell the excess at a profit, and could lead
parties to enter into ‘‘sham’’
contracts.109
311. ISO–NE contends that a direct,
costless allocation of LT-firm
transmission rights, or an auction in
which only load serving entities may
purchase LT-firm transmission rights,
would amount to a wealth transfer to
the load serving entities at the expense
of other market participants. According
to ISO–NE, this is because the load
serving entities would acquire the LTfirm transmission rights at a price below
their value and have every incentive to
resell them on the secondary market for
a profit. Midwest ISO states that this
guideline may give parties an incentive
to enter into ‘‘sham’’ contracts intended
to accomplish nothing but establishing
rights to valuable long-term firm
transmission rights.
312. Ameren believes that the concern
that load serving entities will nominate
excessive amounts of long-term firm
transmission rights is easily addressed
by limiting the amount of long-term firm
transmission rights allocable to a load
serving entity based on its expected
load, including load growth, during the
upcoming year and using state
regulatory processes to police
nominations. APPA states that the RTO
can take the matter up with the load
serving entity on a case-by-case basis if
it believes that the long-term firm
transmission right allocation of the load
serving entity does not appropriately
reflect load growth.
313. PG&E notes that the EPAct 2005’s
focus on the ‘‘long-term service
obligation,’’ its predication of the
threshold amount of Transmission
Rights on those ‘‘power supply
arrangements’’ that constitute
‘‘reasonable needs,’’ as well as the
EPAct 2005’s provisions for shifting
long-term Transmission Rights in
109 See, e.g., ISO–NE, Midwest ISO, NYISO, Coral
Power, APPA and CPUC.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
parallel with load migration, provides
ample opportunity for protection against
‘‘sham contracts’’ and the possibility of
windfall to load serving entities, so long
as the statutory terms are well defined.
APPA states that it and its members are
willing to agree to reasonable
limitations on long-term firm
transmission rights, including
restrictions on resale and requirements
that holders actually have generation
resource arrangements covering the
specified sources and sinks, to avoid
creating such perverse financial
incentives. Also, New England Public
Systems notes that TAPS has proposed
dispatch-contingent option long-term
firm transmission rights that only
generate a payment to the load serving
entity when the resource at issue is run
and do not require payment by the load
serving entity when congestion is
reversed. Alternatively, New England
Public Systems states that long-term
firm transmission right settlements
could be subject to true up at year end
based on actual load levels.
Allowing for Load Growth in Long-Term
Firm Transmission Rights and the Need
for Accurate Load Forecasts
314. Some commenters argue that
priority in the allocation of long-term
firm transmission rights should extend
to provisions for load growth and
unforeseen changes in the need for longterm rights.110 Public Power Council
argues that the preference should
require RTOs and ISOs to set aside
future rights for the load growth of these
entities and the Commission should
ensure that the transmission system is
planned and expanded to accommodate
growth.
315. Allegheny argues that
incremental firm transmission rights to
cover increases in generation capacity
resources, load growth or other factors
should also be granted as part of the
long-term firm transmission right
allocation process, but only to the extent
that the underlying transmission system
can support the feasibility of such
additional firm transmission rights. AEP
believes it is inappropriate for auction
revenue right allocations to be locked
into a configuration that may bear no
resemblance in year 10 to the
simultaneous feasibility tests run in year
one. Industrial Consumers believes that
the load serving entity or a load that is
serving itself should have access to
additional capacity rights for unforeseen
load growth, and similarly, the load
serving entity or load serving itself
110 See, e.g., Public Power Council, Allegheny,
AEP, Industrial Consumers, PJM Public Power
Coalition, Alcoa and FirstEnergy.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
should be required to surrender that
portion of its rights for the amount of
any permanent load reduction.
316. PJM Public Power Coalition
argues that if, during the roll-over term
of the long-term transmission rights, a
load serving entity’s load is reduced
below the level of its long-term
transmission rights, that entity’s rollover right should be reduced to its then
current load level, so that the entity
does not have priority to transmission
capacity it will not use to serve its load.
Administrative Burden
317. Midwest ISO states that the
Commission’s requirement that
transmission organizations provide load
serving entities priority to existing
transmission capacity is problematic for
several reasons. First, transmission
organizations will have to undertake
extensive, burdensome, and costly
administrative processes in order to
evaluate contracts to determine whether
they satisfy the criteria applicable and
ensure that the power supply contracts
are in fact necessary to serve load and
are long-term. Midwest ISO argues that
the transmission organizations should
not be placed in the position of
evaluating long-term contracts to ensure
they legitimately qualify for priority of
the transmission capacity. In response,
APPA notes that many Regional
Reliability Councils have long
undertaken auditing of load serving
entity power supply portfolios to
determine if their regions have adequate
generation resources. APPA claims that
the term of power supply agreements is
usually relatively easy to ascertain, and
annual reporting by the load serving
entities on their generation resource
portfolios, plus oversight and
investigation by the RTO’s Market
Monitor if gaming is suspected, should
be sufficient to keep load serving
entities honest. APPA also notes that,
under section 30 of the Order No. 888
OATT, Network Customers have to
designate new resources by providing
the required information to the
Transmission Provider. Hence, in
APPA’s view, Network Customers are
accustomed to having to verify their
claimed generation resources.
Commission Conclusion
318. We will adopt guideline (5) with
revisions to eliminate the preference for
load serving entities with long-term
power supply arrangements and replace
it with a general preference for load
`
serving entities vis-a-vis non-load
serving entities. Also, as discussed
below, we will revise guideline (5) to
allow the transmission organization to
place reasonable limits on the amount of
PO 00000
Frm 00035
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43597
existing transmission capacity that it
will make available for long-term firm
transmission rights.
319. Although we believe section
217(b)(4) of the FPA would support a
preference for load serving entities with
long-term power supply arrangements,
we agree with those commenters, such
as SDG&E, that claim that EPAct 2005
should not be construed to require that
a preference be given to this class of
load serving entities at the expense of
load serving entities that prefer shortterm power supply arrangements. In our
view, a broader preference for load
`
serving entities in general vis-a-vis nonload serving entities is fully supported
by the statute and indeed better meets
the needs of today’s organized
electricity markets.
320. The overall thrust of new section
217 of the FPA, read in its entirety, is
the protection of transmission rights
used to satisfy native load service
obligations.111 Given the reality that
transmission capacity is limited, and
that the amount that can reasonably be
made available for long-term
transmission rights may be lesser still,
we believe that section 217 of the FPA
provides a general ‘‘due’’ preference for
load serving entities to obtain long-term
firm transmission service. Moreover,
section 217(d), which provides that the
Commission may make transmission
rights that are not used to meet a load
serving entity’s service available to
other entities, strongly indicates that
Congress intended for load serving
entities to be ‘‘first in line’’ for long-term
transmission rights that are made
available.
321. An important advantage of
revising guideline (5) in this manner is
that, in most cases, the transmission
organization will be able to apply the
same basic principles for allocating
long-term firm transmission rights that
it currently uses for the initial allocation
of short-term firm transmission rights,
or auction revenue rights. To explain,
we note that most transmission
organizations now use straightforward
methods to allocate firm transmission
rights (or auction revenue rights)
annually to all load serving entities that
support the embedded costs of the
transmission system. Some of these
methods take explicit account of the
load serving entity’s current or
historical power supply arrangements in
determining its allocation priority.
However, as revised, guideline (5)
111 As noted above, common principles of
statutory interpretation support reading section 217
as a whole to ascertain its intent. See, e.g., United
States v. Andrews, 441 F.3d 220, 223 (4th Cir. 2006)
(noting that statutory phrases are not construed in
isolation, and are instead read as a whole).
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43598
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
neither requires nor prohibits the
consideration of power supply
arrangements in determining this
priority. Guideline (5), as revised, only
requires that load serving entities have
priority over non-load serving entities in
the allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights. This means that, in
most cases, load serving entities can
continue to receive the same allocation
of firm transmission rights (or auction
revenue rights) that they have received
in the past. In addition, by eliminating
from guideline (5) the priority for load
serving entities with long-term power
supply arrangements, we are making it
possible for the transmission
organization to propose an allocation
method that eliminates any obligation
on the part of either the transmission
organization or the load serving entity to
demonstrate or verify that the load
serving entity holds a qualifying longterm power supply arrangement.
322. In addition, revising the
guideline in this manner effectively
addresses the objections of most
commenters that oppose guideline (5) as
proposed in the NOPR. Importantly, it
largely eliminates the potential for load
serving entities that prefer short-term
power supply arrangements, or are
precluded from entering into long-term
arrangements, to be disadvantaged in
the allocation of firm transmission
rights. In particular, load serving
entities in retail access states can
continue to receive and use their
allocated firm transmission rights as
short-term instruments, if that best suits
their business model. Also, load serving
entities that prefer short-term firm
transmission rights (or are limited to
them by law) will not feel compelled to
request long-term firm transmission
rights (or enter into sham contracts) out
of fear that they might otherwise lose
out in the firm transmission right
allocation process. We do not believe
that Congress intended these results
when it enacted section 217 of the FPA,
particularly given the statute’s overall
focus on protecting the transmission
rights of load serving entities with
service obligations. Finally, the
transmission organization will not face
the administrative burden of having to
evaluate power supply contracts to
determine if they qualify for the
preference.
323. In the NOPR, we asked for
comments on whether section 1233 of
EPAct 2005 and new section 217(b)(4) of
the FPA support placing reasonable
limits on the award of long-term rights.
Because of uncertainty regarding load
growth, changes in power flows and
other factors, the Commission expects
that the transmission organization may
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
be reluctant to commit all of its existing
capacity to long-term firm transmission
rights, especially in light of guideline
(2)’s full funding requirement. Also,
commenters claim that the principal
need for long-term firm transmission
rights is to support long-term power
supply arrangements only for base load
generation, not peaking or intermediate
generation. Therefore, we conclude that
the transmission organization and its
stakeholders should be given flexibility
to determine the level at which a load
serving entity may nominate long-term
firm transmission rights as long as that
level does not fall below the ‘‘reasonable
needs’’ of the load serving entity. This
level can be expressed in a variety of
ways, for example as a straightforward
measure of load, such as minimum daily
peak load or 50 percent of maximum
daily peak load. In this regard, we note
that some commenters argue that the
allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights should include
provisions for load growth, to include
the loss of long-term firm transmission
rights when load declines. Rather than
specify an approach here, we will
provide the transmission organization
and its stakeholders with flexibility to
propose an approach for incorporating
load growth in the allocation process, if
it is incorporated at all.
324. The Commission emphasizes that
revising guideline (5) in this manner
should not significantly reduce the
access to long-term firm transmission
rights that a load serving entity with
long-term power supply arrangements
would have had under guideline (5) as
originally proposed. Under that
proposal, load serving entities with
power supply arrangements of more
than one year (per our proposed
definition of long-term power supply
arrangements) would have qualified for
an allocation preference; our revision
only expands the preference to include
load serving entities that have power
supply arrangements of less than one
year. Moreover, most supporters of
proposed guideline (5) agree that a
transmission organization will have
valid reasons to place a limit on the
amount of system capacity that it makes
available to support long-term firm
transmission rights. Also, most of the
commenters that support guideline (5)
as proposed do not include among the
reasons for their support the need to
link the award of long-term firm
transmission rights to long-term power
supply arrangements. Rather, their
comments are principally directed
against any notion that load serving
entities with short-term firm
transmission rights should receive
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
special consideration in the allocation
process. Finally, the other guidelines
adopted here ensure that the long-term
firm transmission rights will support
long-term power supply arrangements,
as Congress intended.
325. Our decision to make explicit the
transmission organization’s right to
propose reasonable limits on the
amount of capacity made available for
long-term firm transmission rights, as
well as to provide the more limited
preference that we are adopting in the
Final Rule, requires that we revise
guideline (5) to read as follows:
Guideline (5): Load serving entities must
have priority over non-load serving entities
in the allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights that are supported by
existing transmission capacity. The
transmission organization may propose
reasonable limits on the amount of existing
transmission capacity used to support longterm firm transmission rights.
326. Commenters such as Manitoba
Hydro and ISO–NE argue that the
preference should extend to certain
entities that do not meet the strict
definition of load serving entity, such as
generators that have a contractual
obligation to a load serving entity.112
The Commission disagrees. Extending
the preference to entities that do not
meet the definition of load serving
entity, as clarified in this Final Rule,
would likely defeat the purpose of
providing the preference. Once load
serving entities have received their
allocated firm transmission rights, those
firm transmission rights and any
additional firm transmission rights
available from remaining system
capacity can be offered to non-load
serving entities (as well as other load
serving entities) through a secondary
auction, bilateral trades or another
method of allocation. This is consistent
with section 217(d) of the FPA. Also, as
noted by New England Public Systems,
a load serving entity that has a
contractual arrangement with a
generator or other entity that allocates
congestion risk in a particular way can
structure its contract with that entity as
necessary to achieve the desired risk
sharing.
327. Industrial Consumers, Alcoa and
CMUA state that certain end users
should receive the preference provided
by guideline (5). As we stated above in
our clarification of the definition of load
serving entity, any end user, such as an
industrial consumer or a large water
agency, that is allowed under state law
and regulation to participate in
wholesale markets as a power purchaser
112 See also our discussion of the definition of
load serving entity in section II.A. above.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
should be construed as a load serving
entity under the Final Rule and,
accordingly, should receive all of the
rights and obligations of a load serving
entity.
328. E.ON asks that a load serving
entity outside of a transmission
organization’s boundaries be given
priority, under certain conditions, to
long-term firm transmission rights on
the transmission organization’s
transmission system. On this matter, the
Commission agrees with TANC that
long-term firm transmission rights
should be made available first to those
entities that have an obligation to serve
load within the transmission
organization’s service territory and are
required to contribute to the embedded
cost of the transmission organization’s
transmission system. Any entity that has
neither an obligation to serve load on
the transmission organization’s
transmission system, nor an obligation
to pay the embedded costs of that
system, should not be given a preference
to acquire long-term firm transmission
rights supported by the system’s
existing capacity.
329. LIPA states that the proposed
guidelines do not specifically
incorporate the standards of FPA
section 217(b)(4), or make clear that
long-term firm transmission rights must
be available to all market participants,
and therefore should be revised. We do
not believe that any revision is
necessary. The guidelines, taken as a
whole, are designed to implement the
relevant requirements of EPAct 2005,
including the provisions of FPA section
217(b)(4). We believe that the guidelines
as revised in this Final Rule provide the
clarity that LIPA seeks. Further, we have
made clear both in the NOPR and in this
Final Rule that long-term firm
transmission rights must be available to
all market participants; this guideline
serves only as a ‘‘tiebreaker’’ between
load serving entities and non-load
serving entities when existing
transmission capacity is limited.
330. Finally, we note that several
commenters express concern that the
preference as proposed in guideline (5)
will lead market participants to resist
infrastructure enhancements, enter into
sham contracts, or make inefficient
investment decisions. We conclude that,
by eliminating the priority for load
serving entities with long-term power
supply arrangements, and by allowing
limits to be placed on the amount of
capacity available for long-term firm
transmission rights, the Final Rule
should virtually eliminate any incentive
that a load serving entity might
otherwise have to hoard long-term firm
transmission rights, enter into sham
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
agreements or resort to other types of
gaming and inefficient decision-making.
Indeed, the Commission agrees with
APPA that a likely greater source of
inefficiency is the unavailability of longterm firm transmission rights in
organized electricity markets, which
may be impeding needed investments in
generation resources and transmission
upgrades. Nevertheless, if a
transmission organization and its
stakeholders conclude that additional
steps must be taken to avert such
problems, the transmission organization
may propose appropriate measures as
part of its compliance filing.
Guideline (6)—Rights are Reassignable
to Follow Load
331. As proposed in the NOPR,
guideline (6) stated that a long-term
transmission right held by a load
serving entity to support a service
obligation should be re-assignable to
another entity that acquires that service
obligation. The NOPR stated that a
successor load serving entity should
assume any cost responsibility that
holding the long-term transmission right
entails. We stated that this proposal is
consistent with section 217(b)(3)(A) of
the FPA, which requires that
transmission rights held by a load
serving entity as of the date of
enactment of EPAct 2005 for the
purpose of delivering energy it has
purchased or generated to meet a service
obligation be transferred to a successor
load serving entity. The NOPR noted
that the short-term transmission rights
currently offered by transmission
organizations are generally reassignable
to successor load serving entities. The
NOPR also noted that a transfer of a
service obligation might occur pursuant
to a state commission order, or might
occur in a state with retail competition
if load chooses a new supplier.
332. The NOPR asked for comments
regarding whether reassignability
should apply to all long-term firm
transmission rights, regardless of how
those rights were obtained, and whether
a holder of long-term rights should
receive compensation when its rights
are reassigned.
333. Also, the NOPR noted that
section 217(b)(4) of the FPA does not
discuss whether long-term firm
transmission rights should be fully
tradable among market participants. We
stated that allowing such rights to be
fully tradable could raise issues of
equity, since a load serving entity that
acquired the rights through a preference
could then possibly sell or trade the
rights at a profit. This might give load
serving entities the incentive to acquire
excess long-term firm transmission
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43599
rights in order to take advantage of
profit opportunities. However, the
NOPR noted that full tradability may
bring benefits to the market, and allow
those that could not obtain long-term
rights in the initial allocation to obtain
such rights later. The NOPR asked for
comments on these issues.
Comments
General Support for Guideline (6)
334. Many commenters express strong
support for proposed guideline (6).113
AEP states that a transmission right to
support a service obligation should stay
with the load and, therefore, be reassignable to another entity that may
acquire the service obligation. APPA
supports guideline (6) and states that
such assignability should be required
regardless of how those rights were
obtained.
335. Cinergy supports the adoption of
guideline (6) in principle because it
believes that market liquidity provides
for more efficient economic outcomes
and that the problems associated with
other guidelines may be mitigated to
some degree by directing that long-term
transmission rights be re-assignable.
BPA states that this policy should
accommodate other open access policies
where the long-term transmission rights
of the original load serving entity would
transfer (1) to other load serving entities
that successfully compete to serve loads
under state retail access programs, or (2)
to wholesale power suppliers that
successfully compete to meet load
serving entity service obligations.
Need for Flexibility
336. Some commenters urge the
Commission to permit flexibility in the
way transmission organizations
implement this guideline. Reliant states
that the Commission should permit
organized electricity markets and their
stakeholders to best determine the
reassignment of long-term transmission
rights. EEI states that flexibility is
important in the application of this
guideline because it will present
administrative burdens with respect to
tracking reassignments on a frequent
basis. CMUA states that, given the
different retail choice regimes in
different regions, or the lack of retail
choice in some, implementation is best
left to the relevant regions.
113 See, e.g., PJM, NRECA, CMUA, Santa Clara,
Xcel, Allegheny, Public Power Council, AEP,
APPA, AF&PA, Minnesota Power, BPA, Strategic
Energy, Coral Power and PJM Public Power
Coalition.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43600
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Should Reassignment be Optional or
Mandatory?
337. NYISO states that this proposal
is reasonable provided that the rights
may be reassigned, not that they
automatically be reassigned, at least in
the case of transmission organizations
with grandfathered auction based
systems under FPA section 217(b) (3).
Similarly, Xcel states that reassignment
itself must not be mandated; the
reassignment should be at the option of
the holder of the right and the entity to
which the service obligation transfers.
PJM Public Power Coalition states that
because these long-term rights can
become a liability under certain
circumstances, entities should be able to
trade, transfer, or decline to exercise the
rights.
338. Suez Energy states that guideline
(6) might be interpreted in a way that
destroys retail competition because
incumbents might argue that long-term
firm transmission rights are merely reassignable at the choice of the
incumbent supplier, and that the
incumbent should be allowed to retain
valuable long-term firm transmission
rights for existing network service.
Conversely, Suez Energy is concerned
that an incumbent supplier that
invested badly could argue that the
financial burden of a now burdensome
investment in transmission
infrastructure is reassignable to a new
supplier.
339. ISO–NE believes that the
Commission should examine proposals
for mandatory re-assignment carefully
where the load serving entity picking up
the service obligation has a different set
of long-term supply arrangements that
may not correspond with the path for
the existing long-term firm transmission
right, or if the successor load serving
entity may not wish to utilize a longterm supply strategy at all.
Rules Governing Reassignment
340. Several commenters offered
proposals for rules that would govern
the reassignment of long-term firm
transmission rights in specific
instances.114 The CAISO asks the
Commission to clarify guideline (6) to
state that the transmission organization
should adopt provisions to require that
either allocated long-term firm
transmission rights or their equivalent
financial value be transferred from one
load serving entity to another to reflect
transfers of load serving obligation. The
CAISO believes that by allowing load
serving entities to transfer the financial
114 See, e.g., CAISO, SoCal Edison, PG&E, APPA,
Redding, CMUA, Strategic Energy, Midwest ISO,
SDG&E, BPA, TAPS and Alcoa.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
value of long-term firm transmission
rights when their load serving obligation
migrates, instead of insisting on the
transfer of the actual long-term firm
transmission rights, the underlying
principle that the allocated long-term
firm transmission rights are the property
of the end-use customers can be
maintained without precluding the
trading of allocated long-term firm
transmission rights by load serving
entities.
341. SoCal Edison recommends that
the only circumstances in which longterm rights should be reassigned are if:
(1) The original right was allocated (i.e.
any rights purchased bilaterally or in an
auction would not be transferred
regardless of any load migration); and
(2) the load-gaining entity has the ability
to utilize the same source/sink pair that
was used to allocate the long-term right
to the load-losing entity; and (3) the
load losing entity can no longer use the
entire long-term transmission right for
the output/load upon which the longterm right was initially awarded to the
load-losing entity. PG&E agrees that no
transfer should occur until such time as
a load serving entity’s remaining service
obligation is less than the megawatt
quantity of its long-term firm
transmission rights. Also, PG&E believes
that the statutory intent to link longterm transmission rights to long-term
power supply arrangements would be
realized if transmission rights or
equivalent payments are made only to
those load serving entities that gain
long-term service obligations and that
also obtain commensurate long-term
power supply arrangements. However,
APPA claims that SoCal Edison’s
condition (2) seems unnecessarily
stringent and asserts that, if the
transmission organization can
reconfigure the long-term firm
transmission rights at the time of
transfer, then this should be permitted.
342. Redding contends that when the
Commission raises the issue of
assignability it implicitly raises the
question of portfolio strategy. Redding
argues that, if the load serving entity has
long-term transmission rights and longterm supply arrangements that were not
utilized to serve the customer with retail
choice, then the customer’s decision to
change providers should not result in
the reassignment of a long-term
transmission right. Redding contends
that there would be an argument for
transfer of the transmission right only if
the customer can demonstrate that it
either directly or indirectly had a
liability that transferred to the new
provider or remained with the customer.
343. Midwest ISO states that the
entity that acquires the service
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
obligation may not want the particular
long-term firm transmission right, but
may prefer a different firm transmission
right with a source that matches the
supply portfolio of the new load serving
entity. Moreover, the firm transmission
right may have negative value and the
new load serving entity may not want it
at all. To the extent the Commission
permits such re-assignment, Midwest
ISO recommends that reasonable
restrictions be imposed. For example,
Midwest ISO states that the Final Rule
should limit the impact of this issue by
(1) limiting the amount of long-term
firm transmission rights to a small
proportion of load serving entity’s load,
and (2) limiting the term of the firm
transmission right. In response, APPA
states that it prefers its proposed
suggestions of minimum hold times,
minimum periods for any resale, or a
requirement that the new holders have
generation resources and loads for the
points specified in the long-term firm
transmission rights, or the
Commission’s suggestion that long-term
firm transmission right holders only be
able to return their long-term firm
transmission rights to the transmission
organization.
344. SDG&E states that any
reassignment mechanism that links
specific long-term firm transmission
rights to individual loads will become
administratively burdensome if the
switching of load between load serving
entities is active, with the transmission
organization potentially forced to track
thousands of long-term firm
transmission rights that are reduced to
fractions of megawatts.
345. Alcoa states that an end user that
acts as its own load serving entity must
be afforded the same opportunity as a
load serving entity to reassign its longterm transmission rights to another
entity that acquires a service obligation
for its load.
Compensation Issues
346. Some commenters provided
recommendations concerning what, if
any, compensation should be paid when
a long-term firm transmission right is
reassigned to a successor load serving
entity.115 APPA states that
compensation is a matter to be dealt
with by the transferee and transferor
load serving entities. BPA states that all
of the costs and liabilities associated
with the transferred rights should follow
to the new load serving entity. However,
BPA recommends that limitations on reassignment, particularly issues relating
115 See, e.g., APPA, Allegheny, BPA, CAISO,
Ameren, AF&PA, Santa Clara, Cinergy and OMS.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
to compensation pricing policy, be left
to the regions to resolve.
347. The CAISO submits that the load
serving entity that has lost a portion of
its service obligation should not be
compensated for any long-term firm
transmission rights it transferred to
another load serving entity for that load.
AF&PA states that, if long-term firm
transmission rights are paid for by the
holder at fair market value, they should
be property of the holder, and should be
assignable by the holder for value or
otherwise in its discretion. Ameren
recommends that there be no
compensation for firm transmission
rights returned to the transmission
organization by a load serving entity.
Santa Clara states that if the holder is
carrying the risk that the congestion cost
could increase and create more value or
decrease and make it less valuable, the
holder should not be forced to return
the rights at the cost at which they were
allocated to them.
congestion management program, as it
would enable the firm transmission
rights to go to those parties that value
them most highly. It also would allow
entities that are not load serving entities
to obtain long-term firm transmission
rights, assuming they value them highly
enough to win them in the market.
351. PG&E states that, because shifts
in service obligations may be temporary
and may be reversed, reassignment of
long-term firm transmission rights with
shifts in service obligations and power
supply arrangements should be
conditioned on assurances that future
shifts of such service obligations and
power supply arrangements are
accompanied by a return of the
accompanying long-term firm
transmission right. PG&E argues that,
while it would be appropriate to allow
trading or transfer of the long-term firm
transmission right for interim periods,
the long-term firm transmission right
itself should remain attached to the
service obligation and not be separately
transferable.
352. IPL argues that there should not
be a requirement that long-term rights
are tradable, and recommends that the
Commission allow the transmission
organizations flexibility to specify the
general terms of reassignments related
to load shifts. Public Power Council
claims that making the rights fully
tradable raises fairness questions if the
seller received a preference due to the
use of the right to meet a service
obligation and the buyer did not. If the
rights were sold to another load serving
entity for the purpose of meeting that
other entity’s service obligations,
however, Public Power Council believes
that the fairness issue would be
avoided.
Trading
348. A number of comments focused
on the question of whether or not longterm firm transmission rights should be
tradable.116 AEP supports the concept of
trading long-term transmission rights as
an appropriate way to facilitate risk
management by load serving entities.
TANC argues that, if after meeting its
native load obligations an entity has
surplus transmission rights, the market
is enhanced by the availability of such
surplus rights. Cinergy believes that
long-term transmission rights acquired
under FPA section 217(b)(4) should be
fully tradable. Also, Cinergy encourages
the Commission to allow market
participants that acquire long-term
transmission rights by investing in
transmission upgrades to trade those
rights for a profit, as that provides even
greater incentive to build transmission
improvements.
349. In SMUD’s view, giving
customers the right to assign their
unused physical transmission rights
temporarily will reduce the likelihood
of hoarding and will serve as a
congestion management tool. In
NRECA’s view, allowing long-term
rights to be tradable would allow load
serving entities a way to reconfigure
their portfolios of long-term firm
transmission rights as their situations
change.
350. Ameren states that making longterm firm transmission rights fully
tradable among market participants
would enhance the efficiency of the
353. A number of commenters express
concern that, if the long-term firm
transmission rights are reassignable and
tradable, a load serving entity might
have an incentive to acquire excess
long-term firm transmission rights for
financial gain.117 EPSA states that it
would be inappropriate for the
Commission to allow utilities to profit
from the sale of any long-term firm
transmission rights that are obtained via
a preferential priority. EPSA claims that
vertically-integrated utilities with longterm contracts could hoard long-term
firm transmission rights, blocking
smaller retail providers from gaining
116 See, e.g., AEP, Midwest ISO, TANC, Cinergy,
SMUD, NRECA, OMS, Ameren, PG&E, Allegheny,
IPL and Public Power Council.
117 See, e.g., EPSA, Santa Clara, OMS, Ameren,
APPA, CMUA, Minnesota Power, Cinergy and
TAPS.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
Gaming and Arbitrage
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43601
access or entry to markets and
competing effectively.
354. Ameren claims that concerns
about possible arbitrage are addressed
by its proposal to place a limitation on
firm transmission right nominations
based on a load serving entity’s load.
APPA recommends that load serving
entities holding long-term firm
transmission rights must have in their
generation portfolios actual resources
(owned or contracted for) and loads
corresponding to the receipt and
delivery points that the long-term firm
transmission rights cover. APPA also
suggests restrictions on the resale of
long-term firm transmission rights in the
form of minimum hold periods and
minimum periods for resale of any right.
However, APPA states that any such
restrictions would have to be balanced
against the need to ‘‘recycle’’ long-term
firm transmission rights to ensure the
most efficient use of the transmission
rights. APPA states that a reasonable
approach would be the Commission’s
suggestion that holders of long-term
firm transmission rights be permitted
only to return their long-term firm
transmission rights to the RTO, and not
to earn any profit on their direct sale to
another market participant. TAPS
claims that its recommended dispatchcontingent firm transmission rights
would have very limited appeal for
market participants interested in firm
transmission right speculation.
355. Minnesota Power urges the
Commission not to allow creation of a
large secondary market in which market
participants are able to inflate the price
of long-term transmission rights or to
use the long-term transmission rights as
an economic position in the market.
Minnesota Power suggests that the longterm transmission rights should be
directly linked to, and tradable only
with, the underlying generation rights or
long-term purchase rights.
Commission Conclusion
356. The Commission will adopt
guideline (6) as proposed in the NOPR,
but will provide transmission
organizations and their stakeholders
with flexibility to determine specific
rules for reassignment of long-term firm
transmission rights. We note that most,
if not all, transmission organizations
now have rules governing the
reassignment of firm transmission rights
when load migrates from one load
serving entity to another. The
introduction of long-term firm
transmission rights should not in itself
require a change in the basic structure
of these rules. In at least some
transmission organizations,
reassignment is achieved through a
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43602
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
reallocation of auction revenue rights,
with a provision to allow the auction
revenue rights to be converted into firm
transmission rights.
357. In general, the issue of
reassignment should arise only in the
context of firm transmission rights
(short-term or long-term) that are
allocated preferentially to a load serving
entity in accordance with guideline (5).
If a load serving entity acquires firm
transmission rights through an auction
or as a result of funding a transmission
upgrade, it should not be required to
reassign such rights because any entity
is free to acquire firm transmission
rights in this manner. Also, a load
serving entity that acquires long-term
firm transmission rights to support the
financing of a new generating facility
should not, in general, be required to
give up those rights simply because
some of its load migrates to another load
serving entity. However, a possible
exception may arise if the original load
serving entity were to lose so much of
its load that the total of its long-term
firm transmission rights exceeds its
remaining load. In this case, as noted by
PG&E, some mandatory reassignment
may be justified.
358. The Commission believes that all
long-term firm transmission rights
should be tradable. Allowing tradability
provides the load serving entity with
flexibility to manage its transmission
rights portfolio and helps to ensure that
long-term firm transmission rights go to
the market participants that value them
most highly. Reassignments may be
temporary. However, long-term firm
transmission rights that the load serving
entity obtains preferentially through an
allocation process should be tradable
only with the proviso that any trades
may be subject to recall if load migrates
to another load serving entity. Making
the long-term firm transmission rights
subject to recall ensures that they can be
reassigned if necessary to follow
migrating load, consistent with section
217(b)(3)(A) of the FPA. We note,
however, in a transmission organization
where reassignment is accomplished
through a reallocation of auction
revenue rights, rather than the firm
transmission rights themselves, there
may be no need for such a proviso. In
this case, reassignment would be
accomplished through a financial
transfer, allowing the actual long-term
firm transmission rights to remain with
the original load serving entity. This
should satisfy the CAISO’s request that
the Commission permit either the
allocated long-term firm transmission
rights or their equivalent financial value
to be transferred from one load serving
entity to another to reflect a transfer of
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
load serving obligation. In addition,
allocating auction revenue rights would
also eliminate any need to place
restrictions on reassignments, such as
requiring the successor load serving
entity to hold a supply contract that
uses the same source/sink pair used by
the original load serving entity.
359. Also, when reassignment of
auction revenue rights or firm
transmission rights is mandated due to
a shift in load serving responsibility,
any cost responsibilities associated with
the holding of such rights, such as
payment of transmission access charges,
should shift from the original load
serving entity to the successor load
serving entity. No other compensation
should be required. Again, the specific
rules for accomplishing this should be
left to the transmission organization and
its stakeholders. With regard to firm
transmission rights or long-term firm
transmission rights that are acquired by
auction or as a result of funding a
transmission upgrade, the Commission
believes (as noted above) that in general
there should be no restrictions on
trading such rights. Transfers should be
permitted to occur at prices negotiated
by the buyer and seller.
360. In response to Alcoa, the
Commission notes that an end user that
is permitted under state law to
participate in wholesale markets may
acquire, trade and reassign long-term
firm transmission rights in accordance
with guideline (6) in the same manner
as other load serving entities, as
discussed above under guideline (5).
Guideline (7)—Auction Not Required
361. As proposed in the NOPR,
guideline (7) stated that the initial
allocation of the long-term firm
transmission rights shall not require
recipients to participate in an auction.
The Commission noted that, currently,
most transmission organizations either
allocate transmission rights directly to
eligible parties, or allocate auction
revenue rights directly and then
conduct a transmission rights auction in
which parties with and without
allocated rights can participate. If an
auction model is adopted or continued
by the transmission organization, the
Commission proposed to require that
any long-term rights allocated as auction
revenue rights be capable of being
directly converted to transmission rights
without participation in the auction.
This was to allow any party that feels
uncertain about valuing its rights
commercially to have them allocated
directly. This guideline did not
preclude interested parties with longterm rights from participating in the
auction if they choose.
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Comments
General Support for Guideline (7)
362. Many commenters express strong
support for proposed guideline (7).118
For example, APPA states that the longterm firm transmission right allocation
called for under guideline (7) is
appropriate because it comports with
section 217(b)(4) of EPAct 2005. Also,
APPA believes that it at least partially
restores the transmission rights that
APPA members in transmission
organization regions lost when full
LMP-based markets were implemented.
363. NRECA claims that, because load
serving entities pay the largest share of
the existing and future transmission
system costs, they should not have to
bid for the right to use a system that
they paid for and that was planned and
built to serve their needs. However,
NRECA states that it is not opposed to
the use of auctions for residual or
secondary rights and for voluntary
dispositions of primary rights,
consistent with current practice. PG&E
recommends that, if any additional
long-term firm transmission rights
remain after the initial allocation
process, such firm transmission rights
should be made available for auction.
PG&E states that, as experience with
long-term firm transmission rights in
LMP environments shows them to be
functioning in an efficient and
predictable manner, auctions could
increasingly be used for long-term firm
transmission right issuance without
detracting from the goals of EPAct 2005.
Public Power Council states that it does
not endorse the use of an auction, but
if an auction is used to allocate scarce
rights, the Commission should permit
only entities with a preference to
participate in the auction in order to
ensure that the price is not artificially
inflated.
364. Central Vermont states that
guideline (7) must be modified to
provide parties with certainty
concerning the value of their directlyallocated long-term transmission rights.
Specifically, parties will not have
certainty about the value of their longterm transmission rights if the initial
allocation of rights also includes
exposure to negative congestion charges
between points, which are unavoidable
and very difficult to assess in value.
365. In reply comments, APPA and
New England Public Systems disagree
with the contention of some
commenters that FPA section 217(b)(4)
118 See, e.g., Xcel, PJM, TAPS, SoCal Edison,
SMUD, Alcoa, PJM–PPC Members, APPA, AEP,
BPA, NRECA, PG&E, New England Public Systems,
Public Power Council, Ameren, TANC, CMUA and
Central Vermont.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
permits the Commission to make a load
serving entity’s ability to obtain a longterm firm transmission right, or the
financial equivalent thereof, turn on
whether the load serving entity is
willing to pay more than other bidders.
New England Public Systems states that
transmission customers were not
required to outbid other potential
customers for firm transmission rights
under the Order No. 888 regime in place
prior to the advent of LMP-based
markets, and load serving entities with
service obligations met through longterm power supply arrangements should
not be required to do so now.
366. TAPS notes that Midwest ISO
argues that it would be difficult for a
transmission organization to value the
congestion hedge provided by a longterm right. TAPS argues that, by
advocating allocation through auction, a
transmission organization essentially
assigns this same task to load serving
entities that have far less information or
control over the planning and expansion
process.
Support for the Use of an Auction
367. Many commenters express strong
support for the use of an auction
mechanism for allocating long-term firm
transmission rights and object to what
they view as guideline (7)’s prohibition
on using an auction for that purpose.119
For example, IPL states that the
guidelines should not preclude rights
allocated by auction because
transmission organizations and
stakeholders should be allowed to
determine whether an auction
mechanism is the most equitable and
efficient way to allocate rights. IPL
contends that EPAct 2005 does not
preclude auctions, does not specify a
particular allocation methodology, and
does not require that load serving
entities receive rights for free. IPL
argues that EPAct 2005 merely requires
that load serving entities be able to
acquire and use such rights and
therefore the guidelines should not
eliminate this flexibility. Also, Cinergy
states that it strongly opposes guideline
(7), claiming that there is no support in
FPA section 217 for the notion that
auctions should be foreclosed. Cinergy
argues that auctions are the best
available means of determining the
initial value of transmission rights and
it makes no sense for the Commission to
exempt load serving entities from
participating in them when that is the
mechanism other market participants
use. In Cinergy’s view, guideline (7)
119 See, e.g., Cinergy, DC Energy, Coral Power,
Morgan Stanley, EEI, IPL, DTE, National Grid,
SDG&E, Midwest ISO, AF&PA, EPSA and Reliant.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
ensures that no market mechanism will
be available to address the unduly
discriminatory free-rider problem
caused when only some load serving
entities obtain long-term rights.
368. DC Energy believes that, to the
maximum extent possible, market-based
solutions should be used to allocate and
to establish prices for firm transmission
rights. DC Energy asserts that robust
auctions will maximize the value of firm
transmission rights and increase overall
market efficiency by allowing the
parties that value firm transmission
rights the most to acquire them. It
believes that transmission users that
acquire firm transmission rights outside
of an auction process may pay less for
firm transmission rights than those who
would bid on them, resulting in a
decrease in auction revenues which
translates into an increase in
transmission costs. Furthermore, DC
Energy argues that transmission
customers that hold firm transmission
rights without having to pay fair market
value for them will not utilize
generation resources in the most
efficient manner and will cause a suboptimal dispatch due to indifference
over supply options.
369. In reply to APPA’s argument that
longer-term transactions should be
favored because they will send the
proper economic signals for
transmission facilities construction
based on long-term power supply
commitments, Coral Power argues that
appropriate economic signals cannot be
established under a system that does not
auction rights on a non-discriminatory
basis. It claims that transmission paths
that are valued highly in successive
short-term auctions are candidates for
upgrades or for other solutions that
might be more economic, such as the
siting of local generation. Coral Power
argues that a system that combines
preferential allocations in long-term
firm transmission rights with short-term
competitive auctions for available
transmission rights will only distort the
market.
370. Morgan Stanley states that the
Final Rule must not allow for the
allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights without the use of
an auction mechanism based on sound
market principles and uniform credit
eligibility standards. Morgan Stanley
argues that allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights through a nondiscriminatory auction, for terms that
can be liquidly traded, will generate
needed price signals for market
participants. Conversely, in Morgan
Stanley’s view, preferential allocation of
long-term firm transmission rights likely
would: (1) Reduce the amount of
PO 00000
Frm 00041
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43603
capacity available to the market; (2)
result in a barrier to competitive entry;
(3) cause price signals to be blunted; (4)
facilitate hoarding, and (5) create an
increased bias in favor of regulatory
outcomes as opposed to a market-based
solution.
371. DTE recommends that, once
auction revenue rights or long-term firm
transmission rights are allocated to
market participants, the regional
stakeholder process should determine
under what future conditions, if any,
long-term firm transmission rights may
be auctioned or traded. It states that this
is a long-term market development issue
that will be unique to each region.
372. National Grid states that, to the
extent that there are uncertainties as to
a customer’s ability to obtain such rights
in an auction, the regions can address
that concern through consideration of
rights of first refusal or other auction
rules. National Grid adds that nothing
prevents the holder of auction revenue
rights from bidding for the underlying
transmission rights and/or trading the
auction revenue rights for transmission
rights. National Grid states that, in
keeping with the Commission’s general
approach to allow regions the flexibility
to achieve consensus, the Commission
should strike guideline (7) or revise it to
allow for the possibility of mandatory
auctions and the assignment of auction
revenue rights if the regions deem these
features to be appropriate.
373. EPSA states that in markets with
allocation of auction revenue rights or
similar rights, regions may choose to
continue to allocate such rights without
the use of an auction. However, EPSA
states that auction revenue rights are not
the same as financial transmission rights
and stakeholders may or may not
include them in long-term firm
transmission right programs. EPSA
submits that the guidelines should be
clear on what they assume will be
included as baseline requirements or
elements for the rules that will underpin
all long-term firm transmission right
programs in organized markets, and
should not preclude a region from
requiring an auction process to
transparently value all firm
transmission rights, including long-term
firm transmission rights. AEP states that
a load serving entity should always have
the right to directly convert auction
revenue rights into firm transmission
rights through the auction process, and
would be comfortable with such a
conversion taking place outside of the
auction process.
374. SDG&E states that load serving
entities that have both long-term and
short-term power supply agreements
have ‘‘reasonable needs,’’ and the
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43604
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
statute does not value the ‘‘needs’’ of
one more than the other. SDG&E
believes firm transmission right
auctions are useful because they allow
all load serving entities to seek whatever
mix of firm transmission rights they
believe would he most valuable in terms
of hedging their power supply
portfolios, thereby enhancing the load
serving entity’s attractiveness to
potential loads. AF&PA recommends
that, in the absence of permitting
auctions, the Commission should
clearly provide guidance as to the
appropriate methodology for
determining the value of such long-term
hedges.
375. Reliant proposes that guideline
(7) be modified to state: ‘‘Guideline (7):
The initial allocation of the long-term
firm transmission rights shall provide
for a non-discriminatory and
transparent auction but not require
recipients to sell their rights into that
auction.’’ APPA, however, states that it
opposes this language because it is too
vague.
ISO–NE’s Auction Mechanism
376. ISO–NE strongly urges the
Commission to provide transmission
organizations and their stakeholders
with the flexibility to consider
allocating long-term firm transmission
rights by auction, consistent with
existing New England practices. ISO–NE
argues that the economic benefits of
auction-based allocation are well
understood and have been accepted by
the Commission in its orders on New
England’s current market design and in
other proceedings. According to ISO–
NE, entities such as PJM that initially
allocated firm transmission rights
directly to load have shifted to an
auction-based allocation for compelling
reasons. ISO–NE adds that, if the
Commission were to preclude an
allocation by auction, it is unclear how
the long-term firm transmission right
acquired by a load serving entity
auction revenue right holder would be
valued.
377. NEPOOL states that a
requirement that long-term firm
transmission rights be directly allocated
to load serving entities has the potential
to be especially disruptive to an
organized market such as in New
England, where there is a mature
auction mechanism in place that
allocates one hundred percent of the
firm transmission rights. According to
NEPOOL, that same auction mechanism
could be used to allocate long-term firm
transmission rights, along with all other
firm transmission rights, while still
ensuring that load serving entities are
able to acquire the long-term firm
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
transmission rights they need. This
protection of load serving entities could
be assured, for example, through a tiebreaker mechanism, under which, if a
load serving entity with a long-term
commitment and another market
participant are bidding the same price
for a long-term firm transmission right,
the load serving entity would have
priority and would get the long-term
firm transmission right. NEPOOL states
that, in New England, load serving
entities receive a direct allocation of
auction revenue rights and would be
able to use their auction revenue right
revenues to bid into the auction for
long-term firm transmission rights, thus
providing them the ability, combined
with a tie-breaker mechanism, to
acquire the long-term firm transmission
rights they need. Also, Morgan Stanley
states that it supports this direct
allocation of auction revenue rights so
long as such direct allocation remains
independent from the allocation of longterm firm transmission rights.
378. New England Public Systems
counters that the auction revenue right/
firm transmission right structure in New
England is inadequate to hedge
congestion risk and is not equivalent to
firm transmission even on a short-term
basis; thus, simply extending the term of
such products cannot satisfy the
statute’s requirements. According to
New England Public Systems, most
auction revenue rights in New England
are allocated among congestion-paying
load serving entities on a zonal load
ratio share basis. In effect, each such
load serving entity is paid the auction
clearing price of an average firm
transmission right in the zone times the
ratio of its peak load to the zonal peak
load. New England Public Systems
argues that there is no assurance that
revenues thus received will be sufficient
to enable the load serving entity to
acquire a specific firm transmission
right across a particularly congested
path. New England Public Systems
asserts that auction revenue rights that
(a) do not necessarily cover the cost of
transmission congestion at a specific
location, and (b) cannot be converted
directly to long-term firm transmission
rights that do hedge the risk of
transmission congestion at a specific
location are not the ‘‘equivalent’’ of the
firm transmission rights that section
217(b)(4) requires.
379. Also, New England Public
Systems states that an auction revenue
right in itself is not the financial
equivalent of a firm transmission right,
because auction revenue right revenues
generally are socialized and distributed
on the basis of zonal load ratio share.
According to New England Public
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Systems, if a load serving entity is
outbid for a valuable firm transmission
right, it receives only a fraction of the
auction revenue generated by the
winning bid yet remains exposed to
congestion along the associated path.
New England Public Systems states that,
aside from the socialization issue, even
path-specific long-term auction revenue
rights could leave their holders exposed
to significant congestion costs unless
there is a right to convert long-term
auction revenue rights to long-term firm
transmission rights.
380. Finally, in reply comments, New
England Public Systems notes that ISO
New England argues that entities such
as PJM that initially allocated firm
transmission rights directly to load have
shifted to an auction-based allocation
for compelling reasons. However, New
England Public Systems contends that
PJM’s auction is not the exclusive
means of acquiring firm transmission
rights in that region. It notes that PJM
permits self-scheduling of firm
transmission rights (in essence, allowing
an auction revenue right holder to
convert its auction revenue right into an
firm transmission right) under some
circumstances, but requires that the selfscheduled firm transmission right have
exactly the same source and sink points
as the auction revenue right. According
to New England Public Systems, these
aspects of PJM’s existing system for
allocation of short-term transmission
rights fatally undercut ISO New
England’s attempt to rely on the PJM
precedent as support for extending the
New England approach (which lacks
direct conversion rights) to long-term
firm transmission rights.
NYISO’s Auction Mechanism
381. NYISO argues that the guideline
(7) proposal does not apply to it because
it has already engaged in an allocation
process that assigned the rights to
transmission congestion contract
auction revenues to the New York
transmission owners. NYISO claims that
the same allocation would apply to any
longer-term transmission congestion
contracts that are issued as a result of
this proceeding. NYISO states that its
transmission congestion contract
auction and allocation rules have
already been approved by the
Commission and are grandfathered
under section 217(c) of the FPA.
Therefore, according to NYISO, it does
not appear that Proposed guideline (7)
is at odds with existing NYISO rules.
NYISO states that, in any event, the
Commission should clarify that
Proposed guideline (7) is not intended
to discourage auctions for long-term
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
firm transmission rights beyond the
initial allocation of revenue rights.
382. In response to NYISO, NYAPP
states that section 217(c) of EPAct 2005
does not serve to ‘‘grandfather’’ any
RTO allocation mechanisms under
section 217(b)(4), only subsections
(b)(1), (b)(2), and (b)(3). The
Commission’s authority to modify a
transmission organization’s current
methods for allocation of transmission
rights is specifically preserved for the
implementation of section 217(b)(4). In
NYAPP’s view, NYISO should still have
to comply with guideline (7).
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
PJM’s Auction Mechanism
383. Reliant states that any allocation
of long-term rights should include a
transparent auction process that allows
participants to evaluate the value of
such rights, and that the existing PJM
auction revenue rights process is a good
market example that meets the varied
needs of all market participants.
384. Strategic Energy argues that any
allocation of transmission hedges
should be provided via auction revenue
right, with the option, but not the
obligation, to convert the auction
revenue right to a firm transmission
right on a concurrent source/sink path,
as is the current PJM practice. Strategic
Energy claims that the auction revenue
right facilitates load migrations and the
equitable migration of the value of
transmission hedges with the load.
However, Strategic Energy states that its
support of the auction revenue right/
firm transmission right allocation and
auction model is mitigated by concern
that initial allocation of auction revenue
rights should not be provided to longterm uses to the detriment of short-term
uses, such as annual or shorter-term
hedging frequently employed by
competitive retail suppliers.
Commission Conclusion
385. We will adopt guideline (7) as
proposed in the NOPR. However, as we
explain below, we clarify that guideline
(7) does not preclude a transmission
organization from using an auction to
allocate long-term firm transmission
rights; it only precludes requiring a load
serving entity to submit a winning bid
in an auction in order to acquire longterm firm transmission rights.
386. The Commission agrees with
commenters such as APPA, NRECA and
CMUA that argue that load serving
entities that are obligated to pay the
embedded costs of the transmission
system should be able to receive an
equitable share of long-term firm
transmission rights without having to
submit a competitive bid for those
rights. As APPA points out, guideline
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
(7) provides the load serving entity with
transmission rights that are more akin to
long-term network and point-to-point
service rights of Order No. 888 than to
the short-term rights offered in today’s
organized electricity markets. Also, the
Commission does not interpret EPAct
2005 as requiring the use of an auction
to allocate long-term firm transmission
rights, or as preventing the Commission
from modifying the allocation method
currently used by any transmission
organization. As we have noted
elsewhere in this preamble, section
217(b)(4) of the FPA is not included in
the list of subsections that section 217(c)
states shall not affect existing or future
transmission organization allocation
methodologies.
387. Nevertheless, the Commission
agrees with those commenters that point
out the many benefits that auctions can
bring to the allocation process. As DC
Energy notes, auctions can maximize
the value of transmission rights and
increase overall market efficiency by
allowing the parties that value firm
transmission rights the most to acquire
them. Also, as Coral Power notes,
transmission paths that are valued
highly in successive short-term auctions
are candidates for upgrades or for other
solutions that might be more economic,
such as the siting of local generation.
We note, however, that some of these
commenters interpret guideline (7) as
precluding the use of an auction to
allocate long-term firm transmission
rights. For example, Cinergy asserts that
guideline (7) ensures that no market
mechanism will be available. Further,
Cinergy states that there is no support
in FPA section 217 for the notion that
auctions should be foreclosed and that
it makes no sense for the Commission to
exempt load serving entities from
participating in them when that is the
mechanism other market participants
use.
388. The Commission clarifies that we
do not intend for guideline (7) to
foreclose all transmission right auctions.
Indeed, the Commission believes that an
auction can be an integral part of a
process for the fair and efficient
allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights that also satisfies the
fundamental requirement of guideline
(7). For example, one such allocation
process is the method now used by PJM
to allocate annual firm transmission
rights. As noted by New England Public
Systems, PJM uses a process that first
allocates auction revenue rights to load
serving entities and then allows each
load serving entity the option to convert
its auction revenue rights directly into
annual firm transmission rights with
identical sources and sinks. In effect,
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43605
each load serving entity in PJM may, at
its option, bid the value of its auction
revenue rights into the auction as a
‘‘price-taker’’ knowing that it will win
the bid for the firm transmission rights
that correspond to the sources and sinks
of its respective auction revenue rights.
As a price-taker, the load serving entity
will not know in advance the price it
must pay for the firm transmission
rights that it acquires, but it is secure in
the knowledge that the value of its
auction revenue rights will cover
exactly the cost of the firm transmission
rights. Such a process could be readily
adapted to the allocation of long-term
firm transmission rights.
389. The principal advantage of this
approach is that, consistent with
guideline (7), it allows the load serving
entity to obtain its long-term firm
transmission rights without having to
submit an explicit price bid in an
auction, yet at the same time it exposes
the load serving entity to a competitive
auction price signal that will promote
efficient-decision making. Of course, as
long as the load serving entity desires
long-term firm transmission rights with
the same source and sink points as its
allocated auction revenue rights, it may
simply bid the value of those auction
revenue rights into the auction and
receive those rights. However, because it
is exposed to the auction price signal,
the load serving entity acquires
information that may cause it to adopt
a different bidding strategy in
subsequent auctions. For example, if the
auction clearing price for the long-term
firm transmission rights that correspond
to a load serving entity’s auction
revenue rights is very high, while the
clearing price for other long-term firm
transmission rights is low, the load
serving entity may determine that it
would prefer to submit an explicit price
bid for the lower-priced rights and
forego the opportunity to convert its
auction revenue rights into the
corresponding long-term firm
transmission rights. In this way, the
load serving entity obtains valuable,
albeit lower-priced, rights and also
receives auction revenues equal to the
difference between the value of its
auction revenue rights and the total
amount it must pay for the lower-priced
rights. In addition, the higher-priced
rights that correspond to the load
serving entity’s auction revenue rights
are now made available to other auction
participants that value them more
highly, thus achieving the goal
identified by DC Energy.
390. In this regard, we note that DC
Energy is concerned that transmission
customers that obtain firm transmission
rights without having to pay fair market
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43606
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
value for them will not utilize
generation resources in the most
efficient manner, and Coral Power
argues that this could result in a highly
inefficient generation siting decision.
Similarly, Morgan Stanley is concerned
that guideline (7) will lead to
competitive entry barriers, hoarding and
blunted price signals. We disagree. Even
when a load serving entity holds
auction revenue rights with a direct
conversion right, it can be expected to
behave in an economically rational
manner because it always has an
incentive to forego its conversion right
if it stands to gain financially from
submitting a price bid for alternative
rights in the long-term firm transmission
rights auction.
391. EPSA notes that in markets with
allocation of auction revenue rights,
regions may choose to continue to
allocate such rights without the use of
an auction. However, EPSA states that
auction revenue rights are not the same
as firm transmission rights and wants
the guidelines to be clear on what
elements must be included in all longterm firm transmission rights programs.
Also, Strategic Energy states that initial
allocation of auction revenue rights
should not be provided to long-term
uses to the detriment of short-term uses.
Although the Commission believes that
allocation methods that combine a
direct allocation of auction revenue
rights with a transmission rights auction
offer many advantages, we will not
prescribe here the process by which a
transmission organization must allocate
auction revenue rights, or ultimately
long-term firm transmission rights, to a
load serving entity or other market
participant. We recognize that, today,
transmission organizations use a variety
of allocation methods, but no one
method has emerged as being clearly
superior to all others. We, therefore, will
provide each transmission organization
and its stakeholders with the flexibility
to propose an approach that meets
regional needs and satisfies each of the
guidelines in this Final Rule, subject to
Commission approval.
392. A number of comments were
directed specifically at the auction
mechanisms currently used by ISO-NE
and NYISO. Based on the comments of
New England Public Systems, it appears
that the allocation process now used by
ISO-NE does not permit a direct
conversion of auction revenue rights
into corresponding firm transmission
rights. If so, the process does not meet
the requirements of guideline (7) for
allocating long-term firm transmission
rights and must be modified. Also, with
respect to NYISO’s auction mechanism,
NYAPP is correct in noting that section
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
217(c) of EPAct 2005 does not prevent
the Commission from modifying the
allocation processes of any transmission
organization under section 217(b)(4).
Therefore, contrary to the view of
NYISO, guideline (7) applies to its
allocation process in the same way that
it applies to the allocation processes of
all other transmission organizations.
393. Finally, Central Vermont states
that guideline (7) must be modified to
provide market participants with
certainty concerning the value of their
long-term transmission rights if the
initial allocation of rights includes
exposure to negative congestion charges.
We will not modify guideline (7) to
address this concern. However, we will
provide the transmission organization
and its stakeholders with flexibility to
include, within the proposed allocation
process, specific rules to address such
matters should they arise.
Guideline (8)—Balance Adverse
Economic Impacts
394. As proposed in the NOPR,
guideline (8) stated that the allocation of
long-term firm transmission rights
should balance any adverse economic
impact between participants receiving
and not receiving the right. The NOPR
noted that, to the extent that the
capacity of the transmission system is
encumbered by entities holding longterm firm transmission rights, entities
that prefer short-term transmission
rights, such as load serving entities
operating in retail states, will have
fewer rights available to them than they
have under current annual allocation
schemes. In addition, to the extent
awarded long-term rights become
infeasible due to unforeseen changes in
the physical properties of the
transmission system, the payment
obligations to holders of long-term firm
transmission rights would have to be
funded by others.
395. The NOPR stated that, in general,
it should be possible for the
transmission organization to introduce
long-term firm transmission rights in a
way that balances economic impacts, for
example, by placing a limit on the
amount of system capacity that is
available to support long-term rights.
Also, the NOPR stated that if the longterm right is an ‘‘option’’ right that
encumbers more system capacity than
an ‘‘obligation’’ right, the holder of such
a right could be required to assume
greater cost responsibility.
396. The NOPR noted that the
transmission organization might provide
for a secondary market or auction that
would provide an opportunity for
transmission customers to obtain longterm rights on either a long-term or
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
short-term basis from those holding
long-term rights. The NOPR proposed to
allow the transmission organization
flexibility to propose methods for
pricing transmission rights and related
services that are appropriate for its
region and are the product of a
stakeholder process.
397. The NOPR asked for comments
on any measures that should be adopted
to protect against the impacts of a
decision by a holder of an ‘‘obligation’’
right to leave the transmission
organization when the feasibility of
other transmission rights depend on that
holder’s counterflows.
Comments
General Comments on the Need for
Guideline (8)
398. Several commenters argue that
the principles embodied in guideline (8)
are important, and some believe that
they should be the primary focus in the
allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights.120 AF&PA states
that principles embodied in guideline
(8) should be seen as controlling the
application of all the other guidelines.
AF&PA states that the Commission must
not return to a pre-OATT world where
certain entities claim the exclusive right
to use the transmission system for their
benefit, and all competing usage is
viewed as incremental or marginal.
399. Midwest ISO states that the
nature and scope of financial hedging
instruments for users of long-term
transmission ultimately should be
defined in well-functioning markets.
Midwest ISO argues that any mandate
that transmission organizations provide
such instruments must carefully balance
the potential benefits to some market
participants against the potential costs
to other market participants. IPL states
that, as proposed, the guidelines are not
balanced and do not meet this standard.
400. NYISO believes that it is possible
that long-term firm transmission rights
can be introduced without inequities,
particularly if transmission
organizations are permitted to retain
existing systems without major changes.
CMUA also believes the equity concerns
raised in guideline (8) may in practice
not prove difficult to reconcile.
Nevertheless, CMUA is concerned that
transmission organizations and certain
stakeholders might attempt to use
guideline (8) to effectively eviscerate
long-term firm transmission rights, in
violation of FPA section 217(b)(4).
120 See, e.g., AF&PA, EPSA, Midwest ISO, IPL,
NYISO, CMUA and National Grid.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Comments Suggesting That Guideline
(8) Is Not Needed
405. Alcoa states that it is not clear
whether the Commission intends that
there will be a redistribution of costs
and benefits between those entities
holding firm transmission rights and
those that do not.
401. Some commenters argue that
guideline (8) is not needed or requires
clarification.121 For example, BPA
suggests that this guideline be deleted
from the Final Rule, as the issues it
raises can be addressed under other
guidelines. Furthermore, BPA states that
it is not appropriate to require
transmission organizations to balance
the adverse economic impacts between
those receiving the right and those that
do not.
402. TAPS states that guideline (8)
should be removed. However, if some
‘‘reasonableness’’ guideline is retained,
it should be reworded as ‘‘avoidance of
undue impacts,’’ to recognize that some
impacts are ‘‘due’’ and reasonable. In
addition, TAPS is concerned that
guideline (8) establishes criteria that are
not called for by section 217(b)(4) and
could be used to undermine Congress’s
clear directive. In response, Midwest
ISO agrees with TAPS that section
217(b)(4) does not expressly require that
a balance be struck between those that
receive long-term firm transmission
rights and those that do not. However,
Midwest ISO claims that section
217(b)(4) also does not expressly require
the Commission to provide load serving
entities unlimited and fully-funded
long-term firm transmission rights to
hedge congestion costs associated with
long-term power supply arrangements.
403. In addition, TAPS notes that the
NOPR describes as an adverse impact
the potential that the long-term rights
will result in the availability of fewer
rights for entities that prefer short-term
rights. TAPS states that this has always
been the case under the Order 888
OATT. TAPS claims that a transmission
provider is not entitled to turn down a
long-term firm request to keep capacity
available for those who wish to make
short-term or non-firm use of the
system.
404. Industrial Consumers argues that,
if the total available rights (short- and
long-term) are insufficient to meet the
needs of end-use customers (an
indication that the owners of the
transmission system are mismanaging
the maintenance and planning of their
assets) it may be necessary to ration the
rights, but still preserve the preference
to holders of long-term rights. In
Industrial Consumers’ view, the real
issue here is not that economic interests
are not appropriately balanced, but that
transmission owners have abrogated
their responsibilities.
Importance of Protecting the Status Quo
408. Some commenters recommend
that guideline (8) be implemented in a
way that protects existing short-term
rights holders and market rules.122 For
example, Constellation states that the
Commission should not adopt policies
that harm the existing competitive
wholesale and retail markets.
Constellation asserts that a policy that
articulates a preference for long-term
supply arrangements is such a policy.
Constellation states that, if the
Commission decides to unwind the
current, competitive market structure by
setting aside existing transmission
capability for long-term uses, then
guideline (8) must be a critical factor in
121 See, e.g., BPA, TAPS, Industrial Consumers
and Alcoa.
122 See, e.g., Coral Power, Constellation, Strategic
Energy, and EEI.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
Conflicts Between Guideline (8) and
Other Guidelines
406. Cinergy states that it completely
agrees with guideline (8), but claims
that this guideline is not achievable in
light of the other guidelines proposed by
the Commission. Midwest ISO
maintains that, while the
implementation of this guideline is
essential, the implementation would be
difficult because it is in direct conflict
with the requirement for full funding of
long-term firm transmission rights
(guideline (2)) and the priority extended
to long-term firm transmission right
holders (guideline (5)). NYISO states
that the same problem applies to
proposed guideline (4) to the extent that
the Commission interprets it to require
non-market based renewal rights for
long-term transmission rights. National
Grid recommends that the Commission
treat these conflicting guidelines more
as goals rather than minimum
requirements.
Need for Regional Flexibility in the
Application of Guideline (8)
407. SoCal Edison states that, because
issues of balance are intricate and
require both judgment and familiarity
with the local market and system issues,
the Commission should leave the
specifics of such a balance to the
transmission organizations. Similarly,
IPL urges the Commission to allow the
transmission organization the flexibility
to develop certain long-term
transmission rights parameters such as
pricing and availability.
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43607
the Commission’s approval of any longterm firm transmission right proposal so
that the Commission can ensure that
there are no adverse impacts on other
market participants. In Constellation’s
view, any long-term firm transmission
right proposal must identify harm that
will be caused by its implementation,
such as the reduction of hedging
opportunities for shorter-term uses, and
propose mitigation for such adverse
consequences.
409. EEI argues that since load serving
entities and other transmission
customers in PJM, Midwest ISO, NYISO
and ISO–NE have made supply and
investment decisions in reliance on
Commission-approved allocations, the
Commission should not reverse its prior
decisions by changing these allocations
and market structures. EEI argues that it
would be disruptive and unfair to
require any changes to the underlying
agreements and understandings that
formed the design of these four
transmission organizations. In response,
APPA argues that the equities cut both
ways. APPA claims that during the
transition to ‘‘Day Two’’ transmission
organization markets, many public
power load serving entities lost valuable
Order No. 888 OATT and grandfathered
transmission rights, leaving their power
supply arrangements subject to
unanticipated transmission congestion
charges. According to APPA, these
entities have since been attempting to
conduct business under a construct of
locational marginal pricing and firm
transmission rights that is essentially
hostile to their business model. In
addition, APPA argues that Congress
contemplated that making long-term
firm transmission rights available to
load serving entities under section
217(b)(4) might indeed require revisiting
the prior allocation of firm transmission
rights in RTO regions. Further, NRECA
claims that Congress has already issued
the mandate and determined the
appropriate balance of costs and
benefits; it has not authorized the
Commission or transmission
organizations to undertake a cost/benefit
analysis of whether the statutory
mandate is justified or the balance
struck by statute appropriate.
Issues Regarding Cost Shifting
410. Several commenters express
concern that requiring transmission
organizations to make available longterm firm transmission rights could
harm market performance and shift
costs unnecessarily or unfairly among
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43608
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
market participants.123 For example,
Strategic Energy submits that
introduction of multi-year rights will
cause cost shifts if holders of such rights
are allocated congestion risk coverage
greater than that accorded to other
parties.
411. BP Energy states that to ensure
the balancing of any adverse economic
impacts, guideline (8) should be
modified to state explicitly that the
allocation of incremental long-term firm
transmission rights to one party can not
result in subsidization of those rights by
other parties, i.e., there can be no
significant shifting of generation
redispatch costs or fixed transmission
costs as the result of new supply
arrangements entered into by load
serving entities receiving long-term
rights to parties not subject to those
agreements.
412. BP Energy also argues that, if
parties seeking long-term rights are able
to shift congestion costs to others, they
will have no disincentive to enter into
supply arrangements that reduce
(because of their relative location on the
grid) the absolute amount of
transmission rights that an organized
market can allocate while maintaining
revenue sufficiency. Similarly, in ISO–
NE’s view, allocation of free long-term
firm transmission rights to load serving
entities versus an auction of long-term
firm transmission rights to generators,
traders and other entities creates equity
and distortion issues.
413. Some commenters address the
problem of balancing adverse impacts in
light of the NOPR’s proposed
requirement for full funding of longterm firm transmission rights.124 For
example, IPL argues that the adverse
economic impact of a long-term
financial transmission rights allocation
stems in large part from the shortfall
funding obligation. IPL urges the
Commission not to require entities to
share this obligation to the extent those
entities do not receive benefits from the
allocation and do not bear direct
responsibility for congestion costs.
According to Midwest ISO, the
Commission’s proposal to guarantee
load serving entities priority of existing
transmission capacity with fully-funded
long-term firm transmission rights for
the entire capacity of their supply
contracts may result in significant costs
on other market participants, increase
the costs of transmission organization
membership, and significantly reduce
the availability of firm transmission
123 See, e.g., EEI, Strategic Energy, Suez Energy,
BP Energy, ISO–NE and Midwest ISO.
124 See, e.g., IPL, PJM, PJM Public Power
Coalition and BP Energy.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
rights to meet short-term firm
transmission right holders’ requests.
Pricing and Cost Responsibility for
Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights
414. Some commenters state that they
agree with the NOPR’s statement that
‘‘to the extent that the long-term right
relieves the holder of the obligation to
pay congestion costs, the value of that
congestion hedge should be reflected in
the price of the long-term right, insofar
as possible.’’ 125 In this regard, BP
Energy argues that two scenarios are
apparent. First, where the same or
electrically similar (mutually exclusive)
rights are sought by multiple parties, the
party willing to pay the most might
acquire them through a competitive
process, such as an auction.
Alternatively, the party seeking such
long-term rights can, consistent with
guideline (3), pay for the necessary
‘‘transmission upgrades and
expansions’’ to receive the ‘‘rights made
feasible’’ by that expenditure. In the
case where existing capacity is sought
by multiple parties, and auctions are not
available, BP Energy argues that the
only equitable and reasonable method of
capacity allocation, consistent with the
Commission’s holding that ‘‘the value of
that congestion hedge should be
reflected in the price of the long-term
right’’ is to honor existing rights
allocations, while expediting capacity
upgrades and expansions to meet needs
exceeding available transmission
capacity.
415. Midwest ISO states that the
notion that the price of the long-term
right should reflect the value of the
congestion hedge is problematic because
it is unclear how transmission
organizations would reflect the value of
the congestion hedge in the price of the
long-term firm transmission right.
Midwest ISO argues that the best way to
determine the value of such a
congestion hedge would be through a
market mechanism such as an auction,
which would be inconsistent with
guideline (7).
416. Some commenters argue that
long-term firm transmission rights
holders should not, in general, be
allocated a cost differential.126 Ameren
states that load serving entities that are
allocated long-term firm transmission
rights are providing the steady, longterm revenue stream to transmission
owners that allows them to invest in
upgrades and expansions to the system,
and thus, should not be assessed a
premium charge. TAPS states that if
e.g., Midwest TOs and BP Energy.
e.g., TANC, NRECA, TAPS, Ameren,
CMUA, NCPA and APPA.
PO 00000
125 See,
126 See,
Frm 00046
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
long-term rights are limited to base load
and renewable resources for which the
grid should be planned in any event, it
is unreasonable to impose an additional
cost burden on long-term right holders.
TAPS states that the Commission
should make clear that it will not accept
proposals that would defeat the purpose
of long-term rights by pricing them out
of the reach of load serving entities.
Also, TAPS supports the Commission’s
proposal to leave the pricing associated
with long-term rights to RTO
compliance filings. However, TAPS
believes that the transmission
organization compliance process will go
more smoothly if the Final Rule
includes a new guideline providing that
the pricing of long-term rights should
support and not frustrate section
217(b)(4)’s directive to enable load
serving entities to secure such rights.
417. With respect to firm transmission
right options, Strategic Energy states
that to the extent that firm transmission
right options can be accommodated,
they should be offered, subject to the
recognition that such products
encumber substantially more system
capacity than obligations, and therefore
should be valued accordingly. Also,
TAPS and OMS agree that those
wanting long-term firm transmission
right options should be willing to pay
for the additional cost of providing such
an instrument. OMS submits that one
possible way of doing this is to first
allocate long-term firm transmission
right obligations, and then allow those
receiving long-term firm transmission
right obligations the option of
converting the firm transmission right
obligation to a firm transmission right
option.
Proposals to Limit the Adverse Impact
of Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights
418. NSTAR and CAISO argue that
some of the concerns the Commission
raises under guideline (8) can be
addressed by making long-term firm
transmmission rights identical to shortterm rights in every way but duration.
In NSTAR’s view, section 217(b)(4) does
not require differences between longterm firm transmission right
characteristics and firm transmission
right/auction revenue right
characteristics except for duration.
NSTAR argues that failure to harmonize
any future long-term firm transmission
rights with the current market and
transmission tariff would be disruptive
of existing arrangements and destabilize
power supply planning.
419. Some commenters argue that the
balance that the Commission seeks
under guideline (8) can be achieved
with the aid of secondary auctions and
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
other market mechanisms.127 For
example, NRECA recommends using a
voluntary secondary auction in order to
allow reconfiguration of long-term firm
transmission rights. NRECA states that
this would allow shorter term rights that
are unused to be auctioned to load
serving entities without longer term
service obligations, which could
mitigate any potential adverse effect
experienced by those that do not receive
long-term firm transmission rights.
420. Several commenters suggest that
adverse impacts associated with the
introduction of long-term firm
transmission rights can be reduced by
limiting the amount of transmission
capacity that is made available for those
rights.128 For example, Reliant supports
placing a limit on the amount of system
capacity available to support long-term
rights as this would reduce the
likelihood that the rights may become
infeasible, which in turn would reduce
the possibility that the burden of
funding the allocated rights would
eventually fall onto other market
participants.
421. APPA states that it is amenable
to discussion of mechanisms that
transmission organizations could use to
minimize to the extent possible the
adverse impacts of long-term firm
transmission right allocations on the
firm transmission rights available to
other transmission customers. APPA
proposes therefore that the Commission
reformulate guideline (8) to reflect this
approach: ‘‘Long-term firm transmission
rights should be allocated in a manner
that minimizes, to the extent possible,
adverse impacts on participants not
receiving such rights.’’ APPA states that
any such mechanisms would have to be
specific to each transmission
organization and could include some
combination of: (1) Restrictions on the
overall portion of the existing
transmission system that could be
allocated to support long-term firm
transmission rights and (2) limits on
each load serving entity’s own long-term
firm transmission right holdings, based
on some percentage of the load serving
entity’s own loads.
422. In response, PJM states that the
APPA rewrite of guideline (8) may go
too far and potentially eliminate the
ability of transmission organizations to
preserve their existing priorities for
short-term firm transmission rights with
the new long-term firm transmission
rights. As a result, PJM asks that
127 See, e.g., NRECA, SMUD, Midwest ISO,
Reliant, AF&PA, Strategic Energy and BPA.
128 See, e.g., Reliant, Kentucky PSC, PJM, Santa
Clara, SoCal Edison, AEP, CAISO, ISO–NE,
Midwest ISO, OMS, NU, PG&E, APPA, TAPS and
Wisconsin Electric.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
guideline (8) not be amended. Rather,
PJM urges the Commission to examine
whether the appropriate balance called
for in guideline (8) has been addressed
in individual transmission organization
filings.
Rules for Withdrawing From
Membership in an RTO
423. With regard to whether measures
are needed to address events such as the
departure of long-term firm
transmission right holders from the
transmission organization, APPA states
that the transmission organization will
likely have to handle such events on a
case-by-case basis. Ameren states that
covering the impact of exit on long-term
firm transmission rights may require
additional language in transmission
organization tariffs and/or members’
agreements.
424. TAPS argues that transmission
dependent utilities have no control over
whether their host transmission owner
seeks to withdraw from an RTO or
switch RTOs. In TAPS’s view,
transmission dependent utilities
therefore should be held harmless from
such decisions. If, upon withdrawal, the
host transmission owner reverts to a
physical rights regime, TAPS states that
the transmission dependent utility’s
long-term right should be adapted to
that regimen. If the host transmission
owner switches transmission
organizations, TAPS states that the new
transmission organization should be
required to honor the transmission
dependent utilities’ long-term rights.
Commission Conclusion
425. The Commission will delete
guideline (8) in the Final Rule.
Commenters make a strong case that
guideline (8) is not needed. Our
principal purpose in including
guideline (8) was to ensure that the
requirements of section 217(b)(4) of the
FPA are implemented in a manner that
is just and reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory, which is our legal duty
under the FPA. Neither we nor, in our
view, Congress intended to require longterm firm transmission right proposals
to meet a different or higher standard.
Indeed, as noted by APPA, TAPS,
CMUA and others, opponents of longterm firm transmission rights could
attempt to interpret guideline (8) in a
way that would effectively eviscerate
long-term firm transmission right
proposals. Also, we agree with BPA’s
statement that the issues raised by
guideline (8) can be effectively
addressed through the application of
other guidelines. Nevertheless, while we
are deleting guideline (8), we believe
that meeting our obligation under the
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43609
FPA to ensure that rates are just and
reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory will still require that we
assess the impact of long-term rights
proposals on those not receiving the
rights.
426. We note that several commenters
overstate the adverse effects of
introducing long-term firm transmission
rights, particularly in light of the revised
guidelines that we are adopting herein.
For example, Midwest ISO states that
providing load serving entities with
priority to receive, from existing
transmission capacity, fully-funded
long-term firm transmission rights to
support the full amount of their supply
contracts may place significant costs on
other market participants, increase the
costs of transmission organization
membership, and significantly reduce
the availability of firm transmission
rights to meet short-term firm
transmission right holders’ requests.
However, by (1) expanding the priority
of guideline (5) to all load serving
entities and (2) allowing limits to be
placed on the amount of existing
transmission system capacity that is
made available for long-term firm
transmission rights, the Commission is
taking important steps in this Final Rule
to reduce, if not eliminate, problems
associated with cost shifting and the
reduced availability of short-term
transmission rights to load serving
entities that prefer them. As we
explained in the discussion of guideline
(5) above, as a result of these changes,
the transmission organization should be
able to design a comprehensive
allocation process for short-term and
long-term transmission rights that
largely replicates the equitable
distribution of short-term rights that
occurred in the past for those entities
that still want them. Indeed, to the
extent that long-term rights and shortterm rights have the same properties
except for duration, as suggested by
NSTAR and CAISO, even the fullfunding requirement should not lead to
significant cost shifting among classes of
rights holders if all rights holders are
given similar full-funding
protections.129 In any event, as noted by
Reliant, placing a limit on the amount
of system capacity available to support
long-term rights will reduce the
likelihood that the rights may become
infeasible, which in turn will reduce the
possibility that the funding burden will
eventually fall onto other market
participants.
427. Also, BP Energy states that if
long-term rights holders are able to shift
129 See the discussion of these issues under
guideline (2), above.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43610
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
generation redispatch and other
congestion costs to others, they will
have no incentive to enter into supply
arrangements that maximize the number
of transmission rights that can be
allocated while maintaining revenue
sufficiency. Similarly, ISO–NE argues
that allocation of free long-term firm
transmission rights to load serving
entities versus an auction of such rights
to all entities creates equity and
distortion issues. We disagree. Well
designed long-term firm transmission
rights should result in no significant
equity issues or economic distortions.
As noted, cost shifting and equity issues
are largely addressed by our revisions to
guideline (5). As to economic
distortions, these largely can be avoided
by making firm transmission rights
available through a process that
combines a direct allocation of auction
revenue rights with an auction of firm
transmission rights, as explained in our
discussion of guideline (7). Also, as
NRECA notes, the availability of a
voluntary secondary auction would
allow reconfiguration of long-term firm
transmission rights and make available
shorter-term rights to entities that were
not able to obtain long-term firm
transmission rights.
428. Finally, with regard to whether
measures need to be adopted to address
events such as the departure of longterm firm transmission right holders
from the transmission organization, the
Commission agrees with APPA and
Ameren that issues related to the
withdrawal of an entity from a
transmission organization are best
addressed in the transmission
organization’s members’ agreement’s
terms for exit and should be reviewed
on a case-by-case basis. As Ameren
notes, the addition of long-term firm
transmission rights may require
additional language in transmission
organization tariffs or members’
agreements. The Commission
encourages transmission organizations
and their stakeholders to consider the
need for such language and to include
any proposed revisions in their
compliance filings.
F. Transmission Planning and
Expansion
429. In the NOPR, the Commission
noted that section 217(b)(4) of the FPA
requires the Commission to exercise its
authority ‘‘in a manner that facilitates
the planning and expansion of
transmission facilities to meet the
reasonable needs of load serving entities
to satisfy the service obligations of the
load serving entities.’’ Accordingly, the
Commission proposed to require that
transmission organizations ensure that
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
the long-term firm transmission rights
they offer remain viable and are not
modified or curtailed over their entire
term. The Commission noted that,
because the proposed guidelines would
require that transmission organizations
guarantee the financial coverage of the
long-term firm transmission rights,
transmission organizations would need
to have an effective planning regime in
place, and might need to expand the
system to ensure that the long-term firm
transmission rights can be
accommodated over their entire term.
430. The Commission stated that it
would not propose specific planning
and expansion procedures in the NOPR,
but rather each transmission
organization and its stakeholders should
develop appropriate methods for
ensuring that long-term firm
transmission rights are supported by
adequate planning and expansion
procedures. The Commission
encouraged transmission organizations
to propose such procedures as part of
their filings in compliance with the
Final Rule, and stated that it will
consider them in light of the direction
in section 217(b)(4) of the FPA that the
Commission exercise its FPA authority
to facilitate the planning and expansion
of transmission facilities. The
Commission asked for comments on
whether it should require that
transmission organizations file their
transmission planning and expansion
procedures and specific plans. It also
sought comment on whether,
alternatively, the Commission should
require that transmission organizations
file the plans and procedures for
informational purposes to allow the
Commission to monitor their adequacy
for ensuring the viability of the longterm firm transmission rights.
431. The Commission noted that the
pro forma OATT adopted by the
Commission in Order No. 888 requires
transmission providers to expand
capacity, if necessary, to satisfy the
needs of network and point-to-point
transmission service customers. The
Commission also noted that its Notice of
Inquiry concerning the pro forma OATT
sought responses from interested parties
on specific questions relating to this
requirement, including: (1) whether this
provision has met transmission
customers’ needs, and (2) whether
public utility transmission providers
have fulfilled these obligations.130 In the
NOPR, the Commission asked for
comments addressing these questions in
Transmission Organization’s
Responsibility for Transmission
Planning
435. A number of comments address
the role of the transmission organization
in the transmission planning process.132
AEP believes that the transmission
organization should conduct regional
transmission planning and be the
primary driver of providing long-term
connections between economic power
sources and load centers. AEP argues
that the transmission organization
should provide for a mechanism that
links the granting of any long-term
transmission rights and the construction
of transmission to make those rights
feasible. Constellation asserts that this
will provide a mechanism to ensure that
130 Since the issuance of the NOPR in this
proceeding, the Commission has issued a NOPR
concerning revisions of the Order No. 888 OATT in
Docket Nos. RM05–25–000 and RM05–17–000.
131 See, e.g., AEP, Constellation, Redding and
MSATs.
132 See, e.g., AEP, Constellation, TAPS, Midwest,
TDUs and NCPA.
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
the specific context of the transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets that are the subject of this
rulemaking.
432. Finally, in the NOPR, the
Commission asked for comments on
whether the definition of native load
service obligation in section 1233 of
EPAct 2005 is the same as the approach
the Commission took in Order No. 888,
with particular emphasis on how the
native load preference has been applied
in the organized electricity markets that
are the subject of this rulemaking.
Comments
Need for Transmission Planning—
General
433. A number of commenters assert
that the need for long-term transmission
planning and expansion goes well
beyond the need to provide for longterm firm transmission rights.131 AEP
states that proper planning of a robust
transmission system is imperative to
meeting long-term economic and
reliability needs, which is a much bigger
issue than hedging long-term
transmission risks.
434. NCPA recommends that all
transmission planning processes
include the following: (1) Needs defined
on a comparable basis, based on
analysis of all projected load serving
entity loads and resources, and
published, consistently-applied
standards; (2) opportunities for all TDUs
to participate in the joint planning
process, and to validate and gain
confidence in transmission planning
models; (3) colorblind selection of plans
to be implemented; (4) a dispute
resolution process; and (5) plans and
inputs that are transparent.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
the system is not overbuilt to ensure
long-term firm transmission rights.
436. TAPS believes that transmission
organizations must be held accountable
for planning and expanding the grid to
ensure load-specific deliverability
sufficient to support the continued
simultaneous feasibility of all long-term
rights issued, taking into account other
rights that require preservation. TAPS
states that RTOs (and transmission
owners, if RTOs aggregate the
transmission plans of their member
transmission owners) should be
required to have an inclusive joint
planning process that meets the needs of
TDUs on the same basis that TOs’
similar needs are met. In TAPS’s view,
to meet the needs of new organized
electricity markets, RTOs must be able
to deliver crucial transmission
upgrades, not just assemble
consolidated lists of projects.
Transmission Planning To
Accommodate Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights
437. A number of commenters stress
that the transmission organization’s
planning and expansion protocols must
take into consideration the long-term
firm transmission rights that are
issued.133 For example, Ameren submits
that the parameters of long-term firm
transmission right elections must be
embedded in the RTO’s planning
process. Ameren states that this will
require the RTO to identify for its
transmission owners the term of each
long-term power supply arrangement
associated with each firm transmission
right on each transmission owner’s
system, so that the expansion plans the
transmission owners submit to the RTO
incorporate any expansions necessitated
by the long-term supply arrangements.
Ameren asserts that ensuring load
serving entities’ priority access to longterm firm transmission rights will give
load serving entities the same rights and
ability to ‘‘lock in’’ long-term firm
transmission to support their long-term
power supply arrangements that they
enjoyed under Order No. 888 before
RTOs and RTOs’ organized electricity
markets. MSATs states that it agrees
with such observations but also believes
that long-term firm transmission rights
should not become the principal driver
of the transmission planning and
expansion process.
438. MSATs argues that
distinguishing between reliability and
economic projects in the context of
transmission planning is inconsistent
with the concept of long-term firm
133 See, e.g., OMS, Ameren, SMUD, EPSA, IPL,
PJM, MSATs, Midwest ISO, NRECA and TAPS.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
transmission rights. MSATs asserts that
firm transmission rights are economic
rights that are intended to insulate
holders from the economic
consequences of congestion, and
building and maintaining the
transmission capacity needed to honor
multi-year firm transmission rights may
or may not be necessary to meet
applicable reliability criteria. MSATs
adds that, conversely, planning and
constructing transmission facilities
based solely on reliability criteria may
not ensure the transmission capacity
needed to honor long-term firm
transmission rights. Thus, MSATs states
that the distinction between economic
and reliability projects is directly at
odds with the type of transmission
planning that is needed to honor longterm firm transmission rights.
439. Similarly, IPL states that the
Commission should separately address
physical delivery risk and financial
risks stemming from congestion charges
because the two risks are substantially
different and efforts to address these
risks that do not distinguish between
them are likely to be counterproductive.
IPL states that the Commission should
not attempt to use financial
transmission rights to provide an
incentive toward investment by
transmission owners because the
Commission’s goal of ensuring that
necessary upgrades are performed is
better addressed separately from
congestion charge hedging. In IPL’s
view, congestion charge hedging is the
singular legitimate purpose of a
financial transmission rights
mechanism.
440. IPL states that the Commission
and the transmission organizations are
undertaking a number of efforts to
ensure that delivery risk is mitigated
through proper transmission planning
and expansion. IPL states that these
efforts, which have no direct connection
with allocations of long-term financial
transmission rights, are the appropriate
fora in which to address mitigating
delivery risk by making sure adequate
transmission infrastructure is available
to meet the reasonable delivery needs of
load serving entities and others.
441. Midwest ISO states that
transmission upgrades and expansion
should be dictated by the transmission
planning studies that ensure
deliverability of generation to serve
load, not participants’ firm transmission
right nominations. However, in
response, APPA states that long-term
firm transmission rights are intended to
ensure exactly that: deliverability of
generation to serve load on a specific
resource-to-load basis, and at a
reasonably ascertainable transmission
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43611
cost that is not subject to volatile
transmission congestion. According to
APPA, since transmission planning and
long-term firm transmission rights are
both intended to ensure deliverability of
generation to load, it is absolutely
appropriate to take account of long-term
firm transmission rights in an RTO’s
transmission planning process. In
addition, NRECA states that it is
impossible to square Midwest ISO’s
comment with the terms of FPA section
217(b)(4). According to NRECA, if that
section means anything, it is that public
utility transmission providers must plan
and expand the transmission grid so as
to enable load serving entities to obtain
long-term firm transmission rights.
EPAct 2005 Requirements for
Transmission Planning and Expansion
442. Some commenters argue that
EPAct 2005 requires the Commission to
adopt specific transmission planning
procedures as part of this rulemaking or
another proceeding.134 For example,
National Grid claims that EPAct 2005
section 1233(b) requires the
Commission to address how it intends
to implement section FPA 217(b)(4) and
not just the portions of FPA section 217
(b)(4) that speak to long-term
transmission rights. To fulfill its
statutory obligation, National Grid
submits that the Commission should
adopt a set of clear guidelines for
transmission planning and expansion
along with its proposed guidelines for
long-term transmission rights. If the
Commission does not adopt planning
guidelines in its Final Rule in this
proceeding, National Grid recommends
that the Commission state how it
intends to discharge its obligations
under the first sentence of FPA section
217(b)(4) and EPAct 2005 section
1233(b) to assure adequate planning.
According to NRECA, FPA section
217(b)(4) does not merely require the
provision of long-term firm transmission
rights; it requires the Commission to
facilitate the planning and expansion of
transmission facilities. In this regard,
NRECA states that public utility
transmission providers should be
required to conduct open joint
transmission planning processes that
allow all load serving entities to
participate on a comparable basis to
public utility transmission providers.
NRECA adds that these planning
processes should accommodate both
reliability and economic needs.
443. In its reply comments, MSATs
states that the Commission should
identify key attributes that should be
134 See, e.g., National Grid, NRECA, MSATs,
TANC and Reliant.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43612
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
incorporated into the RTO’s planning
process.
444. Reliant recommends that the
Commission undertake a parallel
rulemaking to address the long-term
needs of customers outside of organized
markets. If the Commission chooses not
to proceed with such a separate
rulemaking, Reliant urges the
Commission to utilize Docket No.
RM05–25–000, Preventing Undue
Discrimination and Preference in
Transmission Services.
445. Taking a contrary view, NYISO
states that section 217(b)(4) should not
be interpreted as mandating the
overhaul of existing ISO/RTO
transmission planning and expansion
processes. NYISO notes that, with
respect to New York, the Commission
has approved a robust and transparent
planning process that calls for
stakeholder participation and input, and
the NYISO’s Comprehensive Reliability
Planning Process is undertaking its first
comprehensive review of the reliability
needs of the New York bulk power
system. NYISO asserts that making
wholesale changes to this process would
be premature and unnecessary.
Requirement for Filing Transmission
Plans
446. Some commenters state that the
Commission should require
transmission organizations to file their
transmission planning protocols and
their most recent transmission plans as
part of their compliance filings in this
proceeding.135 APPA states that they
should be required to explain in their
long-term firm transmission right filings
how those protocols and plans will take
into account the need to accommodate
the allocated long-term firm
transmission rights for their full terms
and will ensure the construction of any
transmission facilities required to
support them. APPA argues that if the
Commission believes that this showing
is not persuasive, then the transmission
organization should be required to take
action to revise its transmission
planning protocol. However, APPA
recommends that such action be
undertaken in a separate proceeding so
as not to delay initial implementation of
long-term firm transmission rights. Also,
TAPS and NCPA submit that for those
transmission organizations that use
transmission owner transmission plans
as inputs for the transmission
organization’s plan, the transmission
owners should be required to make a
similar filing. However, in response to
APPA, MSATs states that the type of
135 See,
e.g., APPA, TAPS, NCPA, BPA and
SMUD.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
review contemplated by the APPA
would be administratively burdensome
and unlikely to prove beneficial. Also,
Midwest ISO notes that such plans are
already available as public documents.
447. BPA expresses support for the
principle that transmission
organizations should file their planning
and expansion procedures and specific
plans for informational purposes with
the Commission. BPA believes that
doing so helps assure that information
on planning is widely available to
interested persons. However, BPA states
that Commission approval of such
informational filings should not be
required.
448. Many commenters argue strongly
that the Commission should not impose
additional filing requirements on the
transmission organizations.136 For
example, SDG&E argues that unless
Commission-jurisdictional entities have
an opportunity to review the similar
plans and procedures of nonjurisdictional transmission entities, the
latter entities could obtain an unfair
competitive advantage over the former
entities. Moreover, SDG&E states that
transmission planning is resourceintensive, and the effort required to
plan, site, design and build new
transmission is enormous. SDG&E
asserts that the resources allocated to
those efforts should not be diverted to
further regulatory review that is not
proven to be needed to ensure the
viability of long-term firm transmission
rights associated with the planned
transmission lines.
449. ISO–NE views a requirement to
file its system expansion plans as a
significant departure from past
Commission practice. ISO–NE argues
that similar types of highly technical
studies generally have not been subject
to a filing requirement. For example,
ISO–NE points out that although
interconnection studies represent a type
of study akin to the core of system
expansion plans, they have never been
filed with the Commission.
450. PJM states that it currently is
required to file the proposed cost
allocations resulting from its regional
transmission expansion plan with the
Commission, and the proposed
allocations are subject to Commission
approval. PJM recommends that the
Commission not require filing of the
entire plan absent being presented with
a legitimate issue. In reply comments,
NRECA urges the Commission to require
that such plans be filed, even if only for
informational purposes, to monitor
136 See, e.g., SDG&E, MSATs, Midwest ISO, IPL,
NYISO, CAISO, SoCal Edison, PG&E, ISO–NE and
PJM.
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
compliance with the Final Rule in this
proceeding and section 217(b)(4).
Meeting Native Load Requirements
451. In response to the request for
comments in the NOPR on whether the
definition of native load service
obligation in section 1233 of EPAct 2005
is the same as the approach the
Commission took in Order No. 888,
some commenters addressed the subject
of how that preference has been applied
in organized electricity markets.137
APPA states that application of the
native load preference set out in new
FPA sections 217(b)(1) and (2) to the
various RTO regions is governed by new
FPA sections 217(c) and (f). APPA
asserts that these sections were hardfought and carefully negotiated as to
each RTO region, and states that the
Commission should honor the
legislative compromises embodied in
those sections.
452. PJM states that, within PJM,
native load receives a preference to
system capacity by virtue of being
allocated auction revenue rights, which
can be converted to firm transmission
rights at the discretion of the holder of
transmission rights, Midwest TOs
believes the NOPR may result in
reduced firm transmission rights for
native load customers who receive firm
transmission rights in the annual
assignment process currently used by
the Midwest ISO. Midwest TOs
recommends that the Commission
clarify that it intends for all load serving
entities, including vertically integrated
utilities that are just using existing
generation to serve their loads, to be
eligible to seek long-term firm
transmission rights. According to
Midwest TOs, to do otherwise would be
to discriminate against the native load
of vertically integrated companies.
Commission Conclusion
453. The Commission will require
that each transmission organization
with an organized electricity market
implement a transmission system
planning process that will accommodate
the long-term transmission rights that
are awarded by ensuring that they
remain feasible over their entire term.
FPA section 217(b)(4) requires the
Commission to exercise its authority
under the FPA in a manner that
facilitates the planning and expansion
of transmission facilities, and to enable
load serving entities to obtain long-term
firm transmission rights. To implement
that section in a transmission
organization with an organized
137 See, e.g., APPA, PJM, AEP, Midwest TOs and
Santa Clara.
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
electricity market, as required by section
1233(b) of EPAct 2005, we believe that
the transmission organization must plan
its system to ensure that allocated or
awarded long-term firm transmission
rights are feasible.138 FPA section
217(b)(4) itself, by including both the
requirement to facilitate planning and
expansion and the requirement to
provide long-term transmission rights,
supports the Commission’s authority to
impose this requirement. Moreover,
given the full funding requirement of
guideline 2, appropriate planning for
long-term firm transmission rights is
essential to ensure that any charges to
other market participants to cover
revenue shortfalls do not become unjust,
unreasonable or unduly discriminatory.
454. To implement this requirement,
we will require each transmission
organization to include in its
compliance filing an explicit statement
of how its planning and expansion
practices will take into account the need
to accommodate allocated or awarded
long-term firm transmission rights for
their full terms, including the
construction of transmission facilities
(as well as a basis for allocating cost
responsibility) that may be needed to
support them. We will also require that
each transmission organization make its
planning and expansion practices and
procedures publicly available, including
both the actual plans and any
underlying information used to develop
the plans. Also, any holder of long-term
firm transmission rights that believes
that the transmission organization is not
fulfilling its obligation to ensure the
adequacy of the long-term firm
transmission rights over their full term
can seek relief through the transmission
organization’s internal complaint
procedures or by filing a complaint with
the Commission. The Commission will
address problems on a case-by-case
basis, and if necessary, require the
transmission organization to revise its
planning and expansion practices to
better accommodate long-term firm
transmission rights.
455. The Commission notes that, to
meet the requirements that we are
imposing here, as well as the fullfunding requirements of guideline (2), a
transmission organization must plan its
system such that a long-term firm
transmission right, once awarded,
remains viable throughout its full term
without requiring the long-term firm
transmission right holder to pay directly
for any additional transmission
upgrades that may be required to
138 This is not to suggest that we are requiring any
‘‘obligation to build’’ or other obligation that does
not already exist under Order No. 888.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
maintain the feasibility of the right over
its term. Accordingly, the transmission
organization must include, along with
upgrades needed for system reliability,
any upgrades needed to support the
long-term firm transmission right over
its full term in its base plan for system
expansion. While this may require
changes in the transmission
organization’s planning protocols, we
disagree with MSATs that it requires the
transmission organization to draw a
distinction between economic and
reliability projects that is incompatible
with transmission planning. Indeed, the
transmission organization may choose
to make no distinction between
reliability upgrades and those needed to
maintain the feasibility of long-term
firm transmission rights.
456. In addition, we note that when
a transmission customer enters into a
long-term power supply arrangement
and is willing to pay for any
transmission expansion or upgrades
which may be necessary in order to
make long-term firm transmission rights
feasible over the entire term of the
contract, that expansion or upgrade
must be incorporated into the
transmission organization’s planning
process. This will require that the
expansion plans that transmission
owners submit to the transmission
organization incorporate any expansions
necessitated by such long-term supply
arrangements. We believe that it is
important for the regional planning
process to take account of any upgrades
or expansions of the transmission
system that may be required to ensure
FTRs needed to support long-term
power supply arrangements are
available.
457. The Commission agrees with
commenters such as NRECA that
observe that FPA section 217(b)(4) does
not merely require the provision of longterm firm transmission rights; it requires
the Commission to facilitate the
planning and expansion of transmission
facilities. However, the Commission is
considering issues concerning its
broader mandate to exercise its FPA
authority to facilitate planning and
expansion (which applies to all regions)
to Docket No. RM05–25–000, the Order
No. 888 OATT reform rulemaking.
G. Alternative Designs for Long-Term
Firm Transmission Rights
458. We noted in the NOPR that FPA
Section 217(b)(4) recognizes that there
may be alternative designs for long-term
firm transmission rights. The NOPR
noted that for most transmission
organizations, the most straightforward
design for long-term transmission rights
is likely to be an extension of their
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43613
existing design for allocation of auction
revenue rights or FTRs, perhaps with
some modifications of certain rules and
procedures (such as creditworthiness
standards and transmission planning).
The NOPR discussed, and we did not
preclude, alternative designs for such
rights, including departures from the
existing market designs.
Comments
Clarification of Terms
459. Several commenters argue that
the Commission is unclear about its use
of the terms ‘‘firm transmission rights’’
and ‘‘financial transmission rights.’’ IPL
states that section 217(b)(4) uses the
term ‘‘firm’’ to mean physical rights,
and financial to refer to purely financial
rights. In contrast, the NOPR appears to
use the terms interchangeably. IPL states
that ‘‘resolution of this confusion is
critical because the NOPR dually
implies that it is (a) proposing certain
modifications to an existing financial
transmission rights paradigm, and (b)
that it is imposing a physical rights
structure in organized electricity
markets where that concept is anathema
to [LMP].’’ 139 National Grid also states
that the NOPR is unclear as to the status
of whether firm means solely physical
rights and asks for clarification that the
Commission is not implying a
preference for physical rights. Reliant
asks that the Commission clarify that by
firm transmission rights, it does not
mean physical rights, but rather that
financial rights in LMP markets are
equivalent to firm rights.
460. In contrast, TANC argues that the
firm transmission rights cited in section
217(b)(4) were intended to be physical
rights and that even though the statute
recognizes financial transmission rights,
Congress sought to determine that it
favors another methodology, namely
physical transmission rights.
Physical versus Financial Rights
461. In addition, a number of
commenters also had views on whether
long-term firm transmission rights
should be physical or financial rights.
Most commenters assumed that the
rights under consideration in most
organized markets are financial rights
without having to make the requirement
explicit, as reflected in their comments
on auction revenue rights and FTRs.
However, a number of parties, including
CAISO, EEI, IPL, National Grid,
NEPOOL, NU, NSTAR, NYISO, Reliant,
SDG&E and SoCal Edison asked that the
Commission be more explicit that the
rights under consideration should be
financial rights only, in particular in
139 Reply
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
Comments of IPL at 5.
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43614
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
markets that currently have financial
rights.
462. These commenters argue that
physical rights would have deleterious
effects on the LMP markets. For
example, ISO–NE argues that
introducing physical scheduling rights
would create an economic loss for the
region because of less efficient dispatch
of resources, significant administrative
burdens for system users and the ISO,
and new seams with the ISO’s region.
National Grid observes that holders of
physical rights would be insulated from
redispatch costs, which would be
inequitably shifted to holders of
financial rights or to transmission
owners.
463. PG&E argues that while it
supported a financial rights model for
CAISO, the approach of the Final Rule
should allow, but not require,
alternative designs to recognize that
stakeholders in different markets may
prefer different cost-benefit balances.
PJM similarly urges that the Final Rule
clarify that respective regions should
determine the nature of the transmission
right, whether physical or financial.
464. Several commenters supporting
financial rights are also concerned that
the Final Rule does not establish a mix
of physical and financial rights.140 NU
argues that a ‘‘carve-out’’ for physical
long-term rights would reduce available
capacity for shorter-term FTRs and
distort the auction market for them.
NYISO argues that ‘‘financial rights
models can bring as much certainty as
physical rights while allowing for a
fuller and more efficient utilitization of
transmission capacity.’’ 141 PJM, while
supporting regional flexibility to design
physical or financial rights, urges that,
with the exception of approved
grandfathered agreements, there should
not be a mix of physical and financial
rights as a bifurcated system would be
unworkable. EEI cautions that a move
toward long-term physical rights for
some market participants would
undermine the competitive markets.
465. NYTOs suggested that the
Commission establish a regulatory
definition of long-term transmission
right that clarifies that such a right
encompasses both physical and
financial rights to the use of the
transmission system. Such a definition
should state that in organized electricity
markets, market participants have the
physical right to schedule but then
receive financial rights to hedge
congestion charges.
140 These include BP Energy, ISO–NE, NU,
NYISO, and PJM.
141 Reply Comments of NYISO at 7.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
466. Several parties, including
LADWP, Modesto, NRECA, Redding,
SMUD, Santa Clara, and TANC, argue
that long-term rights should be physical
rights or rights with some characteristics
of physical rights. For example, LADWP
states that the rights should have certain
characteristics, including the following:
the right to schedule power up to the
holder’s share of the transmission
facility rating; the ability to market nonscheduled transmission capacity to
others; a fixed charge responsibility not
otherwise dependent on operating
conditions; losses provided for as in the
project agreement; and not subject to
rules set by non-participants. LADWP
argues that these assurances along with
proper planning and investment are
necessary to provide the certainty
necessary for transmission investment.
467. Santa Clara states that no
financial instrument can achieve a truly
effective hedge against congestion costs,
and that only explicit physical rights
(denominated solely in terms of MW of
capacity) can secure a load serving
entity against transmission costs. Santa
Clara thus proposes that long-term firm
transmission rights are physical rights.
SMUD argues that physical rights
coupled with resale and assignment
rights (akin to the gas pipeline open
access model) could capture most of the
efficiencies of the financial rights/LMP
model. In the west, Redding and SMUD
argue that CAISO’s pending
implementation of a financial rights
market make it the only entity in the
region to use that model and will create
seams that diminish trade with the rest
of the region.
468. Santa Clara and TANC argue that
physical transmission rights that mirror
OATT rights have more stable pricing
and allow holders to hedge the risk of
fluctuating congestion charges. Hence,
they will facilitate planning and
construction of new generation facilities
and other long-term supply
arrangements.
469. In contrast to some comments
noted above, several supporters of
physical rights argued that systems that
mix physical and financial rights are
necessary. LADWP supports the coexistence of financial and physical
rights, such as the CAISO’s MRTU
proposal to reserve capacity on its
interties for Existing Transmission
Contracts and Transmission Ownership
Rights. LADWP also proposes that
holders of such rights would be
insulated from congestion costs when
prices reverse direction. TANC argues
that physical transmission rights of
various types are already accommodated
in several transmission organization
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
markets that have financial rights, for
example, as grandfathered rights.
470. Some commenters noted that in
some organized markets, some degree of
long-term physical rights have already
been grandfathered. Coral Power is
concerned that the scope of
grandfathered rights could be
‘‘needlessly’’ expanded. DC Energy
argues that in New York ISO, such
rights have already accommodated those
with the greatest contractual rights to
long-term transmission service.
Alternative Types of Financial Rights
471. Several commenters, including
Allegheny, Constellation, EEI, Kentucky
PSC, and PG&E, stress that FTR option
rights should not be available in the
allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights. This is because
such option rights encumber too much
transmission capacity, resulting in a
reduction in the quantity of rights
available. Instead, the long-term
transmission rights should be specified
as FTR obligation rights. Some of these
commenters would be willing to
accommodate options at a later date.
NEPOOL states that the Commission
should neither require nor preclude
options.
472. APPA agrees that FTR option
rights would likely be unworkable, but
proposes instead its concept of a
‘‘hybrid long-term transmission right’’
that would only provide congestion
revenues in the hours that the holder of
the right schedules transmission and up
to the quantity scheduled. Such a right
would also not require obligation
payments in the event that the prices at
the locations specified in the right
change direction (that is, a higher price
at the injection point than at the
withdrawal point). TAPS proposes that
long-term rights are ‘‘dispatchcontingent’’ FTRs, which would only
pay revenues when the generation
resource is dispatched. In all other
hours, the FTR would not pay revenues,
nor require obligation payments.
Commission Conclusion
Clarification of Definitions and Choice
Between Financial and Physical Rights
473. As noted elsewhere in the Final
Rule, we interpret Section 217(b)(4) to
require that load serving entities be able
to obtain long-term firm rights, whether
as physical rights or as equivalent
financial rights. In the discussion of
guideline (2), we interpreted the
firmness requirement in the financial
rights context to include a fixed (MW)
quantity over the life of the right and
stability in the revenue stream from the
right through full funding. This roughly
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
parallels the quantity and financial
stability of long-term physical
transmission contracts. Because we
believe that under our guidelines
financial rights are as firm as physical
rights outside organized electricity
markets, we have used the terms firm
and financial interchangeably at times.
We have not used the term firm to imply
a preference for physical rights.
474. We will not require that longterm firm transmission rights in
organized electricity markets be
physical or financial rights. However,
we also will not require that
transmission organizations with existing
or approved designs for financial
transmission rights create a new longterm physical right, such as an Order
No. 888 network service right, upon
request of a load serving entity. Instead,
as discussed in our guidelines, we have
sought to provide guarantees of
financial ‘‘firmness’’ alongside the
existing physical firmness of
transmission scheduling in the
organized electricity markets (that is,
decreased frequency of TLRs).
Alternative Types of Financial Rights
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
475. While many commenters have
warned against allowing allocation of
long-term option financial rights, no
commenter has requested such rights.
We agree with commenters that
allocation of long-term financial
transmission option rights would
present severe equity problems in most
organized electricity markets. At best, if
all eligible parties requested option
rights, the set of allocated rights would
be greatly reduced compared to an
allocation of obligation rights. An
alternative approach to obtaining
options would be to allocate long-term
auction revenue rights as obligations
and let entities purchase option rights
through an auction.
476. Schedule-contingent or dispatchcontingent financial transmission rights
could present similar equity problems to
options in allocation and, unlike option
FTRs, possibly create poor scheduling
or dispatch incentives.142 These types of
contingent rights could present revenue
adequacy problems because while they
142 A ‘‘contingent’’ financial transmission right for
the purposes of this Final Rule is a right that only
collects revenues or owes payments (corresponding
to the source and sink points and quantities
specified in the right) under certain conditions.
These rights differ from obligation FTRs in the
following ways. A schedule-contingent right would
only be eligible to collect revenues or obliged to
make payments if it was scheduled in the dayahead market of the transmission organization. A
dispatch-contingent right would only be eligible to
collect revenues or obliged to make payments if it
produced energy in real-time (i.e., was dispatched).
For further discussion see, e.g., Comments of TAPS.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
are not paid when they do not schedule
or dispatch, if they are base-load plants
this will likely only take place when the
prices at the injection and withdrawal
locations are reversed. That is, the unit
will not be scheduled when it is needed
to make counterflow payments to
support the revenue adequacy of other
transmission rights. As a result, the
transmission organization would either
have to model the rights as options in
the allocation of transmission rights or
make arbitrary decisions to limit the
quantity of rights it allocates. Further,
dispatch-contingent rights could have
incentives for inefficient dispatch, since
the right is only paid when a source
generator produces output. In that case,
the holder of the right will have less
flexibility to purchase cheaper power
from the spot market in the presence of
congestion because it will lose the
revenues from its rights.
H. Miscellaneous Comments
477. SMUD states that the uncertainty
associated with marginal loss charges is
at least as big a hedging problem as that
posed by congestion charges. SMUD
argues that marginal loss pricing is not
required under the locational marginal
pricing model. CMUA, Santa Clara and
SMUD urge the Commission to direct
that transmission organizations either
eliminate marginal loss charges or offer
transmission customers with long-term
rights the same full hedge against loss
charges as against congestion charges.
Commission Conclusion
478. We do not interpret section
217(b)(4) as addressing marginal loss
charges. Each transmission organization
operating an organized electricity
market has established methods for
refunds of marginal loss surplus based
on stakeholder discussion. We will not
overturn those decisions here.
I. Implementation of the Final Rule and
Compliance Issues
479. In the NOPR, the Commission
proposed to direct each public utility
that is a transmission organization with
an organized electricity market, within
180 days of the publication of a Final
Rule in the Federal Register, to either:
(1) File with the Commission tariff
sheets and rate schedules that make
available long-term firm transmission
rights that are consistent with the
guidelines set forth in section (d) of the
Final Rule; or (2) file with the
Commission an explanation of how its
current tariff and rate schedules already
provide for long-term firm transmission
rights that are consistent with the
guidelines set forth in paragraph (d) of
the Final Rule. We stated our intent that
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43615
during this 180-day period,
transmission organizations subject to
the rule will work with their
stakeholders (through their usual
stakeholder process) to develop a longterm firm transmission right that will
harmonize prevailing market design
with the guidelines set forth in the Final
Rule. For any transmission organization
that is approved by the Commission
after the 180-day time period, the
Commission proposed that the
transmission organization be required to
satisfy the requirements of the Final
Rule prior to commencing operation.
Comments
480. APPA, New England Public
Systems, and Vermont DPS all support
the Commission’s proposed
implementation procedures. New
England Public Systems states that if
any transmission organization
determines that it will not be able to
meet the 180-day timetable, the
Commission should require that it
submit a detailed explanation of the
cause of the delay and a detailed
schedule for completing and submitting
its compliance filing. PG&E supports the
compliance filing timeline, and suggests
that those deadlines be expanded to
address due dates that would follow the
future adoption of market-based
congestion management programs by a
transmission organization. PG&E also
recommends that a parallel rule be
adopted for long-term firm transmission
rights in markets that do not use marketbased congestion management systems.
481. SMUD argues that the
Commission’s proposed compliance
procedures contain an insufficient
directive to ensure timely compliance,
particularly because it would allow
transmission organizations to submit
proposed tariffs with no proposed
effective dates. Accordingly, SMUD
states that the Commission should issue
a Final Rule by August 8, 2006, and
clarify that compliance tariffs and rate
schedules must be effective 60 days
after their filing, to ensure that longterm firm transmission rights are
available within about a year.
482. Several commenters, including
AF&PA, IPL, ISO–NE, NEPOOL and
OMS, argue that the 180-day deadline
proposed in the NOPR for transmission
organizations to make filings in
compliance with the Final Rule is
‘‘unrealistic’’ given the complexity of
the issues involved and the
transmission organizations’ other
ongoing projects. IPL suggests that the
Commission lengthen the time for
stakeholder procedures and compliance
filings to 365 days, followed by an
additional 365-day period during which
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
43616
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
the transmission organizations will
implement their long-term rights
mechanism. IPL also suggests that the
Commission allow transmission
organizations to phase in long-term
rights over time. OMS requests that the
Commission permit transmission
organizations to report on the status of
their stakeholder procedures in 180
days, and then set a specific filing date
for tariff changes based on that status
report.
483. ISO–NE also requests that the
Commission lengthen the 180-day time
period for developing and filing a
proposal to comply with the Final Rule,
stating that a strict requirement to
formulate a long-term firm transmission
right design within that time frame
could present insurmountable
challenges since it is also in the process
of developing other important market
reforms as part of its Wholesale Market
Plan.
484. NYISO states that it will likely be
able to meet the proposed 180-day
deadline, provided the Commission’s
Final Rule clarifies that only limited
changes to the current market design
need to be considered. It explains that
it may need additional time, however, if
the Final Rule requires more
modifications of existing systems. New
York Transmission Owners suggest that
if changes to the NYISO market are
required, the Commission should allow
it to develop a procedure to phase in
such changes to avoid market
disruptions that could affect the
availability of short-term and
intermediate transmission rights.
485. CAISO notes in its initial
comments that it faces unique
challenges in implementing long-term
firm transmission rights because it is in
the process of implementing a complete
market redesign, which includes a
transition to LMP.143 To implement this
redesign by November 2007, CAISO
states that it will be difficult, if not
impossible, to expand the scope of the
initial market design. According to
CAISO, to adopt long-term transmission
rights before the start of the new market
it would be necessary to develop a
‘‘hybrid’’ instrument that could be used
in both the current market and new
market. Developing this instrument, it
states, would divert resources from its
effort to implement the new market.
Accordingly, CAISO asks that it not be
required to implement, prior to the start
of its redesigned market, any ‘‘hybrid’’
long-term transmission rights product.
486. Furthermore, given its current
process and timeline for implementing
143 This proposed market redesign was filed on
February 9, 2006 in Docket No. ER06–615–000.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
the market redesign, CAISO states that
it most likely would not be able to fulfill
the requirements of the Final Rule
under the proposed compliance
schedule. Accordingly, it states that the
Commission should not require it to
have long-term FTRs in place until at
least one year after the start of its new
markets. CAISO notes that its market
participants lack experience with shortterm financial rights. As a result, it
contends that it could not have a
meaningful stakeholder debate on the
design and implementation of long-term
rights, and urges the Commission to
allow it the same opportunity to gain
experience with LMP that other
transmission organizations have had.
Furthermore, it argues that it is
important that market participants have
a sufficient demonstration of the
financial rights they will be able to
receive under the market redesign
before long-term rights are
implemented.144 As a result, CAISO
seeks sufficient time for stakeholder
discussions on alternate designs, and
asks that it not be required to implement
long-term financial rights before having
at least one year of experience with LMP
markets.
487. SoCal Edison, noting the same
concerns regarding the timing of
CAISO’s market redesign, argues that
the Commission should revise its
proposed compliance procedures to
require a transmission organization that
has filed a complete redesign of its
organized electricity market to make a
proposal for implementing long-term
firm transmission rights after the revised
market becomes effective, instead of
within 180 days of the final rule. CPUC
and SDG&E also express concerns with
regard to the timing of CAISO’s
implementation of long-term firm
transmission rights. CPUC agrees with
CAISO that it should be given a period
of time to gain experience with LMP
before implementing long-term rights,
while SDG&E states that the
Commission should, in the Final Rule,
require CAISO to include long-term
rights in its planned second release of
the market redesign.
488. Conversely, CMUA, APPA and
NCPA all suggest that accommodating
long-term rights should be more easily
accomplished in CAISO because it is
not an established LMP market, and that
it would be easier and less expensive to
incorporate long-term rights into the
market design rather than retrofit the
144 CAISO notes that it has conducted studies of
the financial rights allocation, but that a dry run
with market participants under the allocation rules
filed with the Commission would be more accurate.
It does not expect to complete such a dry run before
the first quarter of 2007.
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
market later. Nevertheless, CMUA
opposes blanket application of the 180day timeline to CAISO, and (along with
TANC) urges the Commission to address
CAISO’s implementation schedule for
long-term firm transmission rights as
part of its consideration of CAISO’s
market redesign filing in Docket No.
ER06–615–000.145
489. Several commenters, including
PG&E, SMUD, and Transmission
Agency of Northern California, oppose
CAISO’s request for deferral and argue
that the Final Rule should apply to
California upon its implementation of
LMP as part of its market redesign.
PG&E argues that CAISO’s reasoning
that delaying deferral because it has not
relied on short-term rights for as long as
other transmission organizations
‘‘stands * * * EPAct on its head’’ and
perpetuates the problem driving
Congress to enact section 217(b)(4) of
the FPA and section 1233(b) of EPAct
2005.146 SMUD (and others) note that
CAISO was directed by the Commission
to develop a long-term firm
transmission service more than eight
years ago, and has not yet proposed
such an option (including in its recent
market redesign filing).147 To avoid
further delay, SMUD states that if a
transmission organization cannot
provide a long-term financial
transmission right product within 180
days, it should be required to offer
physical path arrangements until it can
develop a financial product that meets
the requirements of section 217(b)(4)
and the Commission’s guidelines.148
SMUD also asserts that CAISO wrongly
assumes both that implementing longterm rights will cause a delay in the
start of its redesigned markets, and that
there is urgency in implementing the
market redesign.
Commission Conclusion
490. The Commission will adopt the
implementation timetable proposed in
the NOPR. We clarify what we expect
transmission organizations subject to
this Final Rule to file compliance
proposals within 180 days of its
effective date. Specifically, they must
file proposed tariff sheets and rate
schedules that would make available
long-term firm transmission rights that
satisfy each of the guidelines in the
145 APPA
states that it defers to this proposal.
Comments of PG&E at 17.
147 See, e.g., Comments of SMUD at 40–41; Reply
Comments of CMUA at 3, citing Pacific Gas and
Electric Company, et al., 80 FERC ¶ 61,128 at
61,427 (1997).
148 According to SMUD, CAISO can implement
physical long-term rights immediately, and in fact
has done so for the Western Area Power
Administration.
146 Reply
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
Final Rule. We recognize that the
implementation of long-term firm
transmission rights presents difficult
issues, and that significant effort will be
required to file compliance proposals
within 180 days. Congress directed the
Commission to act quickly, however,
requiring in section 1233(b) of EPAct
2005 that we issue this Final Rule
within one year of the legislation’s
passage. We believe that this directive
shows Congress’s intent that long-term
firm transmission rights be made
available as soon as possible.
491. Commenters (particularly ISO–
NE) express concern that implementing
long-term firm transmission rights on
the proposed compliance timetable
could negatively impact the ability of
transmission organizations to complete
work on other initiatives. We encourage
transmission organizations to explore
ways to reorder their priorities to ensure
that this important Congressional
directive is fulfilled. We will not rule
out at this time the possibility that
transmission organizations may seek
permission from the Commission to
reorder its schedule for market design
changes, tariff changes or other projects
that were directed by the Commission.
492. Some commenters suggest that
the Commission permit transmission
organizations to phase in tariff and
market rule changes to introduce longterm firm transmission rights. We
cannot decide here whether any
particular proposal to phase-in longterm firm transmission would be just
and reasonable. We remind
transmission organizations again,
however, that Congress intended the
implementation of long-term firm
transmission rights to occur as soon as
possible. Any proposal to phase-in longterm firm transmission rights will be
considered in light of this statutory
directive.
493. We note that the final regulations
require transmission organizations to
file tariff sheets and rate schedules that
make available long-term firm
transmission rights that satisfy each of
the guidelines within the 180-day
timeframe. While SMUD asks us to
specify that such tariff sheets and rate
schedules be effective 60 days after
filing, we do not believe it would be
appropriate to prescribe effective dates
now. Transmission organizations may
need to synchronize the availability of
long-term firm transmission rights with
their existing allocation schedules. They
may also need to take additional steps,
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:46 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
such as making necessary software or
procedural changes, to implement the
rights after the Commission acts on their
compliance proposals. As a result, we
will consider effective dates on a caseby-case basis, again in light of
Congress’s intent that long-term firm
transmission be implemented as soon as
possible.
494. Additionally, we clarify that for
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets that are
formed after the effective date of this
Final Rule, we intend that such
organizations will provide long-term
firm transmission rights satisfying the
guidelines in the regulations. We have
made revisions to the proposed
regulatory text to clarify that
transmission organizations approved by
the Commission in the future will be
required to satisfy this Final Rule.
495. The Commission will require
that all existing transmission
organizations, including CAISO, make
proposals to comply with the Final Rule
on the same timetable. While we
understand CAISO’s concerns regarding
its pending market redesign efforts, we
cannot address in this rulemaking of
general applicability any possible plans
for the phase-in or delayed
implementation of long-term firm
transmission rights. Even if we could,
CAISO has not provided any timetable
in its comments for implementing longterm firm transmission rights as
required by section 217(b)(4) of the FPA
and section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005.
Therefore, CAISO must work with its
stakeholders to develop and submit a
compliance filing within the timetable
prescribed in this Final Rule, and the
Commission will consider any issues
specific to CAISO or any proposals
offered in its compliance filing for
implementing long-term firm
transmission rights in CAISO. Once
again, we remind transmission
organizations and their stakeholders,
including CAISO, that Congress intends
that the introduction of such rights
occur as soon as possible.
III. Information Collection Statement
496. The Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) regulations require
approval of certain information
collection requirements imposed by
agency rules. Upon approval of a
collection(s) of information, OMB will
assign an OMB control number and an
expiration date. Respondents subject to
the filing requirements of this rule will
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43617
not be penalized for failing to respond
to these collections of information
unless the collections of information
display a valid OMB control number.
This Final Rule amends the
Commission’s regulations to implement
some of the statutory provisions of
section 1233 of EPAct 2005.
Particularly, section 1233 of EPAct 2005
enacts a new section 217 of the FPA.
New section 217(b)(4) requires the
Commission to exercise its authority in
a manner that facilitates the planning
and expansion of transmission facilities
to meet the reasonable needs of load
serving entities to satisfy their service
obligations, and enables load serving
entities to secure long-term firm
transmission rights to meet their service
obligations. Section 1233(b) of EPAct
2005 directs that Commission to, by rule
or order, implement this new provision
in the FPA. This Final Rule requires
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets to either
file tariff sheets making long-term firm
transmission rights available that are
consistent with guidelines established
by the Commission, or to make a filing
explaining how their existing tariffs
already provide long-term firm
transmission rights that are consistent
with the guidelines. Such filings will be
made under Part 35 of the Commission’s
regulations. The information provided
for under Part 35 is identified as FERC–
516.
497. The Commission 149 submitted
these reporting requirements to OMB for
its review and approval under section
3507(d) of the Paperwork Reduction
Act.150 In the NOPR, comments were
solicited on the Commission’s need for
this information, whether the
information will have practical utility,
the accuracy of provided burden
estimates, ways to enhance the quality,
utility, and clarity of the information to
be collected, and any suggested methods
for minimizing the respondent’s burden,
including the use of automated
information techniques. No comments
were received on these issues.
Therefore, the Commission is retaining
the estimates provided in the NOPR.
Burden Estimate: The Public
Reporting burden for the requirements
contained in the Final Rule is as
follows:
149 CFR
150 44
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
1320.13 (2005).
U.S.C. 3507(d) (2000).
01AUR2
43618
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
Number of
respondents
Number of
responses
Hours per
response
Total annual
hours
Transmission Organizations with Organized Electricity Markets ....................
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Data collection FERC–516
6
1
1180
7,080
Total Annual hours for Collection:
(Reporting + recordkeeping, (if
appropriate) = 7,080 hours.
Information Collection Costs: The
Commission seeks comments on the
costs to comply with these
requirements. It has projected the
average annualized cost to be the total
annual hours of 7,080 times $150 =
$1,062,000.
Title: FERC–516 ‘‘Electric Rate
Schedule Filings.’’
Action: Proposed Collections.
OMB Control No: 1902–0096.
Respondents: Business or other for
profit, and/or not for profit institutions.
Frequency of Responses: One time to
initially comply with the rule, and then
on occasion as needed to revise or
modify.
Necessity of the Information: This
Final Rule implements the
Congressional mandate of the Energy
Policy Act of 2005 to make long-term
transmission rights available in
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets. This
mandate addresses an identified need
for transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets to provide
longer-term transmission rights that can
aid load serving entities in financing
long-term power supply arrangements to
meet their service obligations. Making
long-term firm transmission rights
available will also provide increased
certainty regarding the long-term costs
of transmission service in organized
electricity markets. As a result, longterm firm transmission rights will allow
load serving entities to more effectively
plan their power supply portfolios, and
encourage load serving entities and
other participants in organized
electricity markets to make long-term
investments in power supply
arrangements.
Internal review: The Commission has
reviewed the requirements pertaining to
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets and
determined the proposed requirements
are necessary to meet the statutory
provisions of the Energy Policy Act of
2005.
498. These requirements conform to
the Commission’s plan for efficient
information collection, communication
and management within the energy
industry. The Commission has assured
itself, by means of internal review, that
there is specific, objective support for
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
the burden estimates associated with the
information requirements.
499. Interested persons may obtain
information on the reporting
requirements by contacting: Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426
[Attention: Michael Miller, Office of the
Executive Director, Phone: (202) 502–
8415, fax: (202) 273–0873, e-mail:
michael.miller@ferc.gov]. Comments on
the requirements of the Final Rule may
also be sent to the Office of Information
and Regulatory Affairs, Office of
Management and Budget, Washington,
DC 20503 [Attention: Desk Officer for
the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission], e-mail:
oira_submission@omb.eop.gov.
IV. Environmental Analysis
500. The Commission is required to
prepare an Environmental Assessment
or an Environmental Impact Statement
for any action that may have a
significant adverse effect on the human
environment.151 As we stated in the
NOPR, the Commission has
categorically excluded certain actions
from this requirement as not having a
significant effect on the human
environment. Included in the exclusion
are rules that do not substantially
change the effect of legislation.152 This
Final Rule falls within this categorical
exemption because it implements the
requirements of EPAct 2005 relating to
long-term firm transmission rights in
organized electricity markets.
Accordingly, neither an environmental
impact statement nor environmental
assessment is required.
V. Regulatory Flexibility Act
Certification
501. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 153 generally requires a description
and analysis of rules that will have
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities.
Most, if not all, of the transmission
organizations to which the requirements
of this Final Rule apply do not fall
within the definition of small
entities.154 Therefore, the Commission
151 Regulations Implementing the National
Environmental Policy Act, Order No. 486, 52 FR
47897 (Dec. 17, 1987), FERC Stats. & Regs.
Preambles 1986–1990 ¶ 30,783 (1987).
152 18 CFR 380.4(2)(ii) (2005).
153 5 U.S.C. 601–12 (2000).
154 The RFA definition of ‘‘small entity’’ refers to
the definition provided in the Small Business Act,
PO 00000
Frm 00056
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
certifies that this Final Rule will not
have a significant economic impact on
a substantial number of small entities.
Accordingly, no regulatory flexibility
analysis is required.
VI. Document Availability
502. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through the
Commission’s Home Page (https://
www.ferc.gov) and in the Commission’s
Public Reference Room during normal
business hours (8:30 a.m. to 5 p.m.
Eastern time) at 888 First Street, NE.,
Room 2A, Washington, DC 20426.
503. From the Commission’s Home
Page on the Internet, this information is
available in the Commission’s document
management system, eLibrary. The full
text of this document is available on
eLibrary in PDF and Microsoft Word
format for viewing, printing, and/or
downloading. To access this document
in eLibrary, type the docket number
excluding the last three digits of this
document in the docket number field.
504. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the Commission’s Web site
during normal business hours. For
assistance, please contact FERC Online
Support at 1–866–208–3676 (toll free) or
(202) 502–8222 (e-mail at
FERCOnlineSupport@FERC.gov), or the
Public Reference Room at (202) 502–
8371, TTY (202) 502–8659 (e-mail at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov).
VII. Effective Date and Congressional
Notification
505. This Final Rule will be effective
August 31, 2006. The Commission has
determined, with the concurrence of the
Administrator of the Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs of
OMB, that this rule is not a ‘‘major rule’’
as defined in section 351 of the Small
Business Regulatory Enforcement
Fairness Act of 1996.155 The
Commission will submit the Final Rule
to both houses of Congress and the
Government Accountability Office.
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 42
Electric power rates; Electric utilities.
which defines a ‘‘small business concern’’ as a
business that is independently owned and operated
and that is not dominant in its field of operation.
See 15 U.S.C. 632 (2000).
155 See 5 U.S.C. 804(2) (2000).
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
By the Commission.
Magalie R. Salas,
Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission amends Subchapter B,
Chapter I, Title 18, Code of Federal
Regulations, by adding a new part 42 as
follows:
*
*
*
*
*
I
SUBCHAPTER B—REGULATIONS UNDER
THE FEDERAL POWER ACT
*
*
*
*
*
PART 42—LONG-TERM FIRM
TRANSMISSION RIGHTS IN
ORGANIZED ELECTRICITY MARKETS
Sec.
42.1—Requirement that Transmission
Organizations with Organized Electricity
Markets Offer Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights.
Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a–825r and section
217 of the Federal Power Act, 16 U.S.C. 824q.
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
§ 42.1 Requirement that Transmission
Organizations with Organized Electricity
Markets Offer Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights.
(a) Purpose. This section requires a
transmission organization with one or
more organized electricity markets
(administered either by it or by another
entity) to make available long-term firm
transmission rights, pursuant to section
217(b)(4) of the Federal Power Act, that
satisfy each of the guidelines set forth in
paragraph (d) of this section. This
section does not require that a specific
type of long-term firm transmission
right be made available, and is intended
to permit transmission organizations
flexibility in satisfying the guidelines
set forth in paragraph (d) of this section.
(b) Definitions. As used in this
section:
(1) Transmission Organization means
a Regional Transmission Organization,
Independent System Operator,
independent transmission provider, or
other independent transmission
organization finally approved by the
Commission for the operation of
transmission facilities.
(2) Load serving entity means a
distribution utility or an electric utility
that has a service obligation.
(3) Service obligation means a
requirement applicable to, or the
exercise of authority granted to, an
electric utility under Federal, State, or
local law or under long-term contracts
to provide electric service to end-users
or to a distribution utility.
(4) Organized Electricity Market
means an auction-based day ahead and
real time wholesale market where a
single entity receives offers to sell and
bids to buy electric energy and/or
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
ancillary services from multiple sellers
and buyers and determines which sales
and purchases are completed and at
what prices, based on formal rules
contained in Commission-approved
tariffs, and where the prices are used by
a transmission organization for
establishing transmission usage charges.
(c) General rule.
(1) Every public utility that is a
transmission organization and that
owns, operates or controls facilities
used for the transmission of electric
energy in interstate commerce and has
one or more organized electricity
markets (administered either by it or by
another entity) must file with the
Commission, no later than January 29,
2007, one of the following:
(i) Tariff sheets and rate schedules
that make available long-term firm
transmission rights that satisfy each of
the guidelines set forth in paragraph (d)
of this section; or
(ii) An explanation of how its current
tariff and rate schedules already provide
for long-term firm transmission rights
that satisfy each of the guidelines set
forth in paragraph (d) of this section.
(2) Any transmission organization
approved by the Commission for
operation after January 29, 2007 that has
one or more organized electricity
markets (administered either by it or by
another entity) will be required to
satisfy this general rule.
(3) Filings made in compliance with
this paragraph (c) must explain how the
transmission organization’s
transmission planning and expansion
procedures will accommodate long-term
firm transmission rights, including but
not limited to how the transmission
organization will ensure that allocated
long-term firm transmission rights
remain feasible over their entire term.
(4) Each transmission organization
subject to this general rule must also
make its transmission planning and
expansion procedures and plans
publicly available, including (but not
limited to) both the actual plans and any
underlying information used to develop
the plans.
(d) Guidelines for Design and
Administration of Long-term Firm
Transmission Rights. Transmission
organizations subject to paragraph (c) of
this section must make available longterm firm transmission rights that satisfy
the following guidelines:
(1) The long-term firm transmission
right should specify a source (injection
node or nodes) and sink (withdrawal
node or nodes), and a quantity (MW).
(2) The long-term firm transmission
right must provide a hedge against dayahead locational marginal pricing
congestion charges or other direct
PO 00000
Frm 00057
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
43619
assignment of congestion costs for the
period covered and quantity specified.
Once allocated, the financial coverage
provided by a financial long-term right
should not be modified during its term
(the ‘‘full funding’’ requirement) except
in the case of extraordinary
circumstances or through voluntary
agreement of both the holder of the right
and the transmission organization.
(3) Long-term firm transmission rights
made feasible by transmission upgrades
or expansions must be available upon
request to any party that pays for such
upgrades or expansions in accordance
with the transmission organization’s
prevailing cost allocation methods for
upgrades or expansions.
(4) Long-term firm transmission rights
must be made available with term
lengths (and/or rights to renewal) that
are sufficient to meet the needs of load
serving entities to hedge long-term
power supply arrangements made or
planned to satisfy a service obligation.
The length of term of renewals may be
different from the original term.
Transmission organizations may
propose rules specifying the length of
terms and use of renewal rights to
provide long-term coverage, but must be
able to offer firm coverage for at least a
10 year period.
(5) Load serving entities must have
priority over non-load serving entities in
the allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights that are supported
by existing capacity. The transmission
organization may propose reasonable
limits on the amount of existing
capacity used to support long-term firm
transmission rights.
(6) A long-term transmission right
held by a load serving entity to support
a service obligation should be reassignable to another entity that
acquires that service obligation.
(7) The initial allocation of the longterm firm transmission rights shall not
require recipients to participate in an
auction.
Note: The following appendix will not
appear in the Code of Federal Regulations.
Appendix A—List of Commenters and
Acronyms
Alcoa Inc.—Alcoa
Allegheny Energy Companies—Allegheny
Allete, Inc. (dba Minnesota Power)—
Minnesota Power
Ameren Energy Companies—Ameren
American Electric Power Service
Corporation—AEP
American Forest and Paper Association—
AF&PA
American Public Power Association—APPA
Arizona Consumer-Owned Electric
Systems—Arizona Systems
Arkansas Municipal Power Association—
AMPA
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
43620
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with RULES_2
Bonneville Power Administration—BPA
Borough of Chambersburg, Pennsylvania—
Chambersburg
BP Energy Company—BP Energy
California Department of Water Resources,
State Water Project—DWR
California Municipal Utilities Association—
CMUA
California Independent System Operator
Corporation—CAISO
Public Utilities Commission of the State of
California—CPUC
Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corporation,
Consolidated Edison Company of New
York, Inc., LIPA, New York Power
Authority, New York State Electric and Gas
Corporation, Orange and Rockland
Utilities, Inc., and Rochester Gas and
Electric Corporation—New York
Transmission Owners
Central Vermont Public Service
Corporation—Central Vermont
Cinergy Services, Inc.—Cinergy
City of Redding, California—Redding
City of Santa Clara, California, Silicon Valley
Power—Santa Clara
Constellation Energy Group, Inc.—
Constellation
Coral Power, L.L.C.—Coral Power
DC Energy, L.L.C.—DC Energy
Dominion Resources, Inc.—Dominion
DTE Energy Company—DTE
Duquesne Light Company—Duquesne
Edison Electric Institute—EEI
E.ON U.S.—E.ON
Electricity Consumers Resource Council,
American Iron and Steel Institute,
Association of Businesses Advocating
Tariff Equity, and Coalition of Midwest
Transmission Customers—Industrial
Consumers
Electric Power Supply Association—EPSA
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:11 Jul 31, 2006
Jkt 208001
Energy Producers and Users Coalition and
Cogeneration Association of California—
Energy Producers and Users/Cogeneration
Association
Exelon Corporation—Exelon
FirstEnergy Service Company—FirstEnergy
Illinois Municipal Electric Agency—IMEA
Indianapolis Power & Light Company—IPL
ISO New England, Inc.—ISO–NE
Kentucky Public Service Commission—
Kentucky PSC
Long Island Power Authority and LIPA—
LIPA
Los Angeles Department of Water and
Power—LADWP
Manitoba Hydro—Manitoba
Metropolitan Water District of Southern
California—MWD
MidAmerican Energy Company—
MidAmerican
Midwest Stand-Alone Transmission
Companies—MSATs
Midwest Independent Transmission System
Operator, Inc.—Midwest ISO
Midwest Transmission Owners—Midwest
TOs
Modesto Irrigation District—Modesto
Morgan Stanley Capital Group Inc.—Morgan
Stanley
National Association of Regulatory Utility
Commissioners—NARUC
National Grid USA—National Grid
National Rural Electric Cooperative
Association—NRECA
New England Power Pool Participants
Committee—NEPOOL
New England Public Systems—New England
Public Systems
New York Association of Public Power—
NYAPP
New York Independent System Operator,
Inc.—NYISO
PO 00000
Frm 00058
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
New York Power Authority—NYPA
Public Service Commission of New York—
New York PSC
Northeast Utilities—NU
Northern California Power Agency—NCPA
NSTAR Electric & Gas Corporation—NSTAR
Organization of MISO States—OMS
Pacific Gas and Electric Company—PG&E
PJM Interconnection, L.L.C.—PJM
Old Dominion Electric Cooperative, North
Carolina Electric Membership Corporation,
Delaware Municipal Electric Corporation,
Southern Maryland Electric Cooperative,
and Allegheny Electric Cooperative—PJM
Public Power Coalition
PPM Energy, Inc.—PPM Energy
Public Power Council—Public Power Council
Reliant Energy, Inc.—Reliant
Sacramento Municipal Utility District—
SMUD
San Diego Gas & Electric Company—SDG&E
City of Santa Clara, California, Silicon Valley
Power—Santa Clara
Southern California Edison Company—SoCal
Edison
Strategic Energy, L.L.C.—Strategic Energy
Suez Energy North America, Inc.—Suez
Energy
Transmission Access Policy Study Group—
TAPS
Transmission Agency of Northern
California—TANC
Vermont Public Service Board and Vermont
Department of Public Service—Vermont
Agencies
Wisconsin Electric Power Company—
Wisconsin Electric
Xcel Energy Services Inc.—Xcel
[FR Doc. 06–6494 Filed 7–31–06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
E:\FR\FM\01AUR2.SGM
01AUR2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 71, Number 147 (Tuesday, August 1, 2006)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 43564-43620]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 06-6494]
[[Page 43563]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Part II
Department of Energy
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
18 CFR Part 42
Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity Markets;
Final Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 147 / Tuesday, August 1, 2006 / Rules
and Regulations
[[Page 43564]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 42
[Docket No. RM06-8-000; Order No. 681]
Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity
Markets
Issued July 20, 2006.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission is amending its
regulations under the Federal Power Act to require transmission
organizations that are public utilities with organized electricity
markets to make available long-term firm transmission rights that
satisfy certain guidelines adopted by the Commission in this Final
Rule. The Commission is taking this action pursuant to section 1233(b)
of the Energy Policy Act of 2005, [Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1233(b), 119
Stat. 594, 960 (2005).]
DATES: Effective Date: This Final Rule will become effective August 31,
2006.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Udi E. Helman (Technical Information),
Office of Energy Markets and Reliability, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502-
8080.
Roland Wentworth (Technical Information), Office of Energy Markets
and Reliability, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502-8262.
Wilbur C. Earley (Technical Information), Office of Energy Markets
and Reliability, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502-8087.
Harry Singh (Technical Information), Office of Enforcement,
Division of Energy Market Oversight, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502-
6341.
Jeffery S. Dennis (Legal Information), Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502-6027.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Table of Contents
Paragraph
Nos.
I. Background............................................... 3.
A. The Development of ISOs and RTOs..................... 3.
B. Interest in Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights....... 6.
C. Staff Paper on Long-Term Transmission Rights......... 11.
D. Energy Policy Act of 2005............................ 14.
E. Notice of Proposed Rulemaking........................ 15.
II. Discussion.............................................. 16.
A. Overview............................................. 16.
B. Definitions.......................................... 24.
1. Organized Electricity Market..................... 24.
2. Load Serving Entity and Service Obligation....... 34.
3. Long-Term Power Supply Arrangement............... 55.
4. Transmission Organization........................ 63.
C. Commission Interpretation of EPAct 2005 Requirements. 70.
D. Commission's Approach, Regional Flexibility, and 84.
Regional Seams Issues..................................
E. Guidelines for the Design and Administration of Long- 108.
Term Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity
Markets................................................
Guideline (1)--Specify Source, Sink and Quantity.... 108.
Guideline (2)--Long-Term Hedge That Cannot Be 122.
Modified...........................................
Guideline (3)--Rights Made Available by Expansions 185.
Go to Parties That Pay for the Upgrade.............
Guideline (4)--Term of Rights Must be Sufficient to 217.
Hedge Long-Term Power Supply Arrangements..........
Guideline (5)--Load Serving Entities with Long-Term 273.
Power Supply Arrangements Have Priority to the
Existing System....................................
Guideline (6)--Rights are Reassignable to Follow 331.
Load...............................................
Guideline (7)--Auction Not Required................. 361.
Guideline (8)--Balance Adverse Economic Impacts..... 394.
F. Transmission Planning and Expansion.................. 429.
G. Alternative Designs for Long-Term Firm Transmission 458.
Rights.................................................
H. Miscellaneous Comments............................... 477.
I. Implementation of the Final Rule and Compliance 479.
Issues.................................................
III. Information Collection Statement....................... 496.
IV. Environmental Analysis.................................. 500.
V. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification................. 501.
VI. Document Availability................................... 502.
VII. Effective Date and Congressional Notification.......... 505.
Before Commissioners: Joseph T. Kelliher, Chairman; Nora Mead Brownell,
and Suedeen G. Kelly; Order No. 681; Final Rule
1. In this Final Rule, the Commission is amending its regulations
to require each transmission organization that is a public utility with
one or more organized electricity markets to make available long-term
firm transmission rights that satisfy each of the guidelines
established by the Commission in this Final Rule. We take this action
pursuant to section 1233 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005),
which added new section 217 to the Federal Power Act (FPA).\1\ This
Final Rule will require each transmission organization subject to its
requirements to file with the Commission, no later than January 29,
2007, either (1) tariff sheets and rate schedules that make available
long-term firm transmission rights that satisfy each of the guidelines
set forth in the final regulations, or (2) an explanation of how its
current tariff and rate schedules already provide for long-term firm
transmission rights that satisfy each of the guidelines. A transmission
organization approved by the Commission for operation after January 29,
2007 will be required to satisfy the requirements of this Final Rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 957 (2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. The guidelines adopted in this Final Rule will give transmission
organizations the flexibility to propose designs for long-term firm
transmission rights that reflect regional preferences and accommodate
their regional market designs, while also ensuring that the objectives
of Congress expressed in new section 217(b)(4) of the FPA are met. As
described in more detail below, the Commission will allow regional
flexibility in setting the terms of the rights, but long-term firm
transmission rights must be made available with terms (and/or rights to
renewal) that are sufficient to meet the reasonable needs of load
serving entities to support long-term power supply arrangements used to
satisfy their service obligations.
[[Page 43565]]
I. Background
A. The Development of ISOs and RTOs
3. In Order No. 888, the Commission found that undue discrimination
and anticompetitive practices existed in the provision of electric
transmission service in interstate commerce.\2\ Accordingly, the
Commission required all public utilities that own, control or operate
facilities used for transmitting electric energy in interstate commerce
to file open access transmission tariffs (OATTs) containing certain
non-price terms and conditions and to ``functionally unbundle''
wholesale power services from transmission services.\3\ In addition,
the Commission found in Order No. 888 that Independent System Operators
(ISOs) had the potential to aid in remedying undue discrimination and
accomplishing comparable access \4\ and set out 11 principles for
assessing ISO proposals submitted to the Commission.\5\ Following Order
No. 888, several voluntary ISOs were established and approved by the
Commission.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-
discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery
of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities,
Order No. 888, 61 FR 21540 (May 10, 1996), FERC Stats. & Regs. ]
31,036 at 31,682 (1996), order on reh'g, Order No. 888-A, 62 FR
12274 (March 14, 1997), FERC Stats & Regs. ] 31,048 (1997), order on
reh'g, Order No. 888-B, 81 FERC ] 61,248 (1997), order on reh'g,
Order No. 888-C, 82 FERC ] 61,046 (1998), aff'd in relevant part sub
nom. Transmission Access Policy Study Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667
(D.C. Cir. 2000), aff'd sub nom. New York v. FERC, 535 U.S. 1
(2002).
\3\ Under functional unbundling, the public utility is required
to: (1) Take wholesale transmission services under the same tariff
of general applicability as it offers its customers; (2) state
separate rates for wholesale generation, transmission and ancillary
services; and (3) rely on the same electronic information network
that its transmission customers rely on to obtain information about
the utility's transmission system. Id. at 31,654.
\4\ Order No. 888 at 31,655; Order No. 888-A at 30,184.
\5\ Order No. 888 at 31,730.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. In light of the creation of these ISOs and other changes in the
electric industry, the Commission issued Order No. 2000.\6\ In that
order, the Commission concluded that traditional management of the
transmission grid by vertically integrated electric utilities was
inadequate to support the efficient and reliable operation of
transmission facilities necessary for continued development of
competitive electricity markets \7\ and that opportunities for undue
discrimination continued to exist.\8\ As a result, the Commission
adopted rules to facilitate the voluntary development of Regional
Transmission Organizations (RTOs). The Commission concluded that RTOs
would provide several benefits, including regional transmission
pricing, improved congestion management, and more effective management
of parallel path flows.\9\ In Order No. 2000, the Commission
established the minimum characteristics and functions that an RTO must
satisfy to gain Commission approval.\10\ Under Order No. 2000, the
Commission has approved the voluntary formation of a number of RTOs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ Regional Transmission Organizations, Order No. 2000, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ] 31,089 (1999), order on reh'g, Order No. 2000-A,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,092 (2000), aff'd sub nom. Public Utility
District No. 1 of Snohomish County, Washington v. FERC, 272 F.3d 607
(D.C. Cir. 2001).
\7\ Order No. 2000 at 30,992-93 and 31,014-15.
\8\ Id. at 31,015-17.
\9\ Id. at 31,024.
\10\ Id. at 31,106 et seq.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. Most of the RTOs and ISOs operate organized markets for energy
and/or ancillary services in addition to providing transmission service
under a single transmission tariff. Most of these markets utilize a
congestion management system based on Locational Marginal Pricing
(LMP). Congestion is defined as the inability to inject and withdraw
additional energy at particular locations in the network due to the
fact that the injections and withdrawals would cause power flows over a
specific transmission facility to violate the reliability limits for
that facility. The market operator manages congestion by scheduling and
dispatching generators that can meet load in the presence of
congestion. Financially, in LMP markets the price of congestion is
measured as the difference in the cost of energy in the spot market at
two different locations in the network. When such price differences
occur, a congestion charge is assessed to transmission users based on
their nodal injections and withdrawals. These price differences can be
variable and difficult to predict. In order to manage the risk
associated with the variability in prices due to transmission
congestion, these markets use various forms of financial transmission
rights (FTRs) \11\ to allow market participants who hold the rights to
protect against such price risks. In most cases, these FTRs have terms
of one year or less. In general, load serving entities receive FTRs
through either direct allocation or through a two-step process in which
the load serving entity is first allocated auction revenue rights
(ARRs) and then either uses those rights to purchase FTRs, or has the
ability under the transmission organization tariff to convert them to
FTRs.\12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ While ``FTR'' is sometimes used to refer to ``firm
transmission rights,'' in this Final Rule we use this acronym to
refer to the various forms of financial transmission rights that
exist in organized electricity markets. In some markets, these are
referred to as congestion revenue rights or transmission congestion
contracts.
\12\ For a more detailed discussion, see Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity Markets, Notice of
Proposed Rulemaking, 71 FR 6693 (Feb. 9, 2006), FERC Stats. & Regs.
] 32,598 at P 27 (2006) (NOPR). As we noted in the NOPR, ARRs confer
the right to collect revenues from the subsequent FTR auction.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Interest in Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights
6. In recent years, interest in long-term firm transmission rights
in organized electricity markets has increased, stemming in large part
from a desire of some market participants to obtain rights that
replicate the transmission service that was available to them prior to
the formation of the organized electricity markets and remains
available today in regions without organized electricity markets. The
principal concern of these market participants is the inability to
obtain a fixed, long-term level of service under pricing arrangements
that hedge the congestion cost risk that they face in the organized
electricity markets.
7. There are several important differences between transmission
service under the Order No. 888 pro forma Open Access Transmission
Tariff (OATT) and transmission rights in organized electricity markets
that use LMP and FTRs.\13\ However, the differences that are most
relevant for purposes of this Final Rule concern the management of
congestion, the recovery of congestion costs and the availability of
long-term service arrangements.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ A detailed discussion of transmission rights in traditional
and organized markets was presented in the NOPR at P 15-33.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
8. Under the OATT, the transmission provider in the first instance
manages congestion by redispatching its own or its customers' network
resources as needed to accommodate a transmission constraint; the OATT
provides no mechanism by which firm point-to-point transmission
customers can participate directly in congestion management.\14\
However, in the organized electricity markets that use LMP, the
transmission organization manages congestion through the use of
locational prices that are determined by bids and offers by markets
participants at given locations. This means that all available
resources under an LMP system can participate in redispatch for
congestion management because they all receive the congestion price
signal. As a result, a transmission organization in a region with an
organized electricity market is less likely to have to invoke
[[Page 43566]]
transmission loading relief procedures and service curtailments than a
transmission provider under the OATT.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ The transmission provider may also need to curtail service
to certain customers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
9. The recovery of congestion costs also differs greatly between
regions with and without organized electricity markets. In regions
where transmission service is provided under the OATT, a transmission
customer that takes network service or firm point-to-point transmission
service is not charged directly for the costs of the redispatch that
may be required to accommodate its use of the transmission system. For
example, a firm point-to-point transmission customer is allowed to take
service up to its contractual entitlement while paying only a fixed
demand charge. Also, although a network customer must pay a share of
any redispatch costs that the transmission provider and other network
customers incur, its cost responsibility is determined after the fact
as a load ratio share of the total redispatch costs that are incurred
on behalf of all users of the system over a given time period. While
this type of pricing may not present the customer with a price signal
that accurately reflects all of the costs occasioned by the customer's
use of the system, it does provide price certainty. In addition, both
network service and firm point-to-point transmission service can be
obtained under long-term contracts. These attributes of OATT
transmission service result in a less volatile price for transmission
service over the long-term, which in turn can help facilitate the
planning and financing of large generation facilities and other long-
term power supply arrangements.
10. In contrast, a transmission organization in a region with an
organized electricity market recovers congestion costs measured as
differences in the locational price of energy. Because locational
prices include a congestion cost component (which can be positive,
negative or zero), a participant in an organized electricity market
faces the prospect of paying a congestion charge for many of its
transactions. Locational pricing and price-based congestion management
provide the market participant with much of the information it needs to
make cost effective decisions regarding energy consumption and use of
the transmission system (as well as investment in new generation and
transmission upgrades). However, the FTRs that transmission
organizations currently provide to hedge congestion charges for using
existing transmission capacity (as opposed to incremental transmission
expansions) are generally available for terms of only one year or less.
This can create uncertainty for the market participant who wants to
procure supplies on a long-term basis because it will not know from
year to year with any degree of certainty whether its award of FTRs
will be sufficient to meet its needs. Some market participants have
expressed concern that this uncertainty makes it more difficult to
finance long-term power supply arrangements.
C. Staff Paper on Long-Term Transmission Rights
11. In May 2005, the Commission released a Staff Paper that
provided background and solicited comments on whether long-term
transmission rights were needed in the ISO and RTO markets, and if so,
how to implement them.\15\ A number of commenters on the Staff Paper
argued that the failure of transmission organizations to offer
transmission rights with terms greater than one year is a key
deficiency in the markets that produces increased financial risk due to
congestion price uncertainty, the failure of forward energy markets to
form, and barriers to investment in new generation capacity. Most of
the parties in this group stressed that not all transmission capacity
should be given over to long-term rights, but that there should be an
amount sufficient to cover at least base-load generation resources and
perhaps renewable energy generators.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ Notice Inviting Comments On Establishing Long-Term
Transmission Rights in Markets With Locational Pricing and Staff
Paper, Long-Term Transmission Rights Assessment, Docket No. AD05-7-
000 (May 11, 2005) (Staff Paper).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. A second group of commenters on the Staff Paper largely agreed
with the first that long-term rights should be introduced, but argued
that this should take place within the framework of existing FTR market
designs and follow a cautious, incremental approach. They also
supported limiting the quantity of system capability given over to
long-term FTRs for at least an initial period.
13. Finally, some respondents felt that long-term rights should not
be introduced at this time. These parties were concerned that the
introduction of multi-year rights could introduce inequity and
inefficiency into the organized electricity markets because such rights
will reduce the availability of FTRs with terms of one year or less
that can be used to hedge shorter-term transactions. They also assert
that introducing long-term rights could cause cost shifts if holders of
long-term rights are given congestion risk coverage greater than that
accorded to other parties.
D. Energy Policy Act of 2005
14. On August 8, 2005, EPAct 2005 \16\ became law. As noted above,
section 1233 of EPAct 2005 added a new section 217 to the FPA, which
provides:
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ Pub. L. 109-58, 119 Stat. 594
The Commission shall exercise the authority of the Commission
under this Act in a manner that facilitates the planning and
expansion of transmission facilities to meet the reasonable needs of
load-serving entities to satisfy the service obligations of the
load-serving entities, and enables load-serving entities to secure
firm transmission rights (or equivalent tradable or financial
rights) on a long-term basis for long-term power supply arrangements
made, or planned, to meet such needs.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 958.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005 requires:
Within 1 year after the date of enactment of this section and
after notice and an opportunity for comment, the Commission shall by
rule or order, implement section 217(b)(4) of the Federal Power Act
in Transmission Organizations, as defined by that Act with organized
electricity markets.\18\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Id. at 960. Transmission organization is defined in EPAct
2005 as ``a Regional Transmission Organization, Independent System
Operator, independent transmission provider, or other transmission
organization finally approved by the Commission for the operation of
transmission facilities.'' Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1291, 119 Stat.
594, 985. Below, we adopt this definition with a minor modification
for purposes of this Final Rule.
E. Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
15. On February 2, 2006, the Commission issued a NOPR that proposed
to amend its regulations to require each transmission organization that
is a public utility with one or more organized electricity markets to
make available long-term firm transmission rights that satisfy
guidelines established by the Commission.\19\ As discussed in more
detail below, the NOPR proposed eight guidelines, and sought comments
on various issues raised by the introduction of long-term firm
transmission rights in the organized electricity markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\19\ See supra note 12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Discussion
A. Overview
16. In adopting this Final Rule, the Commission seeks to provide
increased certainty regarding the congestion cost risks of long-term
transmission service in organized electricity markets that will help
load serving entities and other market participants make new
investments and other long-term power supply arrangements. The
guidelines we adopt in this Final Rule are designed and intended
primarily to ensure that
[[Page 43567]]
the long-term firm transmission rights that are made available by
transmission organizations that are subject to the rule have
characteristics that will support a long-term power supply arrangement.
These guidelines provide a framework within which transmission
organizations and their market participants can design and implement
long-term firm transmission rights in the organized electricity markets
that are compatible with the design of those markets, in particular
retaining the advantages of price-based congestion management, and meet
the reasonable needs of market participants.
17. Many of the comments received by the Commission express concern
that the provision of long-term firm transmission rights will result in
a drastic redistribution of transmission rights, with transmission
organizations required to provide long-term rights to load serving
entities regardless of feasibility or impact on other market
participants. This concern is unfounded. While this Final Rule
unequivocally requires transmission organizations to offer long-term
firm transmission rights with characteristics that will support long-
term power supply arrangements, in most cases, offering such rights
should not require major changes in allocations or allocation
procedures.\20\ Our intent with regard to the existing transmission
system is that load serving entities be able to request and obtain
transmission rights up to a reasonable amount on a long-term firm
basis, instead of being limited to obtaining exclusively annual
rights.\21\ Offering such rights should not force transmission
organizations to provide rights to the existing system to one party
that are infeasible. We expect that transmission organizations will be
able to integrate long-term firm transmission rights into their
existing procedures for assessing the feasibility of requests for
transmission service.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ As we discuss in more detail below, while we do not believe
major changes to existing allocation procedures will be necessary,
Congress did not intend to protect existing or future allocation
methodologies from the implementation of section 217(b)(4) of the
FPA. See new section 217(c) of the FPA, Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1233,
119 Stat. 594, 958-59.
\21\ Capacity available would be limited to that which is
generally available and excludes capacity that is the exclusive
right of a participant, e.g., a participant that paid for such
capacity and obtained FTRs for that payment.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
18. While it is difficult to generalize, given the flexibility
afforded in this Final Rule, we expect that in most transmission
organizations with organized electricity markets the process for
obtaining a long-term firm transmission right will not be substantially
different from the current procedures. Most transmission organizations
will be able to use their current allocation/auction systems to allow
load serving entities to nominate source-to-sink transmission rights on
a longer-term basis than is currently available. Transmission
organizations will then assess those requests for feasibility and award
a feasible set of transmission rights, as they do today. This Final
Rule also allows the transmission organization to place reasonable
limits on the total amount of capacity it will offer as long-term
rights. Thus, this Final Rule does not necessarily guarantee that a
load serving entity will be able to obtain long-term firm transmission
rights to hedge its entire resource portfolio or be able to obtain all
the long-term firm transmission rights it requests. Once long-term
rights are awarded to a load serving entity, however, this Final Rule
requires that they be fully funded over their entire term, as discussed
in guideline (2) below.
19. As we noted in the NOPR and reaffirm in this Final Rule,
transmission organizations must provide the opportunity for market
participants to obtain long-term firm transmission rights that are not
currently available by supporting an expansion or upgrade of grid
transfer capability. The Commission's policy is that market
participants that request and support an expansion or upgrade in
accordance with their transmission organization's prevailing rules for
cost responsibility and allocation must be awarded a long-term firm
transmission right for the incremental transfer capability created by
the expansion or upgrade. The transmission organization tariffs must
clearly and specifically provide for this arrangement, if they do not
already. Guideline (3) addresses this requirement. This will enable
load serving entities to obtain long-term rights that they may have
requested but not received due to infeasibility.
20. Moreover, in this Final Rule we also require transmission
organizations with organized electricity markets to explain how their
transmission system planning and expansion policies will ensure that
long-term firm transmission rights, once allocated, remain feasible
over their entire term.
21. Together, these provisions will ensure that transmission
systems are expanded where necessary to ensure the continued
feasibility of allocated long-term firm transmission rights, while also
giving market participants an explicit right to obtain new incremental
transmission rights on a long-term basis, in accordance with the
prevailing cost allocation methodology in the region.\22\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\22\ We are not requiring any ``obligation to build'' that does
not already exist under Order No. 888.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. We understand that specifying and allocating long-term firm
transmission rights supported by existing transfer capability will
raise difficult issues that must be addressed by transmission
organizations and their stakeholders as proposals are developed to
comply with this Final Rule. As we discuss in more detail, we believe
that the approach we adopt in this Final Rule will give transmission
organizations and their stakeholders sufficient flexibility to design
long-term firm transmission rights that fit their prevailing market
design while also ensuring that the rights have certain fundamental
properties necessary to achieve Congress's objectives in section
217(b)(4) of the FPA. We also clarify below that while each guideline
permits flexibility in its implementation, transmission organizations
with organized electricity markets must satisfy each of the guidelines
in this Final Rule.
23. This Final Rule largely adopts the overall approach as well as
the specific guidelines and definitions proposed in the NOPR. In
response to the comments received, however, the Commission has made the
following changes to the proposal, as discussed in this preamble:
Guideline (3) (Rights Made Available by Expansion Go to
Parties That Pay for the Upgrade): We have removed the requirement
that the term of long-term rights from expansion be equal to life of
facility or a lesser term requested by the party paying for the
upgrade. Based on the comments on the difficulty of defining life of
facility, we will defer to transmission organizations to develop
terms based on existing market rules and stakeholder needs. We
encourage transmission organizations to harmonize the terms for
long-term rights awarded for new capacity with the terms of long-
term rights to existing transmission capacity as much as possible.
Guideline (4) (Term of Rights Must Be Sufficient To
Hedge Long-Term Power Supply Arrangements): We have added a
provision that transmission organizations and stakeholders may
determine the length of terms and use of renewal rights to provide
long-term transmission rights, but must offer coverage for at least
a 10-year sequence. Our objective is to balance regional flexibility
in defining terms of rights with the need to ensure that those terms
are sufficient to allow load serving entities to hedge their long-
term power supply arrangements.
Guideline (5) (Load Serving Entities With Long-Term
Power Supply Arrangements Have Priority to the Existing System): We
have revised this guideline in two respects. First, we have
eliminated the preference for load serving entities with long-term
power
[[Page 43568]]
supply arrangements and replaced it with a broader preference for
load serving entities in general vis-[agrave]-vis non-load serving
entities. This broader preference is fully supported by the statute
and better meets the needs of organized electricity markets. We
believe that Congress's intent in enacting section 217 was to
provide long-term firm transmission service to load serving entities
and that load serving entities in general should be ``first in
line'' for long-term transmission rights when existing capacity is
limited. As originally proposed, guideline (5) could have
disadvantaged load serving entities who do not engage in long-term
power supply arrangements, a result that we do not believe Congress
intended. Proposed guideline (5) could have also presented difficult
administrative burdens for transmission organizations, including the
burden of evaluating power supply contracts to determine if they
qualify for the preference. In addition to addressing these
concerns, broadening the preference also makes it possible for
transmission organizations to apply the same basic principles for
allocating long-term firm transmission rights that they currently
use for the initial allocation of short-term firm transmission
rights, or auction revenue rights. As a result of this change in the
guideline, load serving entities will not be required to provide
evidence of a long-term power supply arrangement.
We have also revised guideline (5) to allow transmission
organizations to place reasonable limits on the amount of existing
transmission capacity made available for long-term firm transmission
rights. We have done so in recognition of the expected reluctance of
transmission organizations to commit all of their existing grid
capacity to long-term firm transmission rights due to uncertainty
regarding load growth, changes in power flows and the full funding
requirement of this Final Rule. This will also help to accommodate
load serving entities that prefer short-term rights. In addition,
commenters claim that the principal need for long-term firm
transmission rights is to support long-term power supply
arrangements for base load generation, not peaking or intermediate
generation.
Guideline (8) (Balance Adverse Economic Impacts): We
have elected not to adopt this guideline in the Final Rule. This
guideline is not needed as it requires, in effect, nothing more than
adherence to the FPA requirement that public utility tariffs must be
just and reasonable and not unduly discriminatory. Moreover, it
could have been misinterpreted to require long-term firm
transmission right proposals to meet a different or higher standard,
something the Commission did not intend or believe that Congress
intended.
Definition of ``Long-Term Power Supply Arrangement'':
Because we have deleted the reference to ``long-term power supply
arrangements'' from guideline (5), that term is only used in
guideline (4), relating to the term of long-term firm transmission
rights. The Final Rule removes the specific definition of long-term
power supply arrangements proposed in the NOPR, and addresses issues
related to our definition of long-term power supply arrangements
under guideline (4).
Transmission Planning and Expansion: This Final Rule
requires that each transmission organization with an organized
electricity market implement transmission system planning and
expansion procedures to accommodate long-term firm transmission
rights that are allocated or awarded to ensure that they remain
feasible over their entire term. We also require each such
transmission organization to make its planning and expansion
practices and procedures publicly available, including both the
actual plans and any underlying information used to develop the
plans.
B. Definitions
1. Organized Electricity Market
24. In the NOPR, the Commission proposed to define ``organized
electricity market'' as ``an auction-based market where a single entity
receives offers to sell and bids to buy electric energy and/or
ancillary services from multiple sellers and buyers and determines
which sales and purchases are completed and at what prices, based on
formal rules contained in Commission-approved tariffs, and where the
prices are used by a transmission organization for establishing
transmission usage charges.'' \23\ The Commission stated that it
proposed this definition to ensure that the Final Rule in this
proceeding applies to any transmission organization that is the
transmission provider in its region and has a day-ahead and/or real-
time bid-based energy market, administered by the transmission
organization itself or by another entity. We sought comment on the
scope of this proposed definition.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ NOPR at P 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Comments
25. AMPA \24\ and Public Power Council both argue that the proposed
definition is too narrow and should be expanded to include ``Day 1''
RTO/ISO markets, non-RTO/ISO markets, and other forms of ``organized
markets'' (which can include bilateral markets that use a form
contract).\25\ Public Power Council argues that the proposed definition
could lock the Commission into adopting the types of markets described
in the definition to the exclusion of other types of markets, and that
section 217 of the FPA does not support the Commission's narrow
reading.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ A list of commenters on the NOPR and the acronyms used to
refer to them in this preamble is attached as Appendix A.
\25\ NRECA, while not recommending any change to the proposed
definition, notes that the issues raised over the availability of
long-term firm transmission rights also arise in transmission
organizations without Day 2 markets and on the systems of non-
independent entities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
26. Other commenters argue that the definition should be narrowed.
TAPS, for example, asserts that the Final Rule should not apply in
regions where the OATT provides for long-term physical transmission
rights, particularly the Southwest Power Pool. According to TAPS, the
last clause of the definition of organized electricity markets (``where
the prices are used by a transmission organization for establishing
transmission usage charges'') excludes SPP because the prices produced
by its imbalance market will not establish transmission usage charges.
TAPS requests that the Commission clarify that as currently designed
SPP will not be subject to the Final Rule.
27. PG&E, EPSA and TAPS all state that because the proposed rule
primarily addresses markets that use locational market-based congestion
management mechanisms like LMP and have FTRs, the Final Rule should
clearly state that it only applies to those markets, and only addresses
long-term financial transmission instruments. PG&E recommends that the
Commission issue a parallel rule providing for long-term transmission
rights in markets that do not use a market-based congestion management
mechanism.
28. In reply comments, NRECA opposes proposals to narrow the
definition of organized electricity market, arguing that the need for
long-term firm transmission rights and the language of the statute are
not limited to transmission organizations with locational pricing
structures.
29. APPA states that it supports the proposed definition of
organized electricity market, but suggests that it be revised to
replace ``auction-based market'' with ``a centralized market'' because
use of ``auction-based'' implies that buyers and sellers in RTO markets
have more choice and autonomy than they do in practice.
Commission Conclusion
30. We will adopt the definition of organized electricity market
proposed in the NOPR with one modification. Specifically, we modify the
first clause of the definition to state that organized electricity
market ``means an auction-based day ahead and real time wholesale
market * * *.'' We make this modification to clarify the application of
this Final Rule and ensure that the definition captures the
transmission organizations with organized electricity markets using LMP
and FTRs to which Congress directed the Commission to apply this Final
Rule to in section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005. Today, those electricity
markets do not offer financial transmission instruments supported by
[[Page 43569]]
existing capacity with terms longer than one year, and thus entities
are not able to obtain a ``firm'' transmission right on a long-term
basis in those markets as section 217(b)(4) of the FPA directs. As a
result, they are appropriately the focus of this Final Rule.
31. The Commission will not expand the definition to include other
RTO/ISO regions (sometimes called ``Day 1'' markets), non-RTO/ISO
transmission providers, or any other electricity market structure.
Applying the Final Rule to non-RTO/ISO markets would not be appropriate
because EPAct 2005 requires us to implement section 217(b)(4) in this
rulemaking in ``transmission organizations with organized electricity
markets,'' and non-RTO/ISO transmission providers by definition are not
transmission organizations.\26\ And while Public Power Council is
correct that there may be other electricity market structures, the
definition we adopt here is only for the purposes of this Final Rule
and is crafted to ensure that the appropriate entities are subject to
the Final Rule. Additionally, as we noted in the NOPR, non-RTO/ISO
transmission providers and other RTO/ISOs offer long-term physical
transmission service under the Order No. 888 OATT without rates that
vary with congestion costs.\27\ The Commission recently issued a NOPR
in Docket Nos. RM05-25-000 and RM05-17-000 that would institute reforms
to the OATT. It is more appropriate to consider in that rulemaking any
issues related to the application of section 217(b)(4) of the FPA to
the other markets identified by commenters, particularly issues related
to coordinated, open and transparent transmission system planning.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ This is not to say that there might not in the future be
types of transmission organizations other than ISOs and RTOs
approved by the Commission that operate transmission facilities and
provide transmission service. The new FPA definition of transmission
organization leaves open this possibility. At the current time,
however, RTOs and ISOs are the only such organizations approved by
the Commission.
\27\ While transmission organizations with organized electricity
markets are also expected to have OATTs that meet the requirements
of Order No. 888, the total cost of transmission service in those
transmission organizations varies with the cost of congestion, and
such transmission organizations only offer FTRs to hedge congestion
costs with short-terms.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
32. In response to TAPS, we clarify that SPP is not subject to this
Final Rule because its current market design does not fit within the
definition of organized electricity market that we adopt for purposes
of this rule.
33. Finally, we decline to revise the ``auction-based'' language as
APPA requests. This language simply recognizes that the organized
electricity markets Congress intended to be subject to this Final Rule
are those that utilize auction mechanisms for the buying and selling of
electric energy. We note that we are adopting this definition for the
purposes of this Final Rule only, and do not intend that it will
necessarily apply in other contexts.
2. Load Serving Entity and Service Obligation
34. We proposed to define ``load serving entity'' and ``service
obligation,'' for purposes of the proposed rule, exactly as Congress
defined those terms in new section 217 of the FPA. Specifically, we
proposed to define load serving entity as ``a distribution utility or
electric utility that has a service obligation.'' \28\ We proposed to
define service obligation as ``a requirement applicable to, or the
exercise of authority granted to, an electric utility under federal,
State or local law or under long-term contracts to provide electric
service to end-users or to a distribution utility.'' \29\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ NOPR at P 7, citing Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1233, 119 Stat.
594, 957. EPAct 2005 defines electric utility as ``a person or
Federal or State agency (including an entity described in section
210(f)) that sells electric energy.'' Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1291,
119 Stat. 594, 984.
\29\ NOPR at P 7, citing Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1233, 119 Stat.
594, 958.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Comments
35. APPA, E.ON, NRECA, PG&E and Public Power Council all express
support for the proposed definitions.
36. Several commenters (including Industrial Consumers, CAISO,
NARUC, National Grid and SDG&E) argue that the proposed definitions in
the NOPR would exclude several entities that should be eligible for
long-term firm transmission rights because they are not a
``distribution utility'' or ``electric utility.'' These entities
include industrial customers who serve their own load pursuant to state
law, several types of retail service providers, community aggregators,
and various non-public utilities. The comments generally seek
clarification that all of these various entities are ``load serving
entities'' for purposes of this rule.
37. More specifically, Industrial Consumers and Alcoa explain that
while many large industrial customers are permitted under state law to
self-supply their own load, usually by registering as a retail
provider, not all of these states use the term ``load serving entity.''
Industrial Consumers argue that entities who have qualified as retail
electric providers under state law meet the definition of ``electric
utility'' under EPAct 2005, and request that the Commission
unambiguously state that entities who are qualified to serve retail
load under state law, including those self-supplying, are load serving
entities for purposes of the Final Rule and thus qualify for long-term
firm transmission rights.
38. Regarding retail service providers, several commenters
(including CAISO, EEI, NARUC and National Grid) seek clarifications
regarding whether various types of service providers in retail access
states are load serving entities under the proposed definition. NARUC
notes that states with retail choice programs either may have multiple
sellers of electricity to end users, or may use an auction process
whereby the distribution utility takes delivery of the power supply and
bills the cost to customers, making it the only seller.\30\ To protect
and accommodate these choices made by the states, and to be consistent
with Congress' intent that the protections in section 217 of the FPA be
available to all customers, it asks the Commission to clarify that all
of these entities are ``electric utilities'' and/or ``distribution
utilities,'' thereby making them load serving entities and eligible to
obtain long-term firm transmission rights.\31\ OMS, noting specifically
that Illinois utilities will soon be required to use an auction process
to procure supply and that auction winners under this format would not
meet either definition, asks the Commission to revise the definition of
load serving entity to replace ``a distribution utility or electric
utility'' with ``an entity,'' and revise the definition of service
obligation to replace ``electric utility'' with ``entity.'' EEI and
National Grid both note that under certain retail access structures
service obligations (including the default service obligation) may be
reassigned for terms that are less than the term of long-term firm
transmission rights. EEI asserts that the proposed definition of load
serving entity should be clarified to be simply the distribution
utility, unless its service obligation has been reassigned, while
National Grid suggests that the load serving entity
[[Page 43570]]
should be the electric utility when it holds the service obligation,
and the distribution utility in the first instance. National Grid also
asserts that the Commission should clarify that the term ``electric
utility'' is defined in section 3(22) of the FPA (any ``person or
Federal or State agency * * * that sells electric energy''), which
would encompass both municipal utilities and merchant suppliers not
normally subject to state regulation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ National Grid notes that pursuant to state law, its
distribution utilities have at various times been required to
contract with wholesale suppliers to meet their load obligations
(including congestion cost exposure), while in other retail choice
programs those responsibilities have been directly assigned to
retail suppliers.
\31\ In its reply comments, NARUC reiterates its request,
further stating that the Commission should clarify that vertically-
integrated utilities, municipal utilities and cooperatives in
traditionally regulated states, power suppliers in retail states,
and distribution utilities or auction winners in other states are
all ``electric utilities'' and/or ``distribution utilities,'' and
thus eligible to obtain long-term firm transmission rights.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
39. Santa Clara asserts that the definition of load serving entity
should include non-public utilities (as defined in section 201(f) of
the FPA), subsidiary agencies of non-public utilities, and entities in
which non-public utilities hold an interest (such as joint action
agencies), since each either serve load under statutory obligations to
serve or facilitate such service. Similarly, California DWR and MWD
argue that the Commission should revise the definition of load serving
entities to include water pumping entities.\32\ They assert that in new
section 217(g) of the FPA, Congress recognized a need to expand the
definition of load serving entity to include such entities.\33\ To
comply with section 217(g), California DWR and MWD contend that the
Commission should revise the proposed definition to define load serving
entity to mean ``a distribution utility, or an electric utility that
has a service obligation, or other wholesale transmission user that
owns generation facilities, markets the output of federal generation
facilities, or holds rights under one or more wholesale contracts to
purchase electric energy, for the purpose of meeting a service
obligation.'' \34\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\32\ MWD notes that its water pumping operations require large
amounts of power (roughly 2-3 percent of California's total energy
requirement), and that these operations require long-term
transmission rights to achieve reliable water delivery.
\33\ Specifically, section 217(g) provides that ``[t]he
Commission shall ensure that any entity described in section 201(f)
that owns transmission facilities used predominately to support its
own water pumping facilities shall have, with respect to the
facilities, protections for transmission service comparable to those
provided to load serving entities pursuant to this section.'' See
Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 959.
\34\ Reply Comments of California DWR at 9.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
40. MSATs seek clarification that as stand-alone transmission
companies that do not own generation or distribution facilities, buy or
sell energy, serve loads or act as transmission customers or market
participants, they are not considered load serving entities under the
Commission's proposed regulations.
41. Ameren asks the Commission to clarify that the definition of
service obligation includes future obligations, and not just
obligations existing at the effective date of the Final Rule, which it
states will provide certainty and reassure load serving entities that
long-term firm transmission rights will continue to be made available
in the future.
42. Commenters (including CAISO, PG&E and NU) also raise issues and
seek clarification specifically with regard to the application of the
service obligation definition in retail access frameworks, and
particularly seek clarification as to whether a default service
obligation is a ``service obligation.'' According to CAISO, these
clarifications are important because they will impact the eligibility
rules for long-term firm transmission rights and the rules for
transferring those rights as end-users switch providers. Commenters
such as PG&E assert that entities holding the default service
obligation, even though they may not be serving the load now, must be
able to plan to meet that load should they be required to serve it in
the future. Coral Power states that the definition of service
obligation should be expanded because as proposed by the Commission, it
only applies to distribution companies or entities that provide
electric service to end-users under contracts. It argues that the
definition should include wholesale power suppliers that provide
hedging services to competitive retail suppliers or that have assumed
load obligations under default service or retail access programs.
43. Commenters (including NU and PG&E) also raise issues with the
``long-term contracts'' language in the definition, arguing that it has
the potential to discriminate against load serving entities in retail
access jurisdictions, since such entities do not typically enter into
long-term power supply contracts. NU argues that in New England, the
definition would favor municipal utilities (whose customers are not
included in retail access programs) and utilities from outside the
region that serve load through New England resources.\35\ Accordingly,
it asks that the Commission narrow the definitions to limit eligibility
for long-term firm transmission rights to entities that serve customers
within the same region.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\35\ Comments of NU at 3-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Commission Conclusion
44. In the Final Rule, the Commission is adopting the definitions
of load serving entity and service obligation provided by Congress in
EPAct 2005 and proposed in the NOPR. We believe using these definitions
as Congress provided them will most closely effectuate the intent of
Congress in section 217(b)(4) of the FPA. We will, however, offer
several clarifications.
45. At the outset, we note that the definition of load serving
entity is important in this Final Rule only in that it establishes a
priority in the allocation of long-term firm transmission rights when
necessary under guideline (5). It does not determine eligibility for
long-term firm transmission rights, as some commenters suggest. All
market participants are eligible for long-term firm transmission
rights.
46. In response to National Grid, we clarify that the term
``electric utility,'' as used in the definition of load serving entity,
is defined in section 3(2) of the FPA as ``a person or Federal or State
agency (including an entity described in section 201(f)) that sells
electric energy.'' \36\ This expansive definition will cover many of
the entities for which commenters seek clarification as to their status
as load serving entities.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\36\ 16 U.S.C. 796(22) (2000), as amended by EPAct 2005, Pub. L.
109-58, Sec. 1291(b)(1), 119 Stat. 594, 984.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
47. With regard to large industrial customers who self-supply their
own load, while some of these entities may not technically ``sell * * *
electric energy,'' we construe them to be load serving entities for
purposes of this Final Rule, to ensure that Congress's objectives in
section 217 of the FPA are fulfilled. Thus, transmission organizations
should treat them as such when complying with this rule.
48. With regard to non-public utilities, the Commission notes that
the definition of electric utility discussed above, as amended by EPAct
2005, includes ``an entity described in section 201(f)'' of the FPA,
i.e. non-public utilities. As a result, they are within the definition
of load serving entity, provided, of course, that they have a service
obligation. Additionally, in response to California DWR and MWD, we
note that the definition of load serving entity provided by Congress
appears to already capture water pumping entities, which are non-public
utilities. New section 217(g) of the FPA provides that ``[t]he
Commission shall ensure that any entity described in section 201(f)
that owns transmission facilities used predominately to support its own
water pumping facilities shall have, with respect to the facilities,
protections for transmission service comparable to those provided to
load serving entities pursuant to this section.'' \37\ In light of this
Congressional
[[Page 43571]]
directive, we clarify, to the extent necessary, that water pumping
entities with the characteristics described in section 217(g) are load
serving entities for purposes of this Final Rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1291(b)(1), 119 Stat. 594, 984.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
49. MSATs request that we clarify that stand-alone transmission
companies are not load serving entities for purposes of this rule. We
clarify that as described by MSATs, stand-alone transmission companies
that do not own generation or distribution facilities, buy or sell
energy, serve loads or act as transmission customers are not load
serving entities for purposes of this Final Rule. We emphasize,
however, that this clarification should not be read broadly to suggest
that other types of stand-alone transmission companies (either existing
or that might be developed) with different characteristics from those
described by MSATs will not be load serving entities under this Final
Rule. The Commission will consider these issues on a case-by-case
basis, as necessary.
50. In response to those seeking clarifications regarding various
types of retail service providers, we note that many retail service
providers will be a ``person * * * that sells electric energy,'' thus
making it an electric utility and, consequently, they can be a load
serving entity provided they have a service obligation. The Commission
cannot decide here, however, whether each possible entity operating in
state retail electric markets will meet the definition of load serving
entity. We agree with NARUC, however, that Congress intended to broadly
protect the ability of load serving entities with service obligations
to obtain transmission service. Thus, transmission organizations should
ensure that different types of retail service providers that have
service obligations are accommodated when implementing the Final Rule.
51. As noted above, commenters raising issues regarding the
application of the service obligation definition in retail access
frameworks focus primarily on the default service obligation, which
generally (with variation from state-to-state) requires the entity
subject to that obligation to provide electric service to customers who
do not have another supplier (either because they did not choose one or
because their supplier left the market). Under the definition provided
by Congress, a default service obligation only becomes a service
obligation for purposes of this rule when the entity holding the
default obligation is actually required to serve the load, i.e. when
the competitive supplier either stops serving the load or the load
switches to the default supplier. A default service obligation only
becomes ``a requirement applicable to, or the exercise of authority
granted to'' the default supplier when it must actually serve the load.
We understand the concerns expressed by PG&E and others that a utility
holding the default service obligation must plan to serve that load
should it be required to do so in the future. Transmission organization
rules currently provide that auction revenue rights (ARRs) or FTRs will
generally ``follow the load'' in instances where load switches
suppliers; guideline (6), discussed below, also requires that long-term
firm transmission rights allocated to load serving entities be
reassignable. As a result, when default suppliers assume the service
obligation, they will receive transmission rights that they can use to
serve the default load. While we are aware that those transmission
rights may not match the resources that the default supplier will use
to serve the load, this is a problem that already exists today, and is
not a result of our adoption of Congress's definition of service
obligation. Transmission organizations may consider whether any rules
are necessary (such as allowing or requiring holders of long-term
transmission rights to turn back those rights for reallocation) to deal
with this problem.
52. We decline to revise the definitions of load serving entity and
service obligation to replace ``distribution utility or electric
utility'' and ``electric utility'' with ``an entity,'' as requested by
OMS. Congress chose to use these terms to limit these definitions, and
we are not persuaded to change them here, and do not believe such a
change is necessary to address OMS's concern. While OMS may be correct
that auction winners under Illinois' procurement mechanism may not meet
these definitions, the Illinois utilities that procure electric energy
under this mechanism and resell it to their customers (under their
service obligation) presumably meet the definitions of load serving
entity and service obligation, and thus should be able to obtain long-
term firm transmission rights to deliver that energy to load.
Similarly, we decline to define load serving entity to be only the
distribution utility, unless its service obligation has been
reassigned, as requested by EEI, or to be the distribution utility in
the first instance, as requested by National Grid. This would l