Rate Regulation of Certain Natural Gas Storage Facilities, 36612-36638 [06-5642]
Download as PDF
36612
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
Before Commissioners: Joseph T.
Kelliher, Chairman; Nora Mead
Brownell, and Suedeen G. Kelly
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
I. Introduction
18 CFR Part 284
[Docket Nos. RM05–23–000, AD04–11–000;
Order No. 678]
Rate Regulation of Certain Natural Gas
Storage Facilities
Issued June 19, 2006.
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission (Commission) is
amending its regulations to establish
criteria for obtaining market-based rates
for storage services offered under part
284. First, the Commission is modifying
its market-power analysis to better
reflect the competitive alternatives to
storage. Second, pursuant to the Energy
Policy Act of 2005, the Commission is
promulgating rules to implement new
section 4(f) of the Natural Gas Act, to
permit underground natural gas storage
service providers that are unable to
show that they lack market power to
negotiate market-based rates in
circumstances where market-based rates
are in the public interest and necessary
to encourage the construction of the
storage capacity in the area needing
storage services, and where customers
are adequately protected. These
revisions are intended to facilitate the
development of new natural gas storage
capacity while protecting customers.
DATES: Effective Date: The rule will
become effective July 27, 2006.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Sandra Delude, Office of the General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502–
8583.
Robert McLean, Office of General
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502–
8156.
Ed Murrell, Office of Energy Markets
and Reliability, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
(202) 502–8703.
Berne Mosley, Office of Energy Projects,
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502–
8625.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
1. The Final Rule reforms the
Commission’s current pricing policies to
ensure access to storage services on a
nondiscriminatory basis at just and
reasonable rates and to ensure that
sufficient storage capacity will be
available to meet anticipated increases
in market demand. To achieve these
goals, the Commission is modifying its
market-power analysis to permit the
consideration of close substitutes to
storage in defining the relevant product
market. This will ensure that marketbased rates are not denied because of an
overly narrow definition of the relevant
market. Second, the Commission is
adopting regulations implementing
section 312 of the Energy Policy Act of
2005 (EPAct 2005 or the Act),1 which
permits the Commission, in appropriate
circumstances, to authorize storage
providers to charge market-based rates
for service utilizing new capacity even
when the storage providers cannot (or
do not) demonstrate that they lack
market power. The revisions adopted in
the Final Rule are intended to facilitate
the development of new natural gas
storage capacity while protecting
customers.
II. Background
2. On August 8, 2005, EPAct 2005 was
signed into law. Section 312 of the Act,
adding a new section 4(f) to the Natural
Gas Act (NGA),2 permits the
Commission to allow a natural gas
storage service provider placing new
facilities in service to negotiate marketbased rates even if it is unable to show
that it lacks market power if the
Commission determines that marketbased rates are in the public interest and
necessary to encourage the construction
of the storage capacity in the area
needing storage services, and that
customers are adequately protected.3
3. The enactment of EPAct 2005
added momentum to efforts already
underway at the Commission to adopt
policy reforms that would encourage the
development of new natural gas storage
facilities while continuing to protect
consumers from the exercise of market
power. On September 30, 2004, the
Commission issued a staff report that
examined underground natural gas
1 Energy Policy Act of 2005, Pub. L. 109–58, 119
Stat. 594 (2005).
2 15 U.S.C. 717, et seq. (2000).
3 Energy Policy Act of 2005, Pub. L. 109–58,
section 312, 119 Stat. 594, 688 (2005).
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
storage.4 On October 21, 2004, the
Commission held a public conference
with representatives of the industry to
discuss the Staff Storage Report and
issues relevant to underground storage.5
The Commission received oral and
written comments in connection with
the Staff Storage Report and conference.
4. On December 22, 2005, the
Commission issued a notice of proposed
rulemaking (NOPR) in which it
proposed a two-prong approach for
reforming its current storage pricing
policy.6 First, the Commission proposed
modifications to its traditional marketpower analysis to permit the
consideration of close substitutes to
storage in defining the relevant product
market. Second, the Commission
proposed regulations to implement
section 312 of EPAct 2005 that permits
the Commission, in appropriate
circumstances, to authorize storage
providers to charge market-based rates
for service utilizing new capacity even
when the storage providers cannot (or
do not) demonstrate that they lack
market power.
5. The Commission received
numerous comments from a variety of
entities.7 Based on careful consideration
of the comments submitted in response
to the NOPR, the Commission adopts a
Final Rule that generally follows the
approach of the NOPR with certain
exceptions.
6. First, the Final Rule modifies the
Commission’s market-power analysis to
better reflect the competitive
alternatives to storage. Specifically, we
adopt a more expansive definition of the
relevant product market for storage to
explicitly include close substitutes for
gas storage services, including pipeline
capacity, local production, and liquefied
natural gas (LNG) supplies. The
Commission will evaluate potential
substitutes in the context of individual
applications for market-based rates. The
Final Rule eliminates the NOPR’s
requirement that storage providers
4 Current State of and Issues Concerning
Underground Natural Gas Storage, FERC Staff
Report, Docket No. AD04–11–000 (Sept. 30, 2004)
(Staff Storage Report).
5 State of the Natural Gas Industry Conference,
Docket No. PL04–17–000, October 21, 2004; see
State of Natural Gas Industry Conference; Staff
Report on Natural Gas Storage; Notice of Public
Conference, 69 FR 59917 (Oct. 6, 2004)
(summarizing the issues to be discussed at the
conference).
6 Rate Regulation of Certain Underground Storage
Facilities, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 70 FR
77079 (Dec. 22, 2005), FERC Stats. & Regs.,
Regulations Preambles ¶ 32,595 (Dec. 29, 2005).
7 A list of the commentors is included as an
appendix to this Final Rule. We have not
considered the supplemental reply comments filed
by INGAA on May 31, 2006, due to the lateness of
the filing.
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
granted market-based rates on the basis
of a market power analysis file updated
market-power analyses every five years.
Instead, storage providers with market
shares of ten percent or less would
generally be exempt from such a
requirement. We will consider in
individual cases whether the specific
facts and circumstances presented
require additional reporting for other
storage providers.
7. Second, the Final Rule adopts
regulations implementing section 312 of
EPAct 2005, which permits the
Commission to authorize market-based
rates even if a lack of market power has
not been demonstrated, in
circumstances where market-based rates
are in the public interest and necessary
to encourage the construction of storage
capacity in the area needing storage
services and that customers are
adequately protected. Finding that the
definition of facilities eligible for
treatment under new NGA section 4(f) is
ambiguous, the Commission defines
‘‘facilities’’ as it traditionally has for
purposes of the certification
requirements of section 7(c). However,
to receive market-based rate
authorization, the storage provider will
still need to satisfy the other
requirements of section 4(f).
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
III. Need and Purpose for the Rule
8. The underground storage of natural
gas is critical in assuring that overall
demands and specific requirements of
natural gas customers are met.
Currently, there are approximately 200
storage facilities subject to the
Commission’s jurisdiction, with an
aggregate working gas capacity of
approximately 2.5 Tcf. Estimates of total
domestic working gas capacity (both
subject to and exempt from NGA
jurisdiction) range up to 4.7 Tcf.8
Considering future storage needs of the
United States and Canada together, the
National Petroleum Council (NPC)
estimates an additional 700 Bcf will be
required by 2025.9 Although current
8 The Department of Energy’s Energy Information
Administration (EIA) reports that in 2002 working
gas storage capacity varied between 4.4 and 4.7 Tcf,
whereas the Department of Energy’s Office of Fossil
Energy reports that in 2003 there were 415
underground storage facilities with a working gas
capacity of 3.9 Tcf. The Staff Storage Report
considered the range of estimated aggregate existing
working gas and concluded that the present
working gas capacity is 3.5 Tcf, of which 2.5 Tcf
is subject to NGA jurisdiction, and that by
improving existing storage reservoirs (i.e., by
reengineering existing facilities to enhance
efficiency, rather than by expanding cavern
capacity), there is the potential to obtain another
200 to 500 Bcf. See Staff Storage Report at 7–10.
9 Balancing Natural Gas Policy—Fueling the
Demands of a Growing Economy, NPC, Volume II
at 261 (2003).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
and projected storage development is
keeping pace with aggregate national
storage demands, underground storage
development in some market areas, such
as New England 10 and the Southwest, is
not.11
9. Over the last several years, there
has been a marked increase in the cost
of natural gas and sharp swings in gas
prices. Storage can have a moderating
influence on gas prices. As a physical
hedge, customers can build up
underground inventories during times
of lower demand, and then rely on these
supply stores to avoid paying high spot
market gas prices. Among the key
findings highlighted by the Staff Storage
Report is that the ‘‘continued
commodity price volatility indicates
that more storage may be appropriate’’
and that storage ‘‘may be the best way
of managing gas commodity price, so
the long-term adequacy of storage
investment depends on how much price
volatility customers consider
‘acceptable.’ ’’ 12
10. In consideration of these factors,
the Commission is amending its
regulatory policies in the Final Rule in
order to facilitate the development of
new natural gas storage capacity to
ensure that adequate storage capacity
will be available to meet anticipated
market demand and to mitigate natural
gas price volatility, while continuing to
protect consumers from the exercise of
market power.
IV. Discussion
A. Market-Power Test
11. The Commission evaluates
requests to charge market-based rates for
storage services under the analytical
framework of its 1996 Policy Statement
on Alternatives to Traditional Cost-ofService Ratemaking for Natural Gas
Pipelines and Regulation of Negotiated
Transportation Services of Natural Gas
Pipelines (Policy Statement).13 In the
NOPR, the Commission observed that in
applying its market-concentration and
market-share screens in these cases to
date, the Commission has looked only to
the availability of other storage
alternatives (in the relevant geographic
10 New England appears to have little geologic
potential for the development of underground
storage facilities.
11 See, e.g., Southwestern Gas Storage Technical
Conference, Docket No. AD03–11–000, Transcript at
23, lines 10–14 (Aug. 26, 2003).
12 Staff Storage Report, at 1 (Sept. 30, 2004).
13 Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines and
Regulation of Negotiated Transportation Services of
Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ¶ 61,076 (1996),
reh’g and clarification denied, 75 FERC ¶ 61,024
(1996), petitions denied and dismissed, Burlington
Resources Oil & Gas Co. v. FERC, 172 F.3d 918
(D.C. Cir. 1998).
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36613
market), in assessing whether a storage
provider can exercise significant market
power. Noting that its current approach
to analyzing market power may be too
limiting in some circumstances in
today’s natural gas markets, the
Commission proposed to reform its
market-power test for natural gas storage
operators to more accurately reflect the
competitive conditions in the market for
gas storage services. The Commission
proposed to adopt a more expansive
definition of the relevant product
market for storage to explicitly include
close substitutes for gas storage service,
such as appropriate combinations of
available pipeline capacity, and local
gas production or LNG terminals, on a
case-by-case basis in the context of
individual applications for marketbased rates. We posited that
consideration of these alternative
products will ensure that the
Commission’s market-power analysis
accurately reflects whether a storage
applicant is able to exercise significant
market power.
12. We explained that, as a general
matter, competition to a storage
provider can come from entities that
have the ability to deliver gas in the
same market as the storage facility. In
producing areas, storage may compete
with production or LNG supply, in
addition to other storage facilities. In
market areas, there may also be local
production or LNG available. In
addition, available pipeline capacity can
function as a close substitute by
delivering gas at peak times to compete
with storage. For these reasons, we
suggested it would be appropriate to
permit applicants to present evidence
that both available pipeline capacity
and local production/LNG supply in the
geographic market area can reasonably
be considered as alternative products to
storage services.
13. In addition, we suggested that firm
capacity available through capacity
release can be a good alternative in
appropriate circumstances. Under the
Commission’s capacity release
regulations, holders of firm capacity are
free to release the capacity to other
shippers, as well as to make bundled
sales at alternate delivery points.
Because of this flexibility, some portion
of firm, contracted-for capacity may
have a sufficiently elastic demand (a
willingness to re-sell firm capacity
when price rises) to serve as a good
alternative to an applicant’s storage
service. While pipeline capacity held by
a local distribution company (LDC) that
is needed to meet state-mandated
service obligations for captive retail
customers may not be considered a good
alternative during peak periods, LDCs
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36614
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
and marketers also serve industrial and
other customers under interruptible
contracts. That portion of the LDC’s
capacity might constitute a reasonable
alternative.
14. Moreover, we stated that, in some
circumstances, an applicant may be able
to show that even when firm capacity
on a pipeline is reserved for captive
customers, e.g., residential and small
commercial customers, potential
product or service substitution in
downstream markets might result in
capacity becoming available in
upstream markets to compete with
storage while captive customers
continued to be served. Under the
Commission’s open-access program,
competition in a downstream market
may create competition in upstream
markets, particularly due to Order No.
636’s requirement that pipelines
provide flexible receipt and delivery
points and segmentation including
backhaul. Thus, an LDC’s ability to buy
capacity from another pipeline or
storage facility or to purchase gas in the
downstream market may free it to
release upstream capacity to compete
with storage in the upstream market.
This ability to buy capacity from
another pipeline or storage facility or to
buy gas in the market area is present in
the large downstream markets in the
United States including California,
Chicago and the Northeast.
15. The Commission requested
comments on these alternatives, as well
as suggestions regarding other
approaches for quantifying the amount
of pipeline capacity that might be
available to compete with an applicant’s
storage services.
1. Expansion of the Product Market
Definition
Comments
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
16. A number of commentors
generally support the Commission’s
proposal to liberalize the Commission’s
market-power test for market-based rate
authorization by expanding the kinds of
storage alternatives that it will consider
in analyzing an applicant’s market
power with certain proposed changes
discussed below.14 They agree with the
Commission that available pipeline
capacity, capacity release, local gas
production and LNG terminals all may
serve as adequate substitutes for gas
storage in appropriate circumstances.
These commentors also state that they
14 Comments of INGAA, Northern Natural, Duke,
Williston Basin, the NiSource Pipelines, Dominion,
Sempra, DTE, NYPSC, Falcon, EnCana, Bridgeline,
Unocal, Enstor and Jefferson Storage. The full
names of commentors and the abbreviations used in
this document are shown in the appendix.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
believe that the Commission’s proposal
should provide further incentives for
the development of new natural gas
storage capacity that will improve gas
service reliability and promote price
stability in the future. The NYPSC
agrees with the Commission that local
gas production, pipeline capacity and
LNG potentially can be offered as
alternatives to storage service but
requests the Commission to adhere to
the case-by-case approach and to allow
for consideration of whether there are
realistic alternatives available on a firm
and long-term basis.
17. On the other hand, several
commentors oppose changes to the
current market-power standards on
grounds that liberalizing these standards
is unnecessary and potentially harmful
to customers. AGA, APGA, NGSA, SGR
and UET all question whether the
proposed changes would actually
encourage meaningful development of
new storage facilities. APGA questions
the NOPR’s assumption that a storage
capacity shortage exists. APGA states
that while the NOPR discusses the
upcoming need for an additional 700
Bcf of storage capacity by 2025, the
NOPR does not suggest, much less
demonstrate, that the need will not be
fulfilled. NGSA submits that there is
little evidence to suggest that the
Commission’s current pricing policies
have had a major influence on
developers’ decisions to move forward
with potential storage projects. Rather,
NGSA contends that there are
multitudes of technical and commercial
factors that influence a potential storage
developer’s decision to build storage
that are equal or paramount to the
Commission’s regulatory pricing
policies including geological
limitations, environmental requirements
and NIMBY issues.
18. AGA and SGR assert that the
proposed changes would simply
provide existing storage providers the
opportunity to charge higher prices for
services already available to the market
and create opportunities for crosssubsidies between storage and
transportation services. AGA also fears
that liberalizing the market-power
standards would vastly increase the
scope and complexity of the marketpower determination, while APGA
submits that the NOPR’s proposal to
expand the definition of the relevant
product market for storage would
diminish substantially the showing
required to obtain market-based rates.
19. APGA also argues that the
proposal is inconsistent with the Policy
Statement that defines a ‘‘good
alternative’’ as one that must have the
same qualities of timeliness, price and
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
quality of the storage service it would
replace. Specifically, APGA submits
that pipeline capacity (and local
production/LNG and released capacity)
are not good alternatives, much less
‘‘close substitutes’’ in terms of quality of
service to the high deliverability storage
service that the NOPR seeks to promote.
Similarly, APGA argues that in terms of
price, pipeline capacity is not a good
alternative or close substitute to storage
service, because pipeline capacity is
more expensive than storage capacity.
20. NGSA submits that the expansion
of the relevant product market will not
provide customers with the equivalent
services uniquely offered by new storage
facilities and examining market
elasticity to determine whether product
substitution can occur in downstream
markets, as suggested in the NOPR, is
simply not realistic. NGSA and PGC
stress that the criteria and framework
that the Commission utilizes to review
market-based rate applications have
proven to be effective and flexible,
resulting in the approval of marketbased rates for the majority of
applicants. Moreover, NGSA points out
there are flexible cost-based rates
available to promote new storage
capacity without making wholesale
changes to the Commission’s exiting
market-power analysis. NGSA urges the
Commission to consider whether it
would be more appropriate instead to
adopt changes that will rectify the
unique problems identified in specific
regions by undertaking a generic
proceeding to: (1) Identify where new
storage capacity is needed; (2) document
known proposals in these regions; (3)
determine what specific obstacles may
exist; and (4) establish regulatory
policies to encourage additional storage
construction in those areas.
21. IPAA expresses concern with the
Commission’s proposal to adopt a more
expansive definition of the relevant
product market for storage to explicitly
include close substitutes for gas storage
services. IPAA urges the Commission to
carefully consider the potential impact
of this expanded definition of relevant
product market for storage on other costbased services regulated by the
Commission. (e.g., the regulation of
interstate pipeline transportation rates).
For example, IPAA states that if
pipeline capacity and released capacity
can serve as possible substitutes for
competing storage, then the potential
exists for storage to serve as a substitute
for the availability of competing
pipeline capacity in evaluating
applications for market-based
transportation rates. IPAA states it most
likely would have concern with efforts
to expand the acceptance of market-
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
based transportation rates. Thus, IPAA
strongly encourages the Commission to
consider the effect the expanded
definition of relevant product market
could have on all services under the
Commission’s jurisdiction, not just
within the confines of an individual
application by a storage operator. NGSA
requests that the Commission clarify
that these changes will not be used for
the future evaluation of market power
for interstate transportation services but
only for new storage facilities as it has
proposed for the EPAct 2005 provisions.
22. UET asserts that the Commission
has not demonstrated that the proposed
change in the market-power analysis is
needed to reduce natural gas price
volatility because price volatility is
mitigated on a national, as opposed to
a regional basis, and storage
development is keeping pace with
national demands. UET also argues the
proposed change is not necessary to
solve regional storage capacity shortages
in underserved markets such as New
England and the Southwest, because
proposals for new storage in these areas
have failed for reasons other than rate
treatment. Finally, UET asserts that the
proposed rule is not necessary to cater
to power generation load because the
Commission is able to meet the needs of
power generation customers by
developing rate designs that would
permit storage operators to earn higher
revenues from short-term services
during peak periods.
23. UET also maintains that changing
the market-power analysis as proposed
could discourage rather than encourage
expansion of existing storage facilities.
It asserts that cost-based rates treat the
storage company fairly and also enable
storage customers to participate
sufficiently in the natural gas value
chain that runs from the wellhead to the
burner tip. UET alleges that marketbased rates may disrupt the value chain
to such an extent that potential storage
customers, particularly marketers, will
simply choose to exit the market rather
than serve as the vehicle for funneling
market-based rate revenues to storage
providers. Thus, UET maintains that
storage projects, for which there is a
demand at cost-based rates, may not be
built because the demand is not there
for a project that would qualify for
market-based rates under the relaxed
proposed standards. In addition, noting
that price volatility has increased as the
number of major marketers has
decreased, UET urges the Commission
to exercise care in embracing marketbased rates to encourage new storage in
the name of price volatility mitigation
when those rates may actually increase
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
price volatility by further decreasing the
number of marketers.
24. Finally, AGA, NGSA and Process
Consumers argue that the NOPR is
unnecessary given the alternative of
section 4(f) of the NGA. For example,
AGA asserts that the proposed
regulations pursuant to new NGA
section 4(f) fully address the need to
provide incentives for new storage
services and there is no need to provide
more latitude for qualifying for marketbased rates for existing storage facilities.
At most, AGA asserts the Commission
should considering broadening the
market-power test only after it has had
an opportunity to assess the impact and
outcome of the new rules under section
4(f), a minimum of two years after
implementing regulations under section
4(f). Similarly, NGSA while supporting
the Commission’s goal of maximizing
storage believes that liberalizing the
traditional market-power test is
unsupported and unnecessary. Given
that Congress enacted EPAct 2005 as the
primary vehicle to encourage the
development of new storage facilities,
NGSA urges the Commission to focus its
attention in this proceeding on properly
implementing EPAct 2005, and not
engaging in an unnecessary effort to
provide incentives for new storage by
revising the existing market-power test.
At a minimum, NGSA urges the
Commission to take an incremental
approach and maintain the existing
market-power procedures, at least until
it can assess whether its implementation
of the EPAct 2005 provisions can
provide a sufficient and workable
program that provides a valid incentive
to potential new storage developers.
Commission Determination
25. The Commission finds it is
appropriate to adopt a more expansive
definition of the relevant product
market for storage to explicitly include
close substitutes for gas storage services,
including pipeline capacity and local
production/LNG supplies. As explained
below, this modification to our marketpower analysis better reflects the
competitive alternatives to storage and
is supported by changes in the natural
gas markets that have occurred since the
mid 1990s. In today’s markets, these
non-storage products may well serve as
adequate substitutes for gas storage in
appropriate circumstances.
26. As we explained in Order No. 637,
the deregulation of wellhead natural gas
prices, the advent of open-access
transportation and the requirement that
interstate pipelines offer unbundled
open-access transportation service, has
increased competition and efficiency in
both the gas commodity and
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36615
transportation market.15 Market centers
have developed both upstream in the
production area and downstream in the
market area, providing shippers with
greater gas and capacity choices. The
wholesale market has grown with new
participants that have the ability to
deliver gas into many markets. The
expansion of the product market
definition to include close substitutes
simply recognizes that buyers and
sellers have a greater number of
alternatives from which to choose in
order to obtain and deliver gas supplies.
From an end-use customer’s
perspective, gas is fungible, whether it
comes from storage, local production or
more distant supplies transported by
pipelines. Competition with storage can
come from any of these sources that can
deliver gas in the same market as the
storage facility. For these reasons, we
will permit a storage applicant to
include non-storage products and
services, including pipeline capacity
and local production/LNG supply in the
calculation of its market concentration
and market share.
27. The Commission recognizes,
however, that local production, LNG
and pipeline capacity may not be good
alternatives to an applicant’s storage
services in all circumstances. For a nonstorage product to be a good alternative
it must be available soon enough, have
a price low enough and have a quality
high enough to permit customers to
substitute the alternative for the
applicant’s services. For this reason, we
will evaluate potential substitutes in the
context of individual applications for
market-based rates. In those
proceedings, the applicant will have the
burden to demonstrate that the nonstorage products and services, as well as
the other storage services, used in its
calculation of market concentration and
market share are good substitutes. Any
party to the proceeding can challenge
the inclusion of a particular product on
the grounds that it does not meet the
qualifications for a good alternative.
Based on the record in the proceeding,
the Commission will determine if the
proposed product is in fact a good
alternative that will limit the exercise of
significant market power by the
applicant.
28. In the NOPR, we noted that
although current and projected storage
development is keeping pace with
aggregate demands, underground
storage development in some market
15 Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services and Regulation of
Interstate Natural Gas Transportation Services,
Order No. 637, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations
Preambles (July 1996–December 2000) ¶ 31,091 at
31,249–63 (Feb. 9, 2000).
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36616
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
areas, such as New England and the
Southwest, is not.16 We also
acknowledged that our rate policies will
not guarantee the proliferation of new
storage projects because storage projects
fail to for reasons other than rate
treatment.17 A few commentors claim
that the proposed expansion of the
product market is not supported
because we have not shown that a
storage capacity shortage exists or that
market-based rates will ensure that
storage gets built. We disagree that such
findings are necessary to support the
proposed change to our market-power
analysis. The courts have permitted the
Commission to institute flexible pricing
to improve market efficiency so long as
the overall regulatory scheme protects
against the exercise of market power
and protects and results in just and
reasonable rates.18 Where the
Commission determines that an
applicant lacks market power, the
Commission may depart from a strictly
cost-based determination of rates, and
approve rates reached as the result of
competition. The Commission’s
authority to approve market-based rates
has been approved by the courts when
the Commission has found sufficient
protection against the exercise of market
power.19
29. The Commission finds that its
proposed regulatory change will protect
against the exercise of market power. In
analyzing market-based rate storage
proposals, the Commission will
continue to addresses whether the
applicant has market power; that is, can
the applicant: (1) Withhold or restrict
services to increase price a significant
amount for a significant period of time,
or (2) discriminate unduly in terms of
price or conditions. Before the
Commission can conclude that a seller
cannot exercise market power it must
either: (1) Find that there is a lack of
market power because customers have
sufficient ‘‘good alternatives,’’ or (2)
mitigate the market power (i.e. permit
market-based pricing only if specified
conditions are met that prevent the
exercise of market power). The only
change the Commission is adopting in
this Final Rule is to recognize that in
today’s market, a storage applicant’s
ability to exercise market power can be
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
16 NOPR
at P 8.
17 Id. at P 14.
18 Environmental Action v. FERC, 996 F.2d 401,
410 (D.C. Cir. 1993).
19 Elizabethtown Gas Co. v. FERC, 10 F.3d 866,
870–71 (D.C. 1993) (Elizabethtown); Louisiana
Energy and Power Authority v. FERC, 141 F.3d 364,
369–370 (D.C. Cir. 1998); Interstate Natural Gas
Association of America v. FERC, 285 F.3d 18, 31–
34 ((D.C. Cir.) 2002); California ex rel. Lockyer v.
FERC, 383 F.3d 1006, 1013–1014 (9th Cir. 2004).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
constrained not only by other storage
services but also by some combination
of pipeline and other gas supply
alternatives.
30. Similarly, we do not share
commentors’ views that we should not
adopt the proposed revisions to the
product market definition because it
may result in more complex
proceedings or that there are flexible
cost-based rates available to storage
providers. The Commission’s proposal
is justified because it better reflects the
competitive alternatives to storage.
31. We also find that commentors’
assertion that our action here will
inappropriately raise rates ignores the
connection recognized by the courts
between competition and just and
reasonable rates. In Elizabethtown, the
court concluded that because of the
competition in the pipeline’s sales
market it appeared that the pipeline
would not be able to raise its price
above the competitive level without
losing substantial business to other
sellers. ‘‘Such market discipline
provides strong reason to believe that
Transco will be able to charge only a
price that is ‘just and reasonable’ within
the meaning of section 4 of the NGA.’’ 20
Granting market-based rates in
situations where there are sufficient
alternatives prevents the exercise of
significant market power. A new entrant
found to lack market power offers
another choice to existing customers,
and in the Commission’s experience,
more choice frequently leads to lower,
not higher, rates.
32. We also reject commentors’ claim
that Congress’ enactment of section 312
of EPAct 2005 bars the Commission
from expanding the product market
definition for storage applicants seeking
a finding that the applicant does not
possess market power. These
commentors fail to cite to any provision
in section 312 of the Act that suggests
Congress intended to limit in any way
the Commission’s ability to revise or
modify its traditional market-power
analysis. Rather in section 312, Congress
established an alternative procedure to
permit storage service providers that are
unable to show that they lack market
power to negotiate market-based rates if
the Commission determines that marketbased rates are in the public interest, are
necessary to encourage needed storage
infrastructure and that customers are
adequately protected. The Commission
finds it is reasonable to proceed under
both prongs.
33. As to IPAA’s and NGSA’s concern
that our actions here not prejudge the
issue of whether storage can serve as a
20 10
PO 00000
F.3d 866, at 871 (D.C. Cir. 1993).
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
substitute for the availability of
competing pipeline capacity in
evaluating applications for market-based
transportation rates, we clarify that it is
not our intent. Our actions here only
address what non-storage products may
be considered a good alternative to
storage services, and should not be
construed to address what products may
be considered a good alternative to
transportation services.
34. Finally, we do not share UET’s
views that our action here will
negatively impact the number of
marketers. Marketers, too, will have
choices in contracting for service from
a newly authorized storage service
provider authorized to charge marketbased rates and, as discussed above, the
price will remain just and reasonable
within the meaning of section 4 of the
NGA due to the absence of significant
market power.
2. Scope of Applicability of Expanded
Product Market Definition
Comments
35. Bay Gas requests that the
Commission revise proposed § 284.501,
Applicability, to clarify that the newly
proposed subpart M requirements do
not apply automatically to previouslyordered market-based rate
authorizations. Specifically, Bay Gas
requests that the Commission add the
following language to the end of that
section: ‘‘provided, if such pipeline or
storage service provider was authorized
to charge market-based rates before
subpart M effective date, it need not
conform under that authorization to
subpart M.’’
36. Should the Commission decide to
adopt its proposal to expand the
product market, AGA and NGSA urge
the Commission to expressly limit the
application of any revised market-power
regulations to new storage capacity
rather than to existing storage capacity
that is currently subject to cost-based
rates.
37. NiSource Pipelines request that
the Commission clarify whether existing
storage providers are permitted to seek
market-based rate authority using the
proposed modified market-power
analysis.
Commission Determination
38. As requested by Bay Gas, we
clarify that applicants previously
granted market-based rates need not
resubmit an application under the
broader definition of product market we
are adopting in the Final Rule. If an
applicant has demonstrated a lack of
market power under the traditional
definition of product market, it follows
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
that the applicant would qualify for
market-based rates using an expanded
definition of product market that
includes additional substitutes.
However, we do not agree that a
revision to the regulatory text is
necessary.
39. We find that NGSA and AGA have
provided no support for their request to
limit the applicability of the expanded
product market definition to only new
storage capacity. Pursuant to the Policy
Statement, an entity can file an
application for market-based rates for
storage services if it can demonstrate
that it does not have significant market
power or has sufficiently mitigated that
market power. Where a company can
show a lack of market power, then
competition in the market will ensure
that the company’s rates will be just and
reasonable and the purpose of the NGA
is met. Accordingly, existing storage
providers are permitted to seek marketbased rate authority using the proposed
modified market-power analysis.
However, the Commission will consider
in the case of existing storage all
relevant facts of the applicant’s
potential to exercise market power,
including for example, impacts on
existing customers and the applicant’s
relationship with transmission service
providers in the relevant market.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
3. Determination and Quantification of
a Good Alternative
40. In order to show that a non-storage
product or service such as
transportation is a good alternative, the
Commission stated that the storage
applicant would need to meet the
criteria set forth in the Commission’s
Policy Statement. A good alternative is
one that is available soon enough, has
a price that is low enough, and has a
quality high enough to permit customers
to substitute the alternative for the
applicant’s services.
Comments
41. SCE stresses that the Commission
needs to adopt an analysis that is as
robust as its analysis of the electric
markets and takes into consideration the
interdependence of gas and electric
markets’ competitiveness. SCE urges the
Commission to seriously examine the
limits on ‘‘substitutability’’ among the
various products in each market, noting
the complex dynamic relationships
involved in determining this. SCE states
that storage serves three basic functions:
price arbitrage, balancing and peak
reliability, and customers consider
different kinds of storage and
transportation products to perform each
function. Thus, each alternate product
must be examined in the context of its
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
ability to provide competitive discipline
on the operation of an applicant’s
storage facility. Depending on the
market structure, SCE asserts that some
facilities or products may only be able
to perform one of the three storage
functions while others might serve all of
these functions. In addition, SCE
stresses that the Commission also must
be willing to examine whether, and the
extent to which, an exercise of market
power in the storage market may
ultimately result in supracompetitive
prices elsewhere in the gas markets, i.e.,
other geographic markets or other
products.
42. Enstor urges the Commission to
provide more clarity as to what is, and
is not, a good alternative, and how a
market-based rate applicant can
demonstrate the same. In addition,
Enstor seeks further Commission
amplification on whether an alternative
is ‘‘available.’’ For example, Enstor asks
in regards to LNG terminals in service,
will availability depend on the
terminals’ capacity or their
deliverability?
43. EEI supports the Commission’s
proposal to include alternatives to
storage in its market-power analysis. EEI
submits that this analysis is fact specific
and should be applied in the context of
the region of the country and the users
that would be supplied by the proposed
storage services. With regard to released
capacity as a competitive alternative to
storage, EEI asserts that the applicant
should be required to demonstrate that
there is a viable market in released
capacity. In making this determination,
EEI urges the Commission to rely on
historic information on the extent of
trading in released capacity on a
relevant pipeline because such
information is a better indicator of
substitutes for storage service than a
theoretical analysis of possible releases
in the future.
44. With respect to quantifying firm
transportation capacity that could be
available to compete with an applicant’s
storage service, DTE recommends that
all firm transportation capacity on all
pipeline systems that serve the
applicant’s geographic market that is not
committed to meeting the statemandated obligation of LDCs to serve
captive customers be considered as
available to compete with the
applicant’s storage services, particularly
during swing periods when
deliverability is most critical. DTE
explains that capacity not under LDC
contract is generally held by marketers,
end users, and producers who are in a
position to divert gas on short notice
from contractual primary delivery
points to higher-valued markets in
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36617
response to rapidly changing market
conditions.
45. Given that non-LDC shippers are
in the best position to respond to swings
in the market and control where gas is
delivered, DTE recommends that firm
transportation capacity be quantified on
a shipper-by-shipper basis for the
purpose of calculating swing period
deliverability market shares and a
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI).
Under this approach, each pipeline
shipper would be considered a potential
competitor to the applicant. On the
other hand, DTE claims that marketpower studies should not assume that
pipelines control deliverability and can
use shipper deliverability to respond to
market swings in a manner and time
period that is competitive with storage.
That is, pipeline deliverability should
not be quantified and assigned to each
individual pipeline for the purpose of
calculating market shares and HHIs.
Pipelines are purely transporters and are
not in a position to divert gas on short
notice to higher valued markets in
response to changes in market
conditions.
46. DTE agrees with the Commission’s
statement in the NOPR that to the extent
an LDC holds pipeline capacity in order
to meet state-mandated service
obligations to captive customers, it is
not likely that such pipeline capacity
would be available to respond to market
needs nor would it be a good substitute
for storage capacity and deliverability.
Similarly, DTE urges the Commission to
exclude storage capacity and
deliverability associated with storage
fields owned by LDCs and used to meet
state-mandated service obligations to
captive customers from market share
and HHI calculations contained in
market-power studies submitted by
applicants seeking market-based rates.
DTE states that like firm transportation
used to meet LDC market needs, firm
storage capacity and deliverability
associated with storage fields owned by
LDCs are committed to meet captive
retail customer needs and should not be
considered available to the market to
meet changing economic conditions.
Commission Determination
47. As we have stated above, we
intend to continue to evaluate requests
for market-based rates for storage on a
case-by-case basis. An applicant is
required to identify ‘‘the specific
products or services and the suppliers of
those products and services that provide
good alternatives to the applicant’s
ability to exercise market power.21 A
21 Policy
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
Statement at 61,230–231.
27JNR2
36618
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
good alternative has been defined as one
that is available soon enough, has a
price that is low enough, and has a
quality high enough to permit customers
to substitute the alternative for the
applicant’s service. The burden is on the
applicant to ‘‘show how each of the
substitute services in the product
market are adequate substitutes to the
applicant’s service in terms of quality,
price, and availability.’’ 22 Therefore, we
will not endorse any particular method
for determining the substitutability of a
product here, but rather base our
determination on the record developed
in individual proceedings. Regarding
Enstor’s request that we clarify whether
the availability of LNG terminal service
will depend on the terminal’s capacity
or deliverability, we find that both
elements would be relevant in analyzing
the availability of LNG supply.
48. In order for an applicant to show
that non-storage products are a good
alternative to storage, they must
demonstrate that for peak demand
periods customers will be able to choose
the non-storage product as a comparable
substitute for storage services offered by
the applicant. This demonstration must
show that in terms of quality,
timeliness, and price that non-storage
products will be able to serve
customers’ needs as well as storage
service. For example, an applicant may
be able to demonstrate that pipeline
capacity in combination with spot
market purchases and appropriate
financial market instruments, such as
futures contracts, can reasonably be
expected to be available at prices
competitive with storage service so that
it can act as a substitute for storage gas
purchased, stored and/or redelivered
when needed. Applicants may also be
able to show that available park and
loan services or liquid market-center
spot markets provide sufficient liquidity
during peak periods to constitute an
adequate substitute to storage for
balancing purposes or to serve peak
demand.
4. Additional Revisions to MarketPower Test
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
a. Inclusion of Other Gas Supply
Alternatives in the Product Market
Comments
49. In addition to the pipeline
capacity and LNG supply identified by
the Commission in its NOPR, Duke
urges the Commission to recognize that
other gas supply alternatives may be
available in a given market, such as
financial instruments, that can compete
with storage. Duke explains that storage
22 Id.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
allows a consumer of natural gas to
manage price risk by allowing the
consumer to choose a price at which to
buy natural gas, store it, and then
withdraw that gas as needed. According
to Duke, there are an increasing number
of financial instruments that can be
used to manage this same natural gas
price risk. Williston Basin claims that
other types of alternatives may exist as
well, and accordingly market-based rate
applications should be looked at
individually, to determine what types of
alternatives are available.
Commission Determination
50. As discussed above, we will
continue to evaluate requests for
market-based rates on a case-by-case
basis. An applicant may propose to
include other non-storage products as
alternatives to storage services to the
extent it can demonstrate the proposed
alternatives can be delivered into the
relevant geographic market and
otherwise meet the criteria of a good
alternative.
b. Modification to HHI Threshold
51. Under the Policy Statement, the
Commission’s initial screening tool for
significant market power is the HHI, a
formula that focuses on the relevant
market’s concentration as an indicator
of the potential of an applicant to act
together with other sellers to raise
prices.23 The Commission uses an HHI
of 1,800 as an indicator of the level of
scrutiny to be given to an applicant for
market-based rates. An HHI at this level
indicates that there are four to five good
alternatives to the applicant’s service in
the relevant market. An HHI below
1,800 suggests limited market
concentration with less potential for any
participant to exercise significant
market power. However, an HHI above
1,800 suggests a higher level of
concentration, and will cause the
Commission to increase its scrutiny of
other factors such as the applicant’s
market share, ease of entry into the
market, the relative size of the
applicant’s capacity, and/or the
sustainability of a potential attempt by
the applicant to exercise market
power.24
Comments
52. INGAA and KM urge the
Commission to adopt an HHI level of
2,500 rather than the 1,800 that it
23 The HHI is the sum of the squared market
shares. For example, in a market with five equal
size firms, each would have a 20 percent market
share. For that market, HHI = (20)2 + (20)2 + (20)2
+ (20)2 + (20)2 = 400 + 400 + 400 + 400 + 400 =
2,000.
24 Policy Statement at 61,235–36.
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
currently employs as a benchmark for
measuring market concentration.
INGAA asserts the current level is far
too conservative and is inconsistent
with standards recommended by the
Antitrust Division of the Department of
Justice (DOJ) for analogous oil pipeline
cases.
53. KM asserts that the Commission’s
reliance on the 1,800 HHI level
inappropriately relies on the DOJ’s and
the Federal Trade Commission’s (FTC)
Horizontal Merger Guidelines (Merger
Guidelines) which apply to merger cases
where two companies are merging and
the number of competitors is reduced.
KM argues that the 1,800 threshold is
too conservative as applied to potential
new storage entrants seeking marketbased rates because, in this situation,
the number of competitors will be
increasing and the Commission will
exercise regulatory oversight. KM also
points out that the Commission applies
the 2,500 threshold to oil pipelines
where there is no merger issue and the
adoption of that threshold was
supported by DOJ in filed comments.
Similarly, KM argues the Commission
should adopt a 2,500 HHI threshold for
applicants seeking market-based rate
authority for gas pipelines where
continued regulation of an industry
rather than a merger is at issue. KM also
asserts that adherence to the 1,800 HHI
threshold is at odds with the actual DOJ
and FTC enforcement decisions
regarding horizontal merger review,
where it states that out of 11,263
challenges initiated by the agencies,
only 175 involved markets with HHIs
under 2,500.25
54. Finally, KM asserts that in today’s
markets, purchasers of storage capacity
are generally large LDCs or even larger
and more powerful marketing arms of
large producers and the presence of this
buyer power is not accounted for in the
Commission’s HHI analysis. According
to KM, use of a higher initial screen
would partially take into account other
factors such as buying power.
Commission Determination
55. We are not persuaded by the
commentors’ arguments that there is a
need to change the HHI threshold level.
Significantly, as recognized by KM and
INGAA, the 1,800 HHI level is not a
bright-line test below which an
applicant would automatically qualify
for market-based rates, or above which
an applicant would be excluded from
market-based rates. Rather, the
Commission uses the 1,800 HHI level as
25 Citing Federal Trade Commission and the U.S.
Department of Justice, Merger Challenges Data,
Fiscal years 1999–2003, December 18, 2003.
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
an indicator of the level of scrutiny to
be given to the applicant. As explained
in the Policy Statement, if the HHI is
above 1,800 the Commission will give
the applicant closer scrutiny because
the index indicates that the market is
more concentrated and the applicant
may have significant market power.
Conversely, an HHI below 1,800 would
result in less scrutiny of the applicant’s
potential to exercise significant market
power because it would indicate that
the market is less concentrated.26 The
Commission has applied this policy in
its analysis of individual cases and has
approved market-based rates for several
applicants with HHIs above 1,800 after
examining other competitive factors. For
example, in Avoca Natural Gas Storage
(Avoca),27 the Commission approved
market-based rates despite an HHI for
deliverability of 4,100 in the relevant
New York/Pennsylvania market,
specifically noting the small size of
Avoca’s market share and the apparent
ease of entry into the market as factors
mitigating the market concentration
reflected in the HHI.28
56. We disagree with INGAA’s and
KM’s assertion that the 1,800 HHI level
is too conservative. First of all, it is not
true that applicants seeking marketbased rates will always increase the
number of competitors in a market. For
example, a storage provider may apply
for market-based rates for existing costbased service. More importantly, we
believe that use of the more
conservative approach will ensure that
the impact of other competitive factors
will be given careful scrutiny when the
market is relatively concentrated (less
than four or five good alternatives). In
addition, contrary to KM’s assertion, we
have not adopted a generic 2,500 HHI
level in analyzing whether an oil
pipeline has market power.29 Moreover,
the use of HHI levels in determining
whether an oil pipeline has market
power in individual cases reflects the
specific competitive circumstances
affecting oil pipelines. Specifically, oil
pipelines face competition not only
26 Policy
Statement at 61,235.
FERC ¶ 61,045 (1994).
28 The Commission reached a similar result
analyzing storage services in Steuben Gas Storage
Co., 72 FERC ¶ 61,102 (1995); New York State
Electric and Gas Corp., 81 FERC ¶ 61,020 (1997);
N.E. Hub Partners, L.P., 83 FERC ¶ 61,043 (1998);
Seneca Lake Storage, Inc., 98 FERC ¶ 61,163 (2002);
and Honeoye Storage Corp., 91 FERC ¶ 62,165
(2000).
29 Market-Based Ratemaking for Oil Pipelines,
Order No. 572, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,007 at
31,192 (Oct. 28, 1994) (‘‘[T]he Commission is not
proposing any particular HHI level, such as 1,800
or 2,500, as a screen or presumption, rebuttable or
otherwise. All factors must be considered in
determining whether an oil pipeline lacks
significant market power.’’).
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
27 68
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
from other oil pipeline providers but
also from other modes of delivering oil
such as rail, barges and trucks.30 In
general, there are not similar alternative
modes of delivering or storing natural
gas. Further, as common carriers, oil
pipelines operate in a different
regulatory context.
57. Additionally, we do not agree
with KM that a higher initial screen is
appropriate to take into account the fact
that purchasers of storage capacity are
generally large LDCs or marketing arms
of large producers. First of all, the
purchasers of storage services are not
always large LDCs and marketers and to
implement an analysis premised on the
assumption that they are is not
appropriate. Under the Policy Statement
we consider issues related to buyer
power separately (outside the context of
the HHI threshold) which permits the
Commissions to consider the specific
facts presented in a case. We find this
approach superior to the approach
advocated by KM.
c. Entry and Other Competitive Factors
Comments
58. Duke asserts that while the
inclusion of currently available
competitive alternatives in the
definition of the market for the purposes
of calculating market concentration and
market share values, as advocated
above, is a good starting point, such a
revision alone, while necessary, will not
address the barriers to development
faced by markets with little existing gas
supply infrastructure. To promote the
development of additional storage
infrastructure in these areas, Duke urges
the Commission to shift the overall
focus of its market-based rate analysis
away from requiring evidence of an
existing market to an analysis of the
extent to which a new entrant increases
the potential gas supply options
available to market participants. Duke
states the Commission’s market-based
rate policy should focus on: (1) Whether
the new entrant adds new storage
options to the market, and (2) whether
there are further opportunities for
additional entrants to take similar risks
and develop competitive storage. Duke
urges the Commission to adjust its
existing approach to focus less on the
status of existing competition and more
upon the potential benefits of adding
additional storage by: (1) Making it clear
that applicants may rely upon evidence
of potential developments of storage in
circumstances where there is little or no
existing competition, or (2) by making a
generic determinations concerning the
30 Id.
PO 00000
at 31,191.
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36619
potential competitiveness of particular
areas of the country.
Commission Determination
59. The Commission believes that the
analytical framework for establishing
market-based rates set forth in the Policy
Statement already adequately
accommodates other competitive factors
such as the ability of other entities to
enter the market. In the Policy
Statement, the Commission specifically
recognized that having a large market
share in a concentrated market does not
constitute market power if ease of entry
and other competitive factors can
prevent the applicant from exercising
significant market power.31 In a recent
order in Rendevous Gas Services, L.L.C.,
the Commission granted market-based
rates for hub transportation service
based on the ease of entry into the
market center and the fact that the
proposed pipeline was a new entrant
with no captive customers.32 Similarly,
when requesting market-based rates for
storage services, an applicant is
permitted to establish that it lacks
market power by demonstrating that if
it increases its price, ease of entry by
other providers into the market will
make such a price increase unprofitable.
Moreover, in response to Duke’s
assertion that we should focus more on
the benefits of new entry than market
concentration statistics, we recognize
that there are significant benefits to
competition and customers from new
storage and note that, under our policy,
HHI calculations of market
concentration are used as a screening
tool and are not dispositive of whether
we will grant a request for market-based
rates. Instead, we will consider all
relevant factors, including the benefits
of new entry, in determining whether to
approve market based rates. The
Commission will evaluate such
proposals on a case-by-case basis.
d. Definition of Geographic Market
Comments
60. DTE states that while the
Commission’s NOPR takes the
important step of presenting an
expanded definition for storage
substitutes, the NOPR does not clarify
how an applicant seeking to
demonstrate a lack of market power
31 Policy
Statement at 61,235.
Gas Services, L.L.C., order issuing
certificates, 112 FERC ¶ 61,141; reh’g. denied, 113
FERC ¶ 61,169 (2005). See also Avoca, 68 FERC
¶ 61,045 (1994); Steuben Gas Storage Co., 72 FERC
¶ 61,102 (1995); New York State Electric and Gas
Corp., 81 FERC ¶ 61,020 (1997); N.E. Hub Partners,
L.P., 83 FERC ¶ 61,043 (1998); Seneca Lake Storage,
Inc., 98 FERC ¶ 61,163 (2002); and Honeoye Storage
Corp., 91 FERC ¶ 62,165 (2000).
32 Rendevous
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36620
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
should define its geographic market.
DTE seeks Commission guidance as to
how to define the relevant geographic
storage market in order to provide more
certainty to an applicant seeking
market-based rates for new storage
capacity in more competitive markets
needing new capacity or improved
service flexibility. DTE recommends
that, in developing a geographic market
definition for a market power study, the
Commission should base its geographic
market definition on the ability of
storage customers to access storage
providers in various regions. In
addition, DTE argues that customer
access to alternative storage providers
can be confirmed by reviewing the
applicant’s potential shippers or
shippers accessed by comparably
located and situated storage providers,
for example, as shown in a shipper
index.
Commission Determination
61. In the Policy Statement, the
Commission provided guidance on
defining the geographic market. In
general, the relevant geographic is the
geographic area containing those
suppliers that can affect any attempt by
the applicant to exercise market power.
Since we are not changing the
geographic definition in the Final Rule,
the Policy Statement’s guidance
regarding the geographic market is still
applicable.
e. Treatment of Affiliate Capacity
62. In § 284.503(b)(4) we proposed to
codify our current practice 33 that
capacity on pipeline systems owned or
controlled by the applicant’s affiliates
should not be considered among the
customers’ alternatives and should be
included in the market share calculated
for the applicant.
Comments
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
63. A number of commentors request
that the Commission amend its
proposed regulations in § 284.503(b) to
eliminate the requirement that the
capacity of a market-based rate
applicant’s affiliates is automatically to
be included in the market share
calculated for the applicant.34 They
argue that this requirement is
unnecessary in light of the
Commission’s Standards of Conduct for
Transmission Providers promulgated in
Order No. 2004 which requires
interstate pipelines to function
33 See Policy Statement, 74 FERC ¶ 61,076 at
61,234 (1996).
34 Comments of INGAA, Dominion, Duke,
NiSource Pipelines, Dominion LDCs and Jefferson
Storage.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
independently from their affiliates.35
For example, Dominion submits that
Order No. 2004 is a comprehensive and
effective regulatory regime governing
the relationship between a pipeline and
its energy affiliates such that there is no
realistic possibility for an interstate
pipeline with storage and its affiliates
with storage assets to collude to exercise
market power in the provision of storage
services. Additionally, INGAA states the
Commission’s rules regarding price
transparency, and the requirement that
an open-access pipeline must make all
capacity publicly available, under the
terms, conditions, and rates specified in
the tariff, provide further assurances
that a storage applicant cannot control
or manipulate the capacity of its
affiliated companies.
64. Several commentors also maintain
that the notion that capacity held by an
affiliated company cannot provide a
competitive alternative is inconsistent
with the Commission’s open-access
policies.36 Specifically, they assert that
under the Commission’s open-access
regime, an interstate pipeline cannot
control storage capacity that is
subscribed. Rather, they submit it is the
shipper with the contractual rights who
determines when or if the capacity is
used and if, when and to whom it is
released. The Dominion LDCs assert that
the Commission itself has concluded
that current regulatory controls
minimize the ability of pipelines to use
market power to force captive customers
to enter into longer term contracts than
would be required in a competitive
market.37 Thus, the Dominion LDCs
assert the Commission should find that
a pipeline has neither the legal ability
to withhold existing capacity nor an
incentive to refuse to build new
capacity, and that this, together with the
fact that pipeline activity to act with an
affiliated LDC to exercise market power
by withholding capacity would violate
other Commission rules and be
actionable, leads to the conclusion that
a pipeline and its affiliated LDC are
unlikely to be able to jointly exercise
market power.
65. These commentors conclude that
there is not sufficient justification for
35 Standards of Conduct for Transmission
Providers, Order No. 2004, 105 FERC Stats. & Regs.,
Regulation Preambles ¶ 31,155 (2003), order on
reh’g, Order No. 2004–A, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,161 (2004), order on reh’g and clarification,
Order No. 2004–B, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,166
(2004), order on reh’g and clarification, Order No.
2004–C, FERC Stats. and Regs. ¶ 31,172 (2004),
order on reh’g., Order No 2004–D, 110 FERC
¶ 61,320 (2005).
36 Comments of INGAA, Duke, Dominion and
Dominion LDCs.
37 Citing Order No. 637, 101 FERC ¶ 61,127 at
61,522.
PO 00000
Frm 00010
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
requiring a pipeline to include the
capacity of its affiliates when
calculating market share. In recognition
of the effect of shipper control over
contracted pipeline capacity, INGAA
urges the Commission to establish a
rebuttable presumption that such
capacity is properly considered as a
substitute for the storage service at issue
in a market-based storage rate
application, assuming the capacity
otherwise meets the ‘‘substitutability’’
criteria. Duke states that only storage
and transportation capacity controlled
by the affiliates of a storage applicant
should be aggregated with the capacity
of the applicant’s proposed storage
facility for the purposes of the market
concentration measure and the market
share calculated for the applicant. At a
minimum, these commentors urge the
Commission to eliminate the per se rule,
and evaluate on a case-by-case basis
whether affiliated capacity presents a
competitive alternative. Several
commentors claim that adoption of the
proposed rule will discourage otherwise
meritorious storage applicants and
undermine the Commission’s goal of
stimulating the construction of vital
new storage infrastructure.38
66. To the extent the Commission
does not delete this requirement,
INGAA requests that the Commission
clarify proposed § 284.503(b)(4) that
reads in pertinent part, that ‘‘[a]vailable
capacity * * * owned or controlled by
affiliates of the applicant in the relevant
market shall be clearly identified and
may not be considered as alternatives
competing with the applicant’’, to
clarify that while the pipeline affiliate’s
capacity is to be included in the market
share calculated for the applicant, it
should also be reflected in the total
market share for the geographic area.
67. On the other hand, Falcon urges
the Commission to recognize that the
storage services being evaluated for
market power may well be affiliated
with the ‘‘storage surrogate’’ services
permitted to be considered in the
evaluation. Falcon maintains that the
Commission should provide for
additional safeguards to prevent the
affiliated storage providers from
exercising market power in such a
situation and/or avoid, through separate
treatment and analysis of the affiliated
services, the actual market power or
market share associated with the
alternative affiliated services and
providers.
38 Comments of INGAA, Dominion and the
NiSource Pipelines.
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
Commission Determination
68. The requirement that the capacity
of a market-based rate applicant’s
affiliates is to be included in the market
share calculated for the applicant is
consistent with our established practice
and is supported as discussed below.
69. We disagree with commentors’
claim that the fact that the Commission
has adopted Standards of Conduct for
Transmission Providers which require
interstate pipelines to function
independently from affiliates removes
the necessity of requiring that the
capacity of the applicant and its
affiliates be combined. While affiliates
are required to act independently under
the Commission’s rules, this does not
mean that affiliates will compete for the
same service or product in a given
market. As recognized by the Supreme
Court in Copperweld Corporation v.
Independence Tube Corporation, ‘‘[a]
parent and its wholly-owned subsidiary
have a complete unity of interest. Their
objectives are common, not disparate;
their general corporate actions are
guided or determined not by two
separate corporate consciousnesses, but
one. * * * With or without a formal
‘agreement,’ the subsidiary acts for the
benefit of the parent, its sole
shareholder.’’ 39
70. We are also not persuaded by
commentors arguments that only
affiliate capacity that is not held under
firm contracts should be attributable to
the applicant. This proposal ignores the
fact that pipelines control the
conditions under which transportation
and storage services are provided
through the operation of their systems.
We are not willing to create situations
in which the pipeline, the dominant
owner of capacity, does not have an
incentive to build new capacity because
it or an affiliate can benefit from an
artificial shortage of capacity. As noted
in Order No. 637, the Commission has
carefully tailored its regulations so that
pipelines will not have an incentive to
use their monopoly power to create
scarcity.40 We see no compelling reason
to deviate from that policy here. For
these reasons, we find it is appropriate
to attribute affiliate capacity to the
storage provider even though the
capacity is contracted for by a shipper
under a firm contract. We have made
39 467 U.S. 752, 771 (1984) (holding that a parent
and its wholly-owned subsidiary were incapable o
conspiring with each other for purposes of section
1of the Sherman Act).
40 Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services and Regulation of
Interstate Natural Gas Transportation Services,
Order No. 637, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations
Preambles (July 1996–Dec. 2000) ¶ 31,091 at
31,270–71 (Feb. 9, 2000).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
revisions to § 284.503(b)(4) of the
regulations to clarify our intent.
71. As requested by INGAA, we
clarify that the applicant’s affiliate’s
capacity that is included in the market
share calculated for the applicant
should also be reflected in the total
market share for the relevant geographic
area.
72. Finally, we find that Falcons’s
concerns over affiliate capacity are
adequately addressed by the
requirement that the capacity of a
market-based rate applicant’s affiliates
is to be included in the market share
calculated for the applicant.
f. Filing Procedures
73. The Commission proposed to add
a new subpart M to part 284 that
requires, among other things, that
applications by storage providers
requesting market-based rates contain
certain information. The Commission
stated it would continue its practice of
approving market-based rate proposals
on a prospective basis only. We also
noted that approval of blanket certificate
authority to provide open-access storage
services at market-based rates will
subject the storage service provider to
the existing reporting requirements
applicable to open-access service
providers under § 284.13 of the
Commission’s regulations.
Comments
74. Sempra asserts that it is
unnecessary to impose on market-based
rate storage providers the full panoply
of 18 CFR § 284.13 reporting
requirements applicable to pipelines
operating under cost-based regulation,
given that the requisite showing of
absence of, or mitigation of, market
power has already been made. Instead,
Sempra urges the Commission to utilize
a lighter-handed reporting regime
modeled after the electronic quarterly
reports applicable to holders of electric
market-based rate authority. Sempra
asserts that these are sound
requirements for the Commission to
require of entities holding market-based
rate authority.
75. Enstor submits that the
Commission’s statement that storage
operators cannot charge market-based
rates until the Commission determines
that they lack market power or have
established adequate customer
protections conflicts with our current
policies implementing section 311 of
the NGPA. Enstor states that under the
Commission’s current regulations,
section 311 service providers may begin
charging (subject to refund) their
proposed rates, including market-based
rates, upon the filing of a petition for
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36621
rate approval with the Commission.
Enstor urges the Commission to
reconcile this discrepancy and to leave
intact the current rate filing regime that
governs section 311 service providers in
§ 284.123(b)(2)(i). Enstor also seeks
express clarification that nothing in the
NOPR is intended to upset the current
150-day window within which the
Commission must act on rate petitions
filed by section 311 service providers, or
otherwise the proposed rates are
deemed fair and equitable.
76. Enstor further requests that the
Commission allow flexibility in its
proposed requirements for market-based
rate filings under new § 284.503. While
Enstor agrees that such information may
be necessary in certain circumstances,
Enstor urges clarification in the Final
Rule that some or all of these procedural
requirements may be waived for good
cause when an applicant files for
market-based rates.
77. Finally, Enstor urges the
Commission to incorporate some sort of
time limitation for its review of rate
filings in the Final Rule. For example,
Enstor states the Commission can adopt
a five-month review period, beginning
from the date on which a complete rate
application is filed under proposed Rule
503, during which it could evaluate the
application and any responsive protests.
At the end of the five-month period, the
proposed rates would be deemed
approved in the absence of a formal
Commission ruling.
Commission Determination
78. Regarding the applicability of
§ 284.13 reporting requirements, we
disagree with Sempra that we should
not impose these requirements on
storage providers granted market-based
rates, but rather impose a reporting
regime modeled after the electric
quarterly reports. Under the
Commission’s Part 284 program, all
open-access transporters and storage
providers are required to post or file
with the Commission transaction
reports, quarterly index of customer
reports, and semi-annual storage
reports. These reports are required of all
open-access service providers and
provide crucial transparency. This
information allows both the
Commission and market participants to
monitor the market and detect undue
discrimination. Sempra has provided no
reasonable basis to exempt market-based
storage service providers from the
§ 284.13 reporting requirements.
79. As requested by Enstor, we clarify
that section 311 service providers may
begin charging (subject to refund) their
proposed rates, including market-based
rates, upon the filing of a petition for
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36622
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
rate approval with the Commission
pursuant to § 284.123(b)(2)(i) and that
the 150-day time frame in that section
is applicable to such requests. In
§ 284.502, we are adopting regulations
that provide that applicants providing
service under subpart C (transportation
by intrastate pipelines under section
311) of part 284 must file in accordance
with that section.
80. However, we reject Enstor’s
additional request that we impose a
time limitation on our review of marketbased rate filings by interstate storage
providers, after which time the
proposed rate would be deemed
approved. It would be unreasonable to
approve a market-based rate proposal
without a specific finding that the
applicant lacks market power. However,
the Commission intends to process any
request for market-based rates as
expeditiously as possible.
81. Finally, the Commission clarifies,
as requested by Enstor, that it may file
to waive the procedural requirements in
§ 284.503 for good cause shown.
g. Periodic Review
82. Proposed § 284.504 of the
regulations requires storage applicants
receiving market-based rates on the
basis of a market-power analysis to file
updated market-power analyses within
five years of the date of the Commission
order granting authority to charge
market-based rates, and every five years
thereafter. The Commission stated that
imposition of a periodic review is
necessary to ensure that our grant of
market-based rates to an applicant
remains just and reasonable.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
Comments
83. Several commentors including the
majority of interstate pipelines and
independent storage providers urge the
Commission to eliminate its proposal
for an automatic five-year market-power
review under § 284.504 for storage
operators that have demonstrated they
lack market power. These commentors
assert that this requirement is unduly
burdensome, not necessary to protect
customers and will deter new storage
development.41 Specifically, the
commentors submit that the current
requirement that market-based rate
grantees report any changes in
circumstances that are pertinent to their
original absence-of-market-power
showing, along with ongoing reporting
obligations under existing regulations,
are adequate to protect consumers. DTE
also notes that it is unaware of any
41 Comments of INGAA, Dominion, KM, DTE,
Duke, SGR, Honeoye, Bridgeline, Unicol, Falcon,
SGR and Jefferson Storage.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
abuse complaints submitted by
customers of storage companies granted
market-based rate authority in the past
that would necessitate the imposition of
a five-year market-power review
requirement.
84. A number of these commentors
assert that an automatic review is
unnecessarily burdensome in this
context for the same reasons proffered
by the Commission in support of
reliance on regular monitoring of posted
information and the NGA section 5
complaint processes for market-based
storage rates under new NGA section
4(f). For example, Duke submits that if
regular monitoring and the section 5
complaint provisions are sufficient to
protect consumers in instances where
the Commission presumes that a storage
provider has market power under new
NGA section 4(f), these same provisions
in addition to the Commission’s existing
policy of conditioning its certificate
authorization with a notice of changed
circumstance requirement are more than
sufficient to protect consumers in
circumstances where the Commission
has found the applicant not to possess
market power.
85. If the Commission adopts an
automatic review requirement, several
commentors urge the Commission to
make clear that the new requirement
does not apply to projects that have
previously received market-based rate
approval,42 arguing that any required
periodic review must be prospective
only and not affect existing contractual
terms and conditions agreed upon in
light of the Commission’s initial grant of
market-based rate authority to a service
provider.43 Duke argues that placing a
new periodic-review condition on
existing market-based rate
authorizations would constitute an
impermissible retroactive revision of the
certificate authorizations for the
underlying facilities, frustrate the
investment expectations of the owners
of those facilities, and undermine
investor confidence in the storage
market.
86. INGAA submits that the threat of
revocation of market-based rate
authority in the middle of a contract
term may present an unacceptable level
of risk to potential storage developers.
In order to minimize the uncertainty
that would be created by a new periodic
review requirement, SGR argues the
42 Comments of Bay Gas, INGAA, EnCana,
Bridgeline, and Unocal.
43 Comments of INGAA, KM, and Haddington
Ventures. SGR argues that such a modification must
be made in accordance with the Mobile-Sierra
doctrine, with the Commission determining, on the
basis of substantial record evidence, that the public
interest requires such modification.
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Commission must make it clear that any
review of a storage provider’s marketbased rate authorization will be
conducted under NGA section 5, with
the Commission bearing the burden of
showing that the market-based rate
authorization and the rates it permits a
storage provider to charge have become
unjust and unreasonable, and the
further burden of establishing
prospectively the ratemaking
methodology that would yield just and
reasonable rates.
87. If the periodic review is adopted,
Honeoye and SGR propose that the first
such update should not be due until the
later of 5 years after the effective date of
proposed § 284.504 or the date the
relevant storage facilities are placed in
commercial operation. Honeoye also
seeks confirmation that an existing
holder of market-base rate authority can
comply with this requirement by
demonstrating that the facts that
permitted the Commission to authorize
market-base rates in the first instance
are still true.
88. On the other hand, NGSA, EEI and
PGC support the Commission’s proposal
to require storage applicants granted
market-based rates to file an updated
market-power analysis every five years.
PGC asserts that without such periodic
reviews, the Commission is unable to
perform the regulatory oversight
necessary to prevent unjust and
unreasonable rates against captive gas
customers. EEI notes that there is a
similar requirement for electric utilities
that sell at market-based rates, and
suggests this requirement is necessary to
protect customers from changes in the
marketplace that may no longer justify
market-based rate authority.
89. SCE also supports the
Commission’s five-year periodic report
requirement in § 284.504 and submits
that this review should also consider
any cost-of-service facilities and
interconnected facilities that could
serve as substitutes for one another and
should assess the competitive
functioning of the market and impose
remedial measures such as adjustments
to mitigation measures or the complete
withdrawal of market-based rate
authority as necessary to ensure just and
reasonable rates.
Commission Determination
90. We will not impose a generic fiveyear reporting requirement on storage
providers granted market-base rates
although we reserve the option of
imposing a reporting requirement in any
individual case. We have carefully
considered the comments and have
concluded that any benefits that would
be achieved by a generic requirement
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
are outweighed by the additional costs
that such a generic requirement would
create. The Commission believes that
existing reporting requirements and its
ongoing market monitoring programs
generally give us sufficient information
to know whether storage markets where
applicants have been authorized to
charge market-based rates remain
competitive, and the Commission has
the ability to take appropriate action if
market-power issues arise.
91. A central factor in the
Commission’s decision is the fact that in
the majority of cases where we have
authorized market-based rates for
storage services, the applicant has not
had a large presence in the market. For
example, the Commission has approved
all requests for market-based rates
where the applicant was located in the
production area based on findings that
HHIs in that geographic region are well
below 1,800 and the market shares of
the applicants were small.44 In
consuming regions, such as the
Northeast portion of the United States,
where there are fewer providers, some
with large market shares whose services
are regulated, the Commission has
approved requests to implement marketbased rates by considering factors other
than market concentration including the
small size of the applicant’s market
share.45 In these situations, we find that
market-power concerns are low.
Additionally, in individual cases the
Commission has imposed on applicants
permitted to charge market-based rates
for storage services the requirement to
notify the Commission when there have
been changes of circumstances that
affect the applicant’s ability to exercise
market power,46 and we will codify this
requirement in § 284.504(b). For storage
providers with market shares of ten
44 See, e.g., Caledonia Energy Partners, L.L.C., 111
FERC ¶ 61,095 (2005) (market share of working gas
capacity and deliverability each approximately two
percent); Copiah County Storage Co. 99 FERC
¶ 61,316 (2002) (market share of working gas
capacity and deliverability each less than two
percent).
45 See, e.g., Avoca Natural Gas Storage, 68 FERC
¶ 61,045 (19940. Steuben Gas Storage Co., 72 FERC
¶ 61,102 (1995) (market share of working gas
capacity and deliverability each less than four
percent); New York State Electric and Gas Corp., 81
FERC ¶ 61,020 (1997) (working gas capacity and
deliverability each less than one percent); N.E. Hub
Partners, L.P., 83 FERC ¶ 61,043 (1998) (working gas
capacity and deliverability each less than five
percent); Seneca Lake Storage, Inc., 98 FERC
¶ 61,163 (2002) (working gas capacity and
deliverability each less than two percent); and
Honeoye Storage Corp., 91 FERC ¶ 62,165 (2000)
(working gas capacity and deliverability each less
than two percent).
46 See, e.g., Caledonia Energy Partners, L.L.C., 111
FERC ¶ 61,095 (2005) (requiring that Caledonia
notify the Commission of future circumstances
affecting its present market power status within ten
days of acquiring knowledge of any such changes).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
percent or less, we believe that the
notice of change of circumstance
requirement, together with the
transparency provided by the existing
reporting requirements in § 284.13, are
adequate to permit the effective
monitoring of market-power concerns
related to storage providers charging
market-based rates and enable the
Commission to initiate section 5
proceedings where appropriate.47 For
storage providers with a market share
greater than ten percent, we intend to
consider in individual cases whether
the specific facts and circumstances
presented require additional reporting.
We believe that this approach achieves
an appropriate balance between the
need to monitor for market power and
the goal of creating a regulatory
environment that will promote
infrastructure.
92. However, the Commission wishes
to emphasize that the failure to timely
file a change in circumstance report or
failure to comply with reporting
requirements as required by the
regulations would constitute a violation
of the Commission’s regulations. A
storage provider would be subject to
disgorgement of profits and/or civil
penalties from the date on which the
violation occurred. Such storage
provider may also be subject to
suspension or revocation of its authority
to sell at market-based rates (or other
appropriate non-monetary remedies).
Additionally, if subsequent experience
with the changes enacted here
demonstrates a need for a generic fiveyear market-power analysis
requirement, we reserve the right to
initiate such a change.
h. Cross Subsidies and Customer
Protection Comments
93. Xcel states that it is concerned
that the proposed rule does not
sufficiently protect storage customers
served by a storage provider under costbased rates from bearing costs
associated with storage services
provided by the same provider at
market-based rates. Xcel explains that
the temptation to increase revenues by
misallocating costs will be difficult to
resist and difficult for customers and the
Commission to detect in a rate
proceeding. Therefore, Xcel requests
that the Commission protect customers
by modifying the regulations to require
47 This approach is similar to the Commission’s
proposal to exempt sellers of wholesale electric
power who own or control 500 MW or less of
generating capacity in aggregate from filing triennial
reviews. Market-Based Rates for Wholesale Sales of
Electric Energy, Capacity and Ancillary Services by
Public Utilities, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,602 at P 152 (2006).
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36623
storage service providers to account for
costs incurred in providing marketbased rate storage services separately
from cost-based storage services. Xcel
maintains this requirement is similar to
the Commission’s policy of requiring
pipelines to account separately for the
revenues received under negotiated rate
agreements.
94. Falcon asserts that pipeline and
utility affiliated storage providers
(collectively, ‘‘Affiliated Storage
Providers’’) have a natural advantage
over independents because of their
ability to provide a rate subsidy,
bundling, or other preference, enabling
them to charge lower rates for their
storage services and placing
independent storage providers at a
distinct competitive disadvantage.
Accordingly, Falcon requests that the
Commission take steps to minimize any
subsidization or preference afforded
Affiliated Storage Providers by requiring
Affiliated Storage Providers to: (1)
Unbundle storage and transportation
services, and (2) allocate the appropriate
level of fixed and variable costs to
storage and transportation services.
Absent such actions, Falcon alleges that
independent storage providers will
never be able to effectively compete on
a ‘‘level playing field’’ with Affiliated
Storage Providers, to the detriment of
the ultimate consumer.
95. Similarly, SGR submits that the
broader availability of market-based rate
authority proposed in the NOPR could
increase the possibility that pipelineowned storage could take advantage of
a liberalized market-power test to gain
an unfair competitive advantage over
independent storage developers/
operators. It argues that pipeline-owned
storage enjoys considerable advantages
in the marketplace; given the ability
pipeline-owned storage has to share a
customer base with the pipeline, to
benefit from operational integration
with the pipeline and to enjoy revenue
support offered by pipeline
transportation services. If left
unchecked, SGR submits that these
advantages could present
insurmountable barriers to entry for
independent storage developers.
96. UET asserts that moving from
cost-based rates to market-based rates
for existing storage facilities and
expansions of existing storage facilities
would be unfair to existing storage
customers. For example, UET submits
that in many cases cost-based rates have
paid for facilities with the potential for
cheap expansibility. If, as the result of
the proposed change in market-power
analysis, the expansion capacity is
offered only at market-based rates, UET
alleges that the storage provider will
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36624
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
reap the benefits of the cheap
expansibility for which the customers
have paid.
97. Finally, APS requests that the
Commission take all available steps to
encourage the development of
independent storage facilities in the
southwest including eliminating
barriers to entry such as the ‘‘bundled’’
pipeline storage and transmission
services being offered by El Paso.
Commission Determination
98. In granting market-based rates for
pipelines that provide cost-based
services, the Commission intends to
ensure that no subsidization by existing
cost-based shippers takes place. To date,
when granting market-based rates in
these circumstances, the Commission
has required that the applicant
separately account for all costs and
revenues associated with facilities used
to provide the market-based services.48
We intend to continue this practice and
will codify in new § 284.504 of the
regulations the requirement that
pipelines that provide cost-based
services must separately account for all
costs and revenues associated with
facilities used to provide the marketbased services. This will ensure that
market-based services are not
subsidized by cost-based services, as
well as ensure that pipeline-owned
storage is not afforded an unfair rate
advantage over independent storage
providers.
99. Regarding Falcon’s request to
require unbundling, we note that our
regulations already require that
pipelines offer their customers firm and
interruptible storage on an open-access
contract basis.49 Issues regarding
whether a pipeline has sufficiently
unbundled its services in compliance
with our policies should be raised in
individual pipeline proceedings.50
i. Additional Incentives
Comments
100. As an alternate to market-based
rates, Dominion urges the Commission
to consider offering incentives to
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
48 See,
e.g., Gulf South Pipeline Co., 101 FERC
¶ 61,204 (2002); Koch Gateway Pipeline Co., 66
FERC ¶ 61,385 (1994).
49 See 18 CFR 284.1(a) of the Commission’s
regulations that defines transportation as including
storage. Thus, storage is included within the
nondiscriminatory access and other requirements of
Part 284 for interstate pipelines.
50 APS’ request that the Commission take steps to
encourage the development of independent storage
facilities in the southwest including eliminating the
bundled pipeline storage and transmission services
being offered by El Paso is outside the scope of this
proceeding. This issue has been raised in El Paso’s
rate proceeding in Docket No. RP05–422–000 and
will be addressed there.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
promote the development of new
storage facilities reflecting the increased
investment risk of these projects,
including: (1) Authorizing higher rates
of return on equity for new cost-ofservice storage projects as compared to
new pipeline projects to reflect the
increasingly riskier nature of identifying
new geologic structures and the shorterterm contracts that customers are
entering into; (2) allowing the
authorized rate of return for a new costof-service project to remain unchanged
over the duration of the initial shipper
contract as revenue certainty is
necessary to provide good incentives for
new investment; (3) offering regulatory
incentives to compensate for the
enormous cost of purchasing base gas
for a new facility, particularly reservoir
and aquifer types of storage facilities,
such as permitting the roll in of the
costs of base gas associated with a new
incrementally-priced storage facility
into its system-wide rates in its next rate
case with a five percent cap placed on
the increase to system rates from this
roll-in; and (4) permitting interstate
pipelines to recover the prudently
incurred development cost of storage
facilities that are cancelled or
abandoned prior to being placed into
service, similar to the initiative being
considered in the rulemaking to
promote the construction of new
transmission facilities in the electric
utility industry.
Commission Determination
101. The Commission agrees with
Dominion that there may be alternatives
to market-based rates that would
appropriately address the risk faced by
storage applicants. We note that the
Commission’s policies already
incorporate considerable flexibility in
deriving cost-based pricing options that
are responsive to the market pressures
faced by jurisdictional companies. For
example, in Order No. 637 the
Commission revised its regulatory
policies to enable pipelines to file for
peak/off peak and term differentiated
rates.51 In addition, rates for storage
services can be negotiated between the
storage provider and a shipper under
the Commission’s negotiated rate
policies.52 The Commission is willing to
51 See Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas
Transportation Services, and Regulation of
Interstate Natural Gas Transportation Services,
Order No. 637, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulation
Preambles July 1996–Dec. 2000 ¶ 31,091 (Feb. 9,
2000).
52 Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines and
Regulation of Negotiated Transportation Services of
Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ¶ 61,076 (1996),
reh’g and clarification denied, 75 FERC ¶ 61,024
(1996), reh’g denied, 75 FERC ¶ 61,066 (1996);
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
entertain requests to implement other
cost-based pricing proposals that may
serve to add flexibility and efficiency to
storage services on a case-by-case
basis.53
B. Energy Policy Act of 2005
102. Section 312 of EPAct 2005 adds
new NGA section 4(f), which permits
the Commission to authorize new
natural gas storage projects (i.e., projects
placed in service after the passage of the
Act) to provide service at market-based
rates notwithstanding the fact that the
applicant is unable to demonstrate that
it lacks market power. New NGA section
4(f) requires that, to authorize marketbased rates, the Commission must find
that ‘‘market-based rates are in the
public interest and necessary to
encourage the construction of the
storage capacity in the area needing
storage services’’ and ‘‘customers are
adequately protected.’’ The Act further
requires that the Commission ‘‘ensure
that reasonable terms and conditions are
in place to protect consumers’’ and that
the Commission ‘‘review periodically
whether the market-based rate is just,
reasonable, and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential.’’
Intrastate pipelines also provide storage
services, and new NGA section 4(f)(1)
extends the market-based rate authority
to intrastate pipelines subject to
Commission authority under the Natural
Gas Policy Act of 1978.54 We discuss
below the relevant aspects of new NGA
section 4(f).
1. Storage Capacity Eligible for MarketBased Rates
103. New NGA section 4(f) states that
the Commission may authorize ‘‘marketbased rates for new storage capacity
related to a specific facility placed in
service after the date of enactment of the
Energy Policy Act of 2005.’’ In the
NOPR, the Commission posited that the
phrase ‘‘placed in service after the date
of enactment’’ modifies the term
‘‘facility,’’ not the term ‘‘capacity,’’ such
that it is the facility which must be
placed into service after August 8, 2005,
petition for review denied, Burlington Resources Oil
& Gas Co. v. FERC, 172 F.3d (D.C. Cir. 1998);
Modification of Negotiated Rate Policy, 104 FERC
¶ 61,134 (2003), order on reh’g and clarification,
114 FERC ¶ 61,042 (1996).
53 See, e.g., Saltville Gas Storage Company L.L.C.,
109 FERC ¶ 61,200 (2004) (approving a modified
Equitable method for designing firm storage rates).
54 15 U.S.C. 3301–3432 (2000). We note that the
Commission has authorized Hinshaw pipelines to
be treated the same as LDCs and we intend the same
here. See Certain Transportation, Sales and
Assignments by Pipeline Companies not Subject to
Commission Jurisdiction Under Section 1(c) of the
Natural Gas Act, Order No. 63, FERC Stats. & Regs,.
Regulations Preambles (1997–1981) ¶ 30,118 (Jan. 9,
1980).
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
rather than the storage capacity. Noting
that the statute does not define the term
‘‘specific facility,’’ the Commission
proposed to interpret that term to
consider a new cavern, reservoir or
aquifer that is developed after August 8,
2005, as a facility potentially qualifying
for market-based rates under the Act.
However, the Commission requested
comments on alternative constructions
of the Act. Moreover, the Commission
also invited comments concerning how,
if the Act is construed differently, the
Commission may adequately protect
other customers already receiving
service under cost-based authorizations
that pre-date the Commission’s new
NGA section 4(f) authority.
Comments
104. A number of commentors argue
that the statutory language concerning
the capacity eligible for market-based
rates under section 4(f) is ambiguous
and open to alternative interpretation.
Thus, they assert the Commission has
discretion in implementing the
language.
105. INGAA argues that the
Commission interprets new NGA
section 4(f) too narrowly, so as to
exclude new storage capacity resulting
from the expansion of existing fields or
reservoirs. INGAA submits interstate
pipelines and pipeline affiliates, which
own substantial amounts of existing
storage capacity, should be allowed to
apply for market-based rates to develop
either new or expanded storage fields.
Northern concurs with INGAA and
argues that a broader statutory
interpretation is necessary. DTE
maintains that there is no reason to treat
expansion facilities any differently than
entirely new storage fields. Duke adds
that the best assurance against the
exercise of market power is the creation
of a competitive marketplace and that
granting market-based rate treatment to
only entirely new storage facilities may
place existing storage at a significant
disadvantage and discourage the
expansion of existing storage.
106. Williston Basin argues that there
is no material distinction between
expanding existing storage facilities and
developing a new, separate storage
facility, and that the Commission’s
interpretation might unnecessarily
influence companies to choose
construction of a new facility over
expansion of an existing facility.
Northern asserts that the risks involved
in developing new storage capacity,
whether at a new or existing facility, are
greater than those involved in
constructing new pipeline capacity and
justify the use of market-based rates. It
states that a broader interpretation of the
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
subject provision will recognize the risk
of storage expansions and provide a
proper incentive for developers.
107. Northern maintains that existing
storage customers served by a pipeline
will not be harmed by including
expansions of existing capacity because
customers’ existing storage service will
not be affected by the expansion. In this
vein, Williston Basin asserts that, in the
case of an expansion of existing storage
facilities, existing customers under costbased authorizations can be adequately
protected if the incremental capacity
and associated costs are accounted for
separately and addressed in each storage
service provider’s next rate proceeding.
108. KM states that granting marketbased rates to expansions of capacity
will remove economic distortions
associated with limiting this provision
to new storage fields. KM asserts that it
is faster and more cost-effective to
expand existing storage facilities rather
than to construct new storage facilities
and that such expansions should be
placed on equal footing with greenfield
projects.
109. Other commentors support the
interpretation of the Act proposed in the
NOPR.55 AGA argues that broadening
the definition of ‘‘facility’’ would largely
benefit interstate pipelines, and
potentially harm existing customers of
cost-based storage service. AGA asserts
that the Commission’s policies should
not encourage storage owners to invest
in reshaping the operations of existing
storage facilities in order to maximize
the scope of market-based services.
APGA agrees, and contends that the
NOPR’s interpretation is required by the
language in the statute and is reasonable
because there is no reason to provide
financial incentives to a storage
provider for an expansion of a facility
that has already been constructed. PGC
agrees arguing that interpreting section
4(f) to apply only to new facilities is
most consistent with the goal of
increasing storage capacity.
110. Falcon requests that the
Commission ensure that new gas storage
projects that are developed by Affiliated
Storage Providers do not receive any
direct or indirect subsidy from their
affiliated companies. NGSA and EnCana
assert that if the provision is interpreted
to permit storage services made possible
by incremental capacity at an existing,
cost-based facility to be priced on a
market basis, there would be no set of
conditions that would adequately
protect customers against the risk of
abuse.
55 AGA, Falcon, EnCana, Enstor, NGSA, PGC, and
SCE.
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36625
111. Beyond the risk of cross-subsidy,
EnCana is also concerned that there is
nothing to prevent a storage service
provider with both cost-based rate
facilities and market-based rate facilities
from placing its marketing emphasis on
the market-based rate side in order to
ensure that those storage services are
fully subscribed at the highest possible
rate, while, at the same time,
deemphasizing the sale of their
regulated cost-based services, which are
theoretically underwritten by the
regulated ratepayers. ESGI asserts that,
in order to provide safeguards against
such practices, the Commission would
need to vigilantly review the provider’s
marketing efforts in section 4 rate cases.
112. Enstor contends that allowing
expansion capacity at existing storage
facilities to qualify for market-based rate
treatment under section 4(f) would
place new storage projects (many of
which are developed by independent
operators) at a competitive disadvantage
relative to market incumbents such as
interstate pipelines. Enstor argues that
allowing virtually all new capacity to
fall within the scope of section 4(f)
would enable interstate pipelines to use
their cost-based transportation
monopoly to subsidize new services
offered under this authority.
113. The NiSource Pipelines assert
that the Commission’s interpretation of
the phrase ‘‘specific facility placed in
service after the date of enactment to
mean ‘‘a new cavern, reservoir or
aquifer that is developed after August 8,
2005’’ is not consistent with the gas
industry’s or the Commission’s own
definition of that term, which defines
‘‘in service’’ to mean when the facilities
are actually placed into service.
NiSource advocates that the
Commission revise its interpretation to
incorporate the more appropriate
definition of ‘‘in service.’’
Commission Determination
114. The meaning of new NGA
section 4(f) is ambiguous. Early drafts of
bills stated that the Commission could
authorize a natural gas company ‘‘to
provide storage and storage-related
services at market-based rates for new
storage capacity placed in service after
the date of enactment of the Energy
Policy Act of 2005, notwithstanding the
fact that the company is unable to
demonstrate that it lacks market power
* * *.’’ 56 Under these early versions of
the Act, it was clear that all new storage
capacity would have been eligible for
56 S. 10, 109th Cong. sec. 382 (2005).See also,
H.R. 6, 109th Cong. sec 382 (with engrossed
amendment as agreed to by the Senate, June 28,
2005); H.R. 6, 109th Cong. sec. 382 (as passed and
ordered to be printed by the Senate, July 14, 2005).
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36626
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
market-based rates. However, in the
final bill, the phrase, ‘‘related to a
specific facility’’ was added so that the
subject language read, ‘‘to provide
storage and storage-related services at
market-based rates for new storage
capacity related to a specific facility
placed in service after the date of
enactment of the Energy Policy Act of
2005 * * *’’ 57 The addition of the
specific facility language indicates that
it is the facility, not the storage capacity,
that must be placed in service after the
date of the Act.58
115. Congress, however, provided no
definition of the term facility. Upon
review of the comments and further
consideration, the Commission
concludes that a more traditional
interpretation of ‘‘facility’’ than that
posited in the NOPR may be more
consistent with Congressional intent
and existing precedent, and better serve
to further the Commission’s goal of
facilitating the development of new
natural gas storage capacity. The
Commission recognizes that significant
and substantial enhancements to storage
capacity can be achieved at existing
fields and finds that it is unnecessary to
exclude service from such expansions
from consideration for market-based
rates by narrowly interpreting the term
‘‘facility’’ in the context of section 4(f).
For purposes of implementing the
certification requirements of section 7(c)
of the NGA, the Commission defined
‘‘facilities’’ broadly, in exclusionary
terms—everything except ‘‘auxiliary
installations’’ and certain facilities
constituting replacement facilities are
‘‘facilities’’ for which a natural gas
company must obtain a certificate.59
Applying that same definition here, in
the context of section 4(f), would be
consistent with our longstanding
practice in applying that term under the
NGA and therefore consistent with the
rule that Congress is deemed to be
aware of existing administrative
interpretations when amending a
particular statute that contains such
interpretations.60 This definition would
57 H.R. Rep. No. 109–190, at 97 (2005) (Conf.
Rep.).
58 See Jama v. Immigration & Customs
Enforcement, 543 U.S. 335, 343 (2005) (noting the
‘‘ ‘grammatical ‘rule of the last antecedent,’
according to which a limiting clause or phrase
* * * should ordinarily be read as modifying only
the noun or phrase that it immediately follows.’’ ’
(quoting Barnhart v. Thomas, 540 U.S. 20, 26
(2003)).
59 See 18 CFR 2.55 (2005).
60 See Bragdon v. Abbott, 524 U.S. 624, 645
(1998) (when administrative and judicial
interpretations have settled the meaning of an
existing statutory provision, repetition of the same
language in a new statute indicates, as a general
matter, the intent to incorporate its administrative
and judicial interpretations as well).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
enable storage providers to seek marketbased rates for service associated with
capacity related to any ‘‘specific
facility’’ requiring certification placed in
service after the date of the Act, be it a
new storage cavern or a facility which
expands capacity at an existing cavern
or reservoir. However, to receive such
authorization, the storage provider will
still need to satisfy the other
requirements of section 4(f) discussed
below. In addition, such rates will only
be found to be in the public interest if
the storage provider demonstrates that
the market-based services will not be
subsidized by existing customers and
that customers receiving cost-based
service from expanded facilities will be
adequately protected.
116. Regarding the NiSource
Pipelines’ concern over the
Commission’s definition of ‘‘in service,’’
we clarify that our intent is to define ‘‘in
service’’ to mean when the facilities are
actually placed into service.
2. Market-Based Rates Are in the Public
Interest and Necessary to Encourage the
Construction of Storage Capacity in the
Area Needing Storage Services
117. Section 4(f) of the NGA states
that in order to allow a company to
charge market-based rates under this
section, the Commission must
determine that: ‘‘market-based rates are
in the public interest and necessary to
encourage the construction of the
storage capacity in the area needing
storage services.’’ 61 In the NOPR, the
Commission stated that applicants for
authorization under section 4(f) will
bear the burden of showing that in its
specific circumstances, market-based
rates are necessary to encourage the
construction of storage capacity and that
storage services are needed in the area.
To make this showing, the Commission
suggested that the applicant could
present evidence that it had offered its
capacity at cost-based rates through an
open season and was unable to obtain
sufficient long-term commitments at
those cost-based rates. However, the
Commission invited comments
concerning other ways a project
applicant might make these showings.
Comments
118. AGA supports the suggestion that
an applicant under this section might
demonstrate the need for market-based
storage rates by showing that the market
failed to subscribe under long-term
contracts at cost-based rates offered
through an open season. INGAA also
61 Energy Policy Act of 2005, Pub. L. 109–58,
section 312, 119 Stat. 594, 688 (2005) (to be codified
at 15 U.S.C. 717c(f)(1)(A)).
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
supports the Commission’s suggestion,
but suggests such a showing should not
be required. Rather, the Commission
should allow the applicant substantial
discretion as to how to make the
requisite showing based on the facts of
its project. EEI agrees that the applicant
should have the burden to show that
market-based rates are necessary to
encourage construction of storage
capacity; specifically, EEI urges the
Commission to require an applicant to
show why such capacity cannot be
developed under cost-based rates. SCE
asserts that in the event an applicant
relies on a failed open season as
evidence of need, other parties must
have the opportunity to contest the open
season’s reasonableness.
119. The NYPSC expresses concern
that the NOPR did not discuss ‘‘public
interest’’ as a standard separate and
apart from ‘‘need,’’ as the language of
section 4(f) treats these as separate
standards. The APGA also states that the
Commission must revise § 284.505 to
require a specific public interest
demonstration.
120. NYPSC acknowledges that the
‘‘public interest’’ standard could
encompass a broad range of factors. It
argues, however, that while the
Commission may find it is in the
‘‘public interest’’ to authorize marketbased rates to encourage the entrance of
independent, third party storage
providers into the market, it may not be
in the public interest to encourage the
construction of new storage facilities by
a pipeline with a dominant market
share.
121. Haddington Ventures asserts that
the Commission should recognize three
distinct categories of new storage
projects and treat each differently under
its section 4(f) policy. The three
categories are: (1) Independent storage
projects owned by entities unaffiliated
with existing natural gas infrastructure
subject to cost-based rate regulation; (2)
storage projects owned by entities
affiliated with existing natural gas
infrastructure subject to cost-based rate
regulation, but which are not physically
connected to such existing
infrastructure; and (3) storage projects
owned by entities affiliated with
existing natural gas infrastructure
subject to traditional cost-based rate
regulation to which such storage
projects are connected or upon which
such storage projects otherwise rely.
122. Haddington Ventures submits
that the Commission’s proposal
adequately addresses Category 2
projects, but should be adjusted to better
account for Category 1 and Category 3
projects. With regard to Category 1
projects, Haddington Ventures asserts
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
that the consumer protection required
will be satisfied by: (a) The
Commission’s rate regulation of existing
infrastructure, which establishes a
ceiling on the price that the facility
owner can command for storage, and (b)
the relative ease of entry by potential
competitors.
123. Haddington Ventures asserts that
a Category 3 project should be granted
market-based rates only after the project
has met the burden of demonstrating
that (a) no mechanisms remain that
could be exploited to unfairly advantage
such projects, and (b) any safeguards
imposed are administrable. Category 3
projects should be required to
demonstrate annually and whenever
material changes in the market or of the
project may undermine customer
protections. In addition, Haddington
Ventures maintains that Category 3
projects that do not achieve the desired
level of return at market-based rates
should not be allowed to fold the costs
of the project back into a regulated rate
structure, except where (a) a bona fide
change of circumstances has occurred
that eliminates the original grounds for
granting the market-based rate authority,
and (b) the Commission is satisfied that
the regulated rate would be lower than
the market rate.
124. Enstor takes a different approach,
asserting that those that oppose marketbased rates should have the burden of
showing that such rates are not
‘‘necessary to encourage the
construction of the storage capacity in
the area needing storage services.’’
Enstor proposes that the Commission
establish a presumption that storage
capacity will not be built in the absence
of market-based rate authorization.
Enstor asserts that, in the alternative, if
the Commission does not adopt such a
presumption, the objective financial
criteria that the applicant’s lenders are
requiring for the development of the
particular project should be the basis for
the required determination of need.
Commission Determination
125. In order to authorize marketbased rates under section 4(f), the
Commission must determine that: (1)
Market-based rates are in the public
interest; (2) market-based rates are
necessary to encourage the construction
of the storage capacity; and (3) the area
in which the storage project is proposed
needs storage services. We agree with
the NYPSC and APGA that the public
interest requirement is a separate
standard under the Act and we have
revised § 284.505 accordingly. The
Commission will expect each applicant
to address each of these requirements in
its applications explaining and
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
supporting its contentions with respect
to each element.
126. In determining whether marketbased rates for a particular project are in
the public interest, the Commission will
consider, among other things, the risk of
the project, and the investment required
to fund it. Generally, the Commission
would expect that for market-based rates
to be in the public interest for services
proposed under section 4(f), marketbased rates would be necessary for the
project sponsor to secure financing and
move forward with the project. In the
Commission’s view, it is unlikely that
market-based rate authorization would
be necessary, or in the public interest,
to encourage relatively risk-free
expansions of storage.
127. We also agree with the NYPSC
and Haddington that another factor to
consider in determining whether
market-based rates are in the public
interest is whether the applicant is a
new independent storage provider or an
existing pipeline in the relevant market.
In general, we believe that an existing
pipeline will face fewer difficulties in
securing financing for incremental
expansions of existing storage facilities.
As a going concern with existing
customers and financial relationships,
the risk associated with acquiring
financing is lower for incremental
expansions than the risk associated with
a greenfield project undertaken by a
new entrant in the market. Therefore,
we believe it may be more difficult for
an existing pipeline to meet the public
interest standard than it will be for a
new independent storage provider.
128. Ultimately, the Commission’s
finding that market-based rates are in
the public interest will reflect its
consideration of all aspects of 4(f)
proposals, including, but not limited to,
the risk faced by the project sponsors,
the extent to which additional capacity
is needed in the area of the project, and
the strength of the applicant’s showing
that the facilities would not be built but
for market-based rate treatment.
129. In order to receive authorization
to charge market-based rates under
section 4(f), each applicant must make
a showing as to why market-based rates
are necessary to encourage the
construction of the storage capacity. As
the Commission stated in the NOPR,
one way that the applicant could make
such a showing is to present evidence
that it offered its capacity at cost-based
rates through an open season and was
unable to obtain sufficient long-term
commitments at those cost-based rates.
On the basis of the record, we believe
such an open season is the best means
of demonstrating that cost-based rates
will not be sufficient. However we are
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36627
open to applicants making another type
of showing. Applicants may also cite to
other marketing factors to explain why
market-based rates are necessary. As
suggested by SCE, parties will have an
opportunity to comment upon this
evidence.
130. The Commission will not
establish a presumption that storage
capacity will not be built in the absence
of market-based rate authorization, as
suggested by Enstor. The statute
requires that the Commission make an
affirmative finding that market-based
rates are necessary to encourage the
construction of storage. Also, in the
Commission’s experience, storage has
been built in the absence of marketbased rate authorization. Regarding
Enstor’s assertion that the objective
financial criteria that the applicant’s
lenders are requiring for the
development of the particular project
should be the basis for the
determination of the necessity of the
project, the Commission will afford
applicants significant discretion in
demonstrating that market-based rates
are necessary to encourage the
development of additional storage.
Enstor can cite to requirements imposed
by its lenders if it believes that such
requirements justify the authorization of
market-based rates. The Commission
cannot make a generic determination on
such issues, but must look at the
positions of the parties in individual
cases.
131. Applicants will also have to
show that storage services are needed in
the area in which they are proposing a
project. An applicant can demonstrate
need by including evidence of a general
lack of storage in the area or that
existing storage capacity is fully
utilized, pipeline constraints leading
into the area, projected increased
demand for natural gas in the area to be
served, customer interest, high natural
gas prices and/or volatility and other
information the applicant believes
supports its determination that
additional storage is needed. As noted
above, the Commission will balance the
strength of an applicant’s showing of
need with the other requirements of the
Act in determining whether to approve
a request for market-based rates under
NGA section 4(f).
132. The Commission notes that the
subject of this rule is whether and in
what circumstances authorization of
market-based rates would be
appropriate pursuant to NGA section
4(f). To the extent an applicant is also
requesting authority to construct and
operate new storage facilities pursuant
to NGA section 7(c), the applicant will
be subject to the full range of
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36628
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
requirements of the Commission’s
certificate process.62
3. Customer Protection
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
133. New NGA section 4(f) requires
that the Commission, as a prerequisite
for granting market-based rate authority,
determine that customers are adequately
protected, and requires the Commission
to ensure that reasonable terms and
conditions are in place to protect them.
In the NOPR, the Commission proposed
to allow the applicant to propose a
relevant method of protecting
customers.
134. The Commission stated that in
general, customers will be better off if
more storage infrastructure is
constructed. Therefore, the Commission
sought a balance in considering requests
for market-based rate authority under
new NGA section 4(f), between the
obvious benefits of additional storage
capacity in areas needing storage
services against adverse impacts which
might arise from the potential exercise
of market power by the storage provider.
In doing so, the Commission stated that
it remained mindful of the fact that to
the extent unnecessary conditions are
imposed, the additional storage
infrastructure and the additional service
options would be lost to potential
customers. Accordingly, the
Commission sought comments
concerning how to achieve this balance.
135. The Commission stated that the
appropriate method of customer
protection may vary according to the
facts and circumstances of the
individual project proposals and
therefore, the Commission proposed to
allow each applicant to propose a
method of protecting customers best
suited to its project. However, the
Commission sought comments on
whether it would be beneficial to
identify certain acceptable approaches
to protect customers. The Commission
reasoned that the establishment of
generic safeguards would facilitate the
application process for NGA section 4(f)
market-based rate authority, but stated
that each applicant would retain the
right to propose other methods of
protecting customers that might better
fit the circumstances of its project.
62 Pursuant to § 157.20(b) of the Commission’s
regulations, any authorization granted for the
construction of a proposed project will establish a
time within which construction of the facility must
be completed and made available for service. We
have in the past granted extensions of time within
which to complete construction of proposed
projects. With regard to projects for which NGA
section 4(f) authorization is sought, we note that we
would not anticipate granting an extension of time
to complete construction based on an argument that
market demand for the project has not materialized.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
136. Therefore, in addition to seeking
suggestions for possible generic
safeguards, the Commission outlined
two generic safeguards for comment.
The Commission reasoned that entities
with market power can exercise that
power in two general areas: (1) The
withholding of capacity; and (2) the
extraction of monopoly rents. Therefore,
the Commission set forth two
approaches to protecting customers
against the exercise of market power.
The first approach would involve
conditions that limit the withholding of
capacity and the second approach
would involve rate protections.
137. The Commission reasoned that
market power can be exercised in
circumstances where a storage operator
can withhold capacity from the market
and thereby raise prices. The
Commission stated that as long as
storage capacity has not been withheld,
‘‘the fact that shippers may at times bid
up contract length likely reflects not an
exercise of [the pipeline’s] market
power, but rather competition for scarce
capacity.’’ 63 The Commission requested
that comments address whether by
ensuring that the storage operator has
sold or made available to the market all
of its capacity (and thus it is not
withholding capacity), customers can be
assured that market power is not being
exercised by the storage service provider
and that any increase in price is due to
customers’ demand for storage relative
to the available supply.64
138. The Commission recognized that
one difficulty in applying this standard
is defining when withholding should be
found to be indicative of the exercise of
market power. Therefore, the
Commission requested comment on
how to apply a prohibition against
withholding which balances the
competing needs of the project sponsor
to secure revenues adequate to attract
necessary investment in new
infrastructure and of the needs of
customers to be protected from the
abuse of market power.65
63 Process Gas Consumers Group v. FERC, 292
F.3d 831, 837 (D.C. Cir. 2002).
64 Id. (affirming Commission determination that
prices determined through an uncapped bidding
process were the product of competitive forces, not
the exercise of market power).
65 The Commission sought comment on several
consumer protection questions including: (1)
whether allowing the storage operator to set a
reserve price would provide an appropriate balance;
and (2) whether a withholding prohibition should
apply all the time, or only during periods of peak
demand for storage services? The Commission also
request comment on how terms such as ‘‘reserve
price’’ and ‘‘period of peak demand’’ should be
defined, if such conditions were to be adopted. The
Commission also requested comment on whether a
formal auction process under which the applicant
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
139. The Commission also pointed
out that market power can be exercised
in those circumstances where a storage
operator can extract monopoly rents and
stated that rate protections could take
several forms. The Commission stated
that rate caps could be designed to
provide adequate customer protection
while also supporting the financing of
new storage projects. The Commission
sought comment on whether there are
certain approaches to rate caps that
could be adopted as a generic safeguard.
The Commission also proposed that it
allow an applicant to establish a longterm (e.g., 5–10 years) recourse rate that
was cost-based and allow the applicant
to negotiate contracts under marketbased rates for shorter-term transactions
and requested comment on this
approach or whether there were other
cost-based rate designs or price cap
methodologies that the Commission
should consider.
Comments
140. With respect to the ‘‘customer
protection’’ findings required under
section 4(f)(1)(B), INGAA and Williston
Basin submit that the Commission can
rely on the same reporting requirements
and NGA section 5 complaint process
that it proposes with respect to
compliance with the statutory periodic
review requirement. INGAA and
Williston Basin also support the
Commission’s suggestion that it may
rely on a showing that a storage operator
has sold or made available all of its
capacity.
141. INGAA asserts that the focus of
customer protection should be those
customers receiving storage service at
cost-based rates. Other commenters,
including AGA, APGA, and NGSA,
place the focus on storage customers
seeking service under market-based
rates authorized pursuant to section 4(f).
EGSI requests the Commission to also
ensure protection for competitors.
142. Williston maintains that the
applicant should be allowed to propose
an adequate method of protecting
customers and the Commission should
address each application individually.
Duke also asserts that the Commission
should not adopt any generic safeguards
that will be the equivalent of price
controls. Duke argues that imposing on
storage participants an obligation to sell
available capacity is unworkable and, if
adopted, would eliminate any of the
potential advantages that would result
from market-based rates. Duke explains
that for an obligation to sell to be
meaningful, that obligation must be
is obligated to sell all capacity above a reserve price
should be considered?
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
imposed with respect to some price,
which inevitably leads to the imposition
of price controls.
143. Northern, Sempra, INGAA and
Enstor state that the circumstances of a
project should determine the
appropriateness of any given customer
protection. Northern maintains there are
some additional protections that should
apply, including an open season
bidding process with or without a
minimum reserve price, known terms
and conditions of service defined in the
storage provider’s tariff, a restriction on
the storage provider requesting during a
contract term that the market-based
rates it agreed to be increased, a
commitment by the pipeline to existing
customers that it will not allocate
incremental costs associated with a
market-based storage expansion to
existing shippers receiving storage
services under cost-based rates in a
general rate case proceeding, and a
requirement that market-based rates
should be subject to the Commission’s
reporting and posting requirements. SCE
urges the Commission to perform a
contemporaneous market-wide analysis
in determining whether to grant marketbased rate authority as well as
considering mitigation methods tailored
to the specifics of each application.
144. Dominion supports both the
case-specific approach to reviewing the
adequacy of customer protections, and
establishing generic protections that
will expedite the process. Dominion
submits that customers will be protected
from the exercise of market power if
they are offered long-term, cost-based
storage rates as a recourse service
option. Dominion asserts that this will
prevent a storage provider from
extracting monopoly rents because a
customer can always opt for the longterm recourse service. Withholding of
capacity is therefore not possible,
Dominion stresses, because the services
will be offered under open-access, nondiscriminatory FERC-approved tariffs.
145. PGC states it is appropriate to
establish a general rule requiring the use
of certain pre-established safeguards
where market-based rate authority is
granted. However, because some
concerns may be case-specific, PGC
supports requiring individual applicants
to carry the burden of demonstrating
that consumers are adequately
protected, separate and apart from their
compliance with any universally
established safeguards. PGC supports
the requirement that all capacity be
offered for sale and made available to
customers on a non-discriminatory
basis.
146. NYPSC supports the
establishment of generic safeguards.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
Specifically, the NYPSC maintains that
a condition prohibiting the withholding
of capacity would serve to protect
consumers. It states that the
Commission could address the pricing
issues associated with this condition by
allowing applicants to propose and
support a reasonable recourse rate on a
case-by-case basis. The NYPSC also
supports allowing intervenors to
propose other protective conditions on
a case-by-case basis. NASUCA asserts
that restrictions on withholding of
capacity would limit the ability of a
storage operator to exercise market
power. NASUCA urges the Commission
to require the storage applicant to post,
both continuously and on a real-time
basis, the amount of contracted storage
service and storage capability for each
storage service offered, the identified
differences being considered an offer to
sell.
147. AGA urges the Commission to
lift the cap on capacity releases in order
to permit greater competition with
storage operators to place downward
pressure on prices.
148. APGA maintains that the NOPR
errs in its assumption that the consumer
will be protected by requiring that a
market-based-rate storage service
provider sell all of its existing capacity.
APGA contends that the Commission’s
reliance on Process Gas is misplaced
because that decision relied on the fact
that the rates for the capacity in
question were regulated and thus the
pipeline would have no incentive for
refusing to build additional capacity.
This is not the situation the Commission
faces in the instant case. APGA also
contends that the NOPR erred in
fashioning customer and consumer
protections that disregard the statutory
requirement that rates and services
cannot be unduly discriminatory or
preferential.
149. To prevent the imposition of
either excessive or unduly
discriminatory rates, APGA proposes
that: (1) The Commission cap the price
of long-term storage service (i.e.
contracts with a term of one year or
more) and require tariff terms and
conditions for this service; (2) these
long-term contracts be subject to the
right-of-first-refusal; (3) storage
operators be allowed to sell any excess
capacity as short-term storage service;
(4) an auction be used to award storage
capacity where the storage operator
must make all capacity available at or
above a reserve price (a rate no higher
than the cost-based rate for short-term
capacity); (5) storage operators be
required to continually provide timely
information on storage capacity
availability and to initiate an auction
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36629
upon a prospective customer request; (6)
storage providers be required to
maintain a record for three years of the
quantities, rates, terms and conditions
and date of each market storage
purchase; (7) the Commission review,
every three years, whether the
availability and rates offered are just
and reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential; (8) the
Commission be allowed to proceed sua
sponte or based on a complaint to
determine whether the rates, terms and
conditions were or are just and
reasonable; (9) the Commission be
granted the authority to require the
disgorgement of unjust profits, invoke
civil fines, and suspend or revoke the
certificate or market-based rate authority
where it determines that the availability
or rates charged for market-based rates
were or are not just and reasonable or
are unduly preferential or
discriminatory; and (10) the costs of the
storage capacity for which market based
rates are sought be prohibited from
inclusion in recourse rates.
150. EGSI urges the Commission to be
sensitive to the need to protect
competitors as well as customers,
because a storage provider that has
market power and market-based rates
could use that market power in anticompetitive ways. EGSI agrees that one
way of guarding against such an abuse
of market power is the establishment of
a minimum ‘‘reserve’’ rate or rate floor.
EGSI suggests that such rate floor be set
at or above the facility’s short-term
marginal costs.
151. Enstor does not support the
adoption of the Commission’s suggested
generic consumer safeguards. Enstor
asserts that the Commission’s proposed
prohibition on the withholding of
capacity, and its suggested rate
protections, would upset the balance
between the customer and the storage
provider such that new storage projects
would never get built. INGAA also
rejects the ‘‘rate cap’’ protections
suggested by the Commission as simply
incompatible with market-based rates.
Enstor would support an approach
where the rate applicant would state
upfront whether it would be willing to
submit to an annual reporting
requirement detailing the agreements
and rates that it negotiated during the
preceding 12 months, similar to those
that section 311 service providers
submit. Enstor advocates that the
Commission adopt a 60-day ‘‘safe
harbor’’ review period during which the
market-based rate arrangements could
be evaluated. If the Commission took no
action during this time frame, the
arrangements would be left intact.
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36630
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
Commission Determination
153. As a prerequisite for granting
market-based rate authority, new NGA
section 4(f) requires that the
Commission, determine that customers
are adequately protected, and requires
the Commission to ensure that
reasonable terms and conditions are in
place to protect them. The Commission
will require an applicant for this
authorization to show that granting its
application can be done consistent with
the requirement of section 4(f)(1)(B).66
This may be done in different ways, and
as the NOPR proposed, we will leave
applicants with the discretion to fashion
proposals that will operate effectively
given the unique situations involved.
However, we will also describe methods
that an applicant might employ to
satisfy the Commission that the
customer protection requirement has
been met.
154. Customer protection starts with
potential storage customers having a fair
and open opportunity to contract for
proposed new capacity. One way for an
applicant requesting section 4(f)
authority to demonstrate that interested
customers were given nondiscriminatory access to new storage
capacity would be to show that it had
conducted a fair and transparent open
season. The industry has conducted
open seasons for quite a few years, and
the Commission has provided guidance
in individual cases on issues that have
arisen.67 A properly conducted open
season will allow a project sponsor to
test the market, attempt to negotiate
mutually agreeable rates which support
the project financially, and provide a
means to give the market fair notice of
and open access to potential new
services. Allegations that the process
offered by an applicant failed to provide
such fair notice and access can be raised
by potential customers in individual
proceedings.
155. APGA argues that the NOPR
erred in disregarding the statutory
requirement that rates and services
cannot be unduly discriminatory or
preferential. The Commission disagrees.
With respect to rates, nothing in this
Final Rule transgresses the statutory
requirement that they be ‘‘just,
reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential.’’ With
respect to services, every part 284
transporter, which includes storage
service providers, must comply with the
non-discriminatory access requirements
of those regulations.68 This rule deals
with the setting of rates and does not
disturb nor set aside other provisions of
the Commission’s open-access
requirements.
156. Another necessary component of
customer protection is ensuring that
existing customers are not subject to
additional costs, risks, or degradation of
service resulting from new services
provided under section 4(f). Potentially,
existing storage service providers,
including interstate pipelines and
intrastate pipelines, may request
authority to charge market-based rates
66 In its comments, NYPSC requests the
Commission allow interveners to propose other
protective conditions on a case-by-case basis. While
the burden rests with the applicant, interveners
may also propose protective conditions. The
Commission will give full consideration to such
proposals when it considers an individual case.
67 See, e.g., Ouachita River Gas Storage Co.,
L.L.C., 68 FERC Õ 61,402 (1994); Avoca Natural Gas
Storage, 68 FERC Õ 61,045 (1994); Northwest
Pipeline Corp., order denying reh’g, 61 FERC
Õ 61,047 (1992); Pacific Gas Transmission Co., 54
FERC Õ 61,291 (1991).
68 18 CFR 284.7(b), 284.7(c) and 284.9(b) (2005).
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
152. NGSA suggests that the
Commission take the following steps to
ensure consumer protection: (1) Assess
whether the applicant has provided
sufficient evidence that its rates will be
just and reasonable by examining
whether the proposed rates are ‘‘in line’’
with other storage rates within the
region that are charging market-based
rates; (2) assess other specific safeguards
as proposed by the applicant that
indicate that the applicant is willing to
mitigate market power, including
whether the applicant has negotiated
contracts that permit customers to
ratchet down levels or permit
mandatory ‘‘out’’ clauses or contracts
that include indexed-based rates where
the risk is shared by the applicant and
the customer; (3) require the applicant
to hold an open season, which if
structured correctly, will provide
transparency and enhance the
Commission’s ability to analyze and
review the conduct of the storage
operator; (4) apply generic customer
safeguards which would include a no
withholding requirement requiring that
all storage capacity be available at all
times with a ‘‘reserve price’’ based on
the range of rates charged for storage
area facilities with market-based rates;
(5) reaffirm existing policies including
the filing of a tariff that contains all
terms and conditions of service, as well
as standard forms of service agreements,
and the ability of customers to release
capacity and application of the affiliate
rules under Order No. 2004; and (6)
employ several prospective generic
actions for all applications which would
include the monitoring of an applicant’s
compliance with the implementation of
the safeguards and acting swiftly upon
receiving a customer complaint.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
pursuant to section 4(f). Any applicant
which already serves customers under
prior authorization must ensure that
existing customers will not be subject to
additional costs, risks, or degradation of
service as a result of a section 4(f)
authorization, and must explain how its
application is consistent with this
requirement.
157. In addition, successful applicants
will be required to separately account
for the costs, services, and commitments
provided pursuant to section 4(f)
authorizations, and to retain these
records for as long as they may be
required under the Commission’s
existing practices for pipelines
operating under the Uniform System of
Accounts.69
158. A third fundamental protection
is an open-access tariff stating the terms
and conditions of service offered. While
the rates would be left to individual
negotiation, within the customer
protections offered by that provider and
accepted by the Commission, the terms
and conditions of service must be
provided in a generally-applicable tariff.
As acknowledged and supported in the
comments of Northern and NGSA, a
tariff provides essential transparency
and basic knowledge about the nature
and quality of service to be provided. It
is also a touchstone by which all
customers may be assured that the
quality of service provided is
comparable for all customers.70
Although the NOPR did not refer to
tariff-filing requirements, we note that
the context of these authorizations is the
provision of open-access storage and
storage-related services offered under
Part 284 of the Commission’s
regulations. While parts of these
regulations are routinely waived in
market-based rate authorizations upon
applicant’s request and for good cause
shown, the Commission has
consistently required generally
applicable tariffs for these services and
intends to continue this practice for
authorizations pursuant to section 4(f).
This will also allow the Commission to
‘‘ensure that reasonable terms and
conditions are in place to protect
consumers’’ as required by new section
4(f).
159. EGSI asks the Commission to
expand customer protection to require
that competitors also be protected.
While the Commission does not
generally require that competitors be
protected, and does not read the
69 18
CFR part 225 (2005).
transporters offering service pursuant to
NGPA section 311, their statement of operating
conditions will provide similar transparency and
consistency of service for all customers.
70 For
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
customer protection requirement of new
section 4(f) to require such protection,
the Commission agrees that as a general
matter, storage service providers, like
other natural gas companies, should not
charge rates less than their marginal
costs.71 However, the Commission is not
here requiring that a storage service
provider authorized to collect marketbased rates under section 4(f) state a
minimum average variable cost rate
below which it would not be allowed to
charge. Rather, in the event of a
complaint, the Commission will require
the storage service provider to
demonstrate that marginal costs were
recovered under every rate charged.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
i. Withholding
160. In the NOPR, the Commission
requested comment on whether
customers can be assured that market
power is not being exercised if all
capacity is made available to the market,
and how to apply a prohibition against
withholding. NiSource Pipelines assert
that the Commission’s Part 284
regulations already contain a generic
safeguard against withholding of
capacity.72 INGAA states that an auction
process with an appropriate reserve
price would be an appropriate means of
complying with a no-withholding rule.
However, INGAA urges the Commission
not to attempt to establish generic
requirements for how such a reserve
price should be established. Northern
believes that an open season with or
without a reserve price (and with other
stated conditions) would be an
appropriate method of compliance.
161. PGC, NYPSC and NASUCA all
support the concept of prohibiting
withholding. PGC and NYPSC would
leave the method for achieving this
result to be worked out in individual
cases. NASUCA would impose
continuous and real-time posting
requirements on capacity, contracted
capacity and available capacity. APGA
would also require more capacity
postings, and would require the storage
operator to initiate an auction upon
customer request.
162. Williston and Duke, on the other
hand, argue that a formal auction
requirement with a reserve price would
reduce or eliminate the incentive for
71 See Regulations of Natural Gas Pipelines After
Partial Wellhead Decontrol, Order No. 436, FERC
Stats. and Regulations, Regulations Preambles
1982–1985 ¶ 30,665, at 31,543–45 (1985)
(permitting the discounting of transportation rates
between the maximum and minimum approved
rates with the minimum rate based on average
variable costs).
72 Citing, Process Gas Consumers Group v. FERC,
292 F.3d 831, 837 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (Process Gas) and
Natural Gas Pipeline Negotiated Rate Policies and
Practices, 114 FERC ¶ 61,042 at P 10 (2006).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
storage service providers and customers
to enter into market-based rates
contracts and they urge the Commission
to allow the applicant to propose an
adequate method of customer
protection. They argue that any
mandated reserve price would
constitute de facto cost-based rate
regulation and would nullify any
benefits offered by market-based rates
under these circumstances. Enstor
objects to any generic requirements or
prohibitions.
163. The Commission believes that an
applicant’s proposal that adequately
prevents withholding is one good way
to meet the customer protection
requirement. The Commission’s existing
part 284 open access regulations require
interstate pipelines to provide service
on a non-discriminatory basis to the
extent capacity is available and a
qualified shipper is willing to pay the
maximum tariff rate. In the absence of
proof that the service provider lacks
market power and a just and reasonable
rate, the Commission has no reason to
believe (and no basis for reasonably
deciding) that an applicant for section
4(f) market-based rates does not have
the potential to exercise market power.
In this context, a proposal that acts to
prevent withholding as a method of
exercising substantial market power,
tempered with a reasonable reserve
price which would allow a section 4(f)
applicant to recover its investment
appears to be the best way to satisfy the
test.
164. Several commenters have
suggested specific methods for setting
reserve prices. For example, NGSA
suggests use of the range of rates
charged for other area storage facilities
with market-based rates. APGA would
require a cost-based rate to be used.
However, the Commission
acknowledges the objections of
Williston and Enstor that a mandatory
reserve price is tantamount to indirect
cost-based ratemaking. Many other
commenters advocate leaving it to the
individual applicant to establish a
reasonable method of compliance. The
Commission believes that the most
reasonable course is to allow the
individual applicant to propose a
method that balances adequate customer
protections against withholding as a tool
for exercising significant market power
against the applicant’s need for revenue
sufficiency.
165. In its application for section 4(f)
authority to charge market-based rates,
the applicant must demonstrate how it
intends to comply with the nowithholding requirement, and must also
specify whether, and if so, how it will
establish a reserve price. The
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36631
Commission will entertain reserve
prices which represent a reasonable
price in the market to be served. A few
examples of how this price may be set
include: prices offered by competing
storage sellers in the same market, as
suggested by NGSA; applicant’s total
costs; applicant’s other already agreed
upon rates (e.g., the highest initial rate
agreed to at arms-length with a nonaffiliate in the initial open season); or
another type of reserve price for which
the applicant can provide a just and
reasonable basis convincing to the
Commission based on the facts of a
specific case. Applicants proposing a
method of forestalling attempts to
withhold capacity in an effort to exert
market power which does not include a
reserve price must convincingly
demonstrate how the proposal will
prevent the withholding of capacity.
ii. Other Rate and Service Protections
166. In the NOPR, the Commission
also sought comments on rate caps that
might provide protection against the
extraction of monopoly rents. In
response, Dominion advocates that the
offer of a long-term cost-based storage
service as a recourse service offering,
would satisfy the customer protection
requirement. APGA proposes a twoprong approach where long-term storage
services are first offered at price-capped
rates, with unbooked capacity available
to be auctioned for short-term services;
the short-term auction would be subject
to a reserve price no higher than the
cost-based rate for short-term capacity.
Many of the pipelines and storage
operators oppose any cost-based pricing
restraints as nullifying the incentives to
build new storage infrastructure.
167. The Commission will not
mandate cost-based price controls as a
method for ensuring customer
protection. On balance, we agree with
the comments that a mandated price cap
would undermine and perhaps nullify
the incentive to build new storage
infrastructure, which is the
Commission’s primary goal here, and is
otherwise tantamount to imposing a
cost-based rate, rather than granting
authority to sell at market-based rates.
However, the Commission views the
suggestion of a long-term cost-based
recourse storage service as a viable
approach that an applicant may
propose. In addition, some of the
concepts discussed above on the reserve
price issue may offer other methods of
capping prices which an applicant may
use in its proposal. For example, a price
cap based on the range of prices offered
by competing sellers in the same market
could be adopted without an auction
process.
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36632
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
4. Periodic Review
168. In the NOPR, we suggested that
regular Commission monitoring of
market-based storage operators based on
existing forms and data postings,
supplemented as necessary with more
specific information, would satisfy the
periodic review requirement of the new
NGA section 4(f). Appropriate action
under section 5 of the NGA would be
available should the Commission
determine, based on its own review or
in response to a complaint, that rates
charged by the storage operator were not
just and reasonable.
169. The Commission requested
comments on this approach, whether
further reporting or transparency
requirements should be imposed, and
whether the applicant’s proposed
customer protection requirements
should be reviewed every five years.
Comments
170. Several commentors generally
agreed with the approach described in
the proposed rule to rely on existing
reporting requirements, and NGA
section 5, to comply with the periodic
review requirement.73 INGAA submits
that the information currently reported,
along with the public information
regularly reviewed by Commission staff
and the information provided in
response to any specific complaint, as
well as the existing compliance
regulations, are sufficient to ensure
compliance with the statute. Williston
Basin and Enstor state that a more
formal review process, such as every
five years, would add unnecessary
expense and is unlikely to present any
additional information than is already
publicly distributed on a regular basis.
Sempra states that the reporting
requirements should be designed to
provide information that updates the
information that was initially relied
upon by the Commission in concluding
that market-based rates were
appropriate and to assure that such rates
remain just and reasonable.
171. AGA, on the other hand,
supports a periodic review of marketbased rates every five years in addition
to the proposed Commission monitoring
of public postings by storage operators.
AGA suggests that the Commission
provide an opportunity every five years
for customers and interested parties to
submit comments regarding storage
rates and consumer protection
measures. Similarly, NGSA also
suggests that the Commission institute a
periodic review at least every five years
or earlier if potential issues are detected
73 Comments of INGAA, Williston Basin, Enstor,
Dominion, and DTE.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
as a result of the Commission’s
monitoring or a filed complaint. APGA
disagrees with the Commission’s
suggestion that a section 5 complaint
complies with the section 4(f) mandate
that the Commission periodically
review whether the market-based rate is
just and reasonable and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential.
According to APGA, a section 5
complaint procedure suggests that the
Commission can impose only a
prospective remedy, which would fall
short of the consumer and customer
protections mandated by section 4(f).
Commission Determination
172. We find that the regular
Commission staff monitoring based on
existing forms and data postings,
supplemented as necessary with more
specific information required during the
course of any necessary inquiry,
coupled with our authority under NGA
section 5 will satisfy the periodic review
requirement of the new NGA section
4(f). Ongoing review of storage
operations, capacity subscription, and
transaction details would provide a
greater degree of customer protection
than would a formal review on a multiyear periodic cycle. Ongoing review, as
part of the Commission’s regular market
oversight and enforcement efforts,
would identify potentially problematic
situations faster and initiate solutions
sooner than a formal periodic
proceeding.
173. Existing reporting requirements
provide a wide range of information
regarding storage service operations and
rates. The Index of Customers filing
under § 284.13(c) reports contract
entitlements quarterly. The semi-annual
storage report under § 284.13(e) filed at
the end of the injection and withdrawal
seasons identifies the capacity
applicable to each storage customer, the
actual volume injected or withdrawn,
the revenues received, and any
discounts permitted. The information in
these reports, supplemented with adhoc staff inquiries will provide tools to
identify potential unlawful withholding
of storage capacity.
174. Storage operators are also
required to post a daily report of
available storage on their electronic
bulletin board or Web site under
§ 284.13(d). This data will allow the
detection of daily storage operating
patterns inconsistent with appropriate
market operations.
175. Storage providers also must
report the rates and terms of storage
service transactions under § 284.13(b) at
the time service commences. These
reports will provide the opportunity to
detect potential undue discrimination or
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
preference in storage rates or services.
The Commission reminds storage
operators that this requirement will be
monitored closely by our oversight and
audit staff to assure full compliance.
176. Financial and operational data
reporting in Form 2 or 2a is another
source of information useful in
monitoring section 4(f) storage
operations, rates, and services. We will
require section 4(f) storage companies to
fully comply with the financial and
accounting information required for
Forms 2 and 2a. While we have waived
these requirements for storage operators
found to lack market power, we will not
do so for firms seeking market-based
rates under section 4(f). Full compliance
is necessary to provide the Commission
with a more complete picture of marketbased storage operations for firms
presumed to possess market power.
177. The above sources of information
are available for regular monitoring by
the Commission staff and current or
potential storage service customers.
These sources, plus the ability of the
Commission staff to seek further
information as needed, will provide for
more timely review and remediation of
section 4(f) storage rates and service that
might fall outside of a range of
reasonableness or fail to meet the just
and reasonable standard than a formal
periodic review proceeding.
178. While the ongoing review of
section 4(f) storage operations by the
Commission staff would not be a formal
proceeding in which customers could
file comments, as suggested by the AGA,
customers would still have the
opportunity to make their views known
in several ways. Customers could
contact the Commission’s Enforcement
Hotline to bring problem situations to
the attention of the Commission.
Interventions in proceedings involving
section 4(f) operators provide another
venue for communication. Alternate
dispute resolution processes are
available through the Dispute
Resolution staff. The formal complaint
process under section 5 is available for
more serious concerns.
179. Although we believe that these
reporting requirements will be sufficient
to allow the Commission and other
interested parties to ensure that
customer protections remain adequate
over time, as required by the Act, in the
event it is demonstrated that this is not
the case for a particular project, we will
take whatever additional steps are
necessary to ensure that the periodic
review provision of the statute is
satisfied.
180. We disagree with the assertion by
the APGA that a section 5 complaint
procedure would fall short of the
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
consumer and customer protections
mandated by section 4(f) because under
section 5 remedies can only be
prospective remedy. There is nothing in
the new section 4(f) that implies a
remedial procedure for rates under this
section other than the prospective
remedy afforded by section 5 of the
NGA.
181. Finally, as noted infra, failure to
comply with the § 284.13 filing
requirements would constitute a
violation of the Commission’s orders
and regulations. A storage provider
would be subject to disgorgement of
profits and/or civil penalties from the
date on which the violation occurred.
Such a storage provider may also be
subject to suspension or revocation of
its authority to sell at market-based rates
(or other appropriate non-monetary
remedies).
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
5. Presumption of Market Power
182. Proposed § 284.505(b) provides
that any storage service provider seeking
market-based rates for storage capacity
pursuant to section 4(f) will be
presumed to have market power.
Comments
183. INGAA urges the Commission to
eliminate proposed § 284.505(b) that
establishes a presumption that an
applicant has market power. INGAA
submits that new NGA section 4(f) does
not require it and without a clear
picture of the implications of the
presumption, potential applicants may
be dissuaded from pursuing otherwise
meritorious storage projects.
184. Similarly, the NiSource Pipelines
claim that this presumption is not
consistent with section 312 of EPAct
2005. They submit that applying the
presumption would create precedent for
all subsequent proceedings that the
applicant possesses market power,
regardless of the fact that no market
power analysis has ever been
performed.
185. EnCana argues that consistent
with the intent of Congress, the
Commission should revise proposed
§ 284.505(b) by: (i) Removing the
presumption of market power, and (ii)
adding language which requires a
traditional market power study to be
filed by a storage service provider as
part of its § 284.505 application. EnCana
argues that the presumption of market
power is not present in section 4(f);
rather, EnCana asserts that Congress
contemplated that a traditional market
power analysis would be filed in
connection with a market-based rate
authorization granted under that
section. EnCana maintains that the
Commission should use this market
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
power study to determine what terms
and conditions to impose upon a given
authorization in order to provide the
protection required by section 4(f) of the
NGA. Encana asserts that the terms and
conditions imposed by the Commission
should be proportionate to the results of
the market power study; the strictest
terms and conditions should be
imposed when a storage service
provider fails both parts of the market
power test, namely that the market it
plans to enter is found to be heavily
concentrated, or it will have a high
market share in that market. Where a
storage service provider fails the first
part of the test (high market
concentration due to the small number
of participants), but shows that it will,
in that concentrated market, have low
market share, EnCana asserts that the
Commission should be able to impose
more lenient conditions based on a
finding that, despite having market
power, admitting the new entrant into
the market would increase competition
by diluting the market concentration of
the dominant player(s) in the market
area.
Commission Determination
186. In implementing new section 4(f)
of the NGA, we find that the
establishment of a presumption of
market power is warranted in order to
meet our consumer protection
obligation under the NGA to protect
ratepayers from excessive rates.74
Because new section 4(f) permits
market-based rates without a finding
that the applicant lacks significant
market power, we can not rely on
competition to ensure that rates remain
just and reasonable as we do under our
traditional market power analysis.
Rather, in order to ensure that the rates
we authorize under section 4(f) will be
just and reasonable, it is necessary to
establish a presumption of market
power in implementing the consumer
protection provision of the Act.
However, we clarify that the
presumption of market power is
intended to apply only for the purpose
of implementing section 4(f); and is not
a generic finding that would apply in
other situations.
187. We reject EnCana’s request that
we require section 4(f) applicants to
submit a market power study. We find
that implementation of such a
requirement is inconsistent with the
intent of Congress in implementing
section 4(f) which specifically permits
the Commission to authorize marketbased rates not withstanding the fact
74 See generally FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320
U.S. 591, 610 (1944).
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36633
that the applicant is unable to
demonstrate that it lacks market power.
Under the Final Rule, an applicant can
choose whether to file a market power
study under the traditional approach for
obtaining market-based rates or by
submitting an application under the
provisions of section 4(f) that does not
require a showing of a lack of market
power but requires the applicant to meet
other requirements including that
market-based rates are in the public
interest and necessary to encourage the
construction of the storage capacity in
the area needing storage services and
customers are adequately protected.
6. Applicability of Section 4(f)
Treatment
Comments
188. Enstor seeks clarification that the
Commission’s requirements related to
implementation of section 4(f) are not
applicable to an applicant that seeks a
determination that it lacks market
power.
189. Dominion seeks clarification that
new section 4(f) applies only to rate
treatment and not to the storage service
itself. Dominion states that it utilizes all
of its storage assets together to achieve
operational efficiency. Dominion seeks
confirmation from the Commission that
should it receive market-based rate
authority for a new storage project
under section 4(f), it will be able to
operate that field on an integrated basis
in conjunction with the other storage
assets that are subject to cost-based
rates.
Commission Determination
190. We clarify that the requirements
adopted in § 284.505 related to
implementation of section 4(f) are not
applicable to applicants seeking a
finding that they lack market power.
Rather, those applicants are subject to
the requirements set forth in §§ 284.503
and 284.504 which require an applicant
to submit a traditional market power
analysis. An applicant is free to choose
the procedures it wishes to be subject to.
191. We do not have a sufficient basis
to rule on Dominion’s request that we
find that if Dominion receives marketbased rate authority for a new storage
project under section 4(f), it will be able
to operate that field on an integrated
basis in conjunction with its other
storage assets. Dominion may file and
support such a request in any
proceeding it files pursuant to section
4(f).
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36634
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
3. Storage and Related Services Eligible
for Market-based Rates
C. Other Issues
1. Section 284.126(d) Notification of
Termination
Comments
192. Bay Gas requests that the
Commission remove § 284.126(d),
Notification of termination, from its
regulations consistent with Order No.
581.75 Bay Gas asserts the Commission
stated it was removing that provision in
the preamble of Order No. 581 but failed
to delete that section from the
regulations.
Commission Determination
193. Bay Gas’s request is beyond the
scope of this proceeding. However, we
note that on March 23, 1999, an errata
was issued in Docket No. RM95–4–000
modifying the regulatory text to Order
No. 581 to include the deletion of
§ 284.126(d). We have placed Bay Gas’
request in the rulemaking docket in
which Order No. 581 was issued and
will correct the matter there.
2. Encouragement of Certain Types of
Storage
Comments
194. Falcon Gas is concerned that
statements made in the NOPR regarding
the operations of salt caverns v.
reservoir storage may be read to favor
one storage project over another. Falcon
maintains that the Commission should
be clear with respect to its comments
and intentions and let the market
determine which form of gas storage
capacity is best suited to any particular
area of need. Falcon submits that
reservoir storage, with the appropriate
reservoir characteristics and equipped
with the appropriate number of
properly-configured wells and attendant
surface facilities, can very closely match
the operating characteristics of salt
cavern storage, typically at a fraction of
the unit development cost.
Commission Determination
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
195. The Commission clarifies that it
did not intend by its statements in the
NOPR to prejudge whether one form of
gas storage capacity is better suited to
any particular area of need. Rather, our
intent was to provide a general
statement of the function of certain
types of storage capacity. We affirm our
intent to continue to evaluate the merits
of a particular storage project on a caseby-case basis.
75 Revisions to Uniform System of Accounts,
Forms, Statements, and Reporting Requirements for
Natural Gas Companies, FERC Stats. & Regs.,
Regulations Preambles (January 1991–June 1996)
¶ 31,026 (Sept. 28, 1995).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
196. The NiSource Pipelines contend
that the Final Rule should not limit the
availability of market-based rates to firm
storage services. Noting that the
Commission has typically approved
market-based rate authority for small
storage projects, not storage services
provided by major interstate pipeline
companies, the NiSource Pipelines
contend that the Commission should
broaden the two methods proposed in
the NOPR for obtaining market-based
rates to include interruptible storage
services, short-term firm and seasonal
storage services. They also state that the
Commission should consider
applications for market-based rates for
park and loan services and other
services that provide storage-type
imbalance management functions.
Commission Determination
197. We clarify that the applicability
of the provisions we are adopting in
subpart M are not limited to firm storage
services. An applicant may seek marketbased rate treatment for any storage
services that it proposes to provide. We
will grant requests to charge marketbased rates for storage services to the
extent the applicant is able to meet the
requirements set forth in the
regulations.
V. Summary of Regulations
198. The Commission, therefore, is
revising its Part 284 regulations as
follows. New subpart M will be added,
which addresses applications for
market-based rates for storage. Within
new subpart M, § 284.501,
Applicability, explains which pipelines
or storage service providers are eligible
to apply for market-based rates under
subpart M, § 284.502, Procedures for
applying for market-based rates,
explains what procedures must be
followed for submitting an application.
Section 284.503, Market-power
determination, explains what must be
submitted as part of an application for
market-based rates, including what
information must be submitted related
to an applicant’s market power. Section
284.504, Requirements for marketpower authorizations, requires storage
service providers granted the authority
to charge market-based rates who also
provide cost-based service(s) to
separately account for all costs and
revenues associated with facilities used
to provide the market-based services.
This section also requires storage
providers to notify the Commission of
significant changes occurring in its
market power status. Section 284.505,
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Market-based rates for storage providers
without a market-power determination,
explains what a storage service provider
that does not seek a market-power
determination must submit to the
Commission in an application for
market-based rates.
VI. Information Collection Statement
199. The Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) regulations require that
OMB approve certain reporting, record
keeping, and public disclosure
(collections of information) imposed by
an agency.76 Accordingly, pursuant to
OMB regulations, the Commission is
providing notice of its proposed
information collections to OMB for
review under section 3507(d) of the
Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995.77
200. The Commission identifies the
information provided under part 284
subpart M as contained in FERC–545,
FERC–546 and FERC–549.
201. The Commission did not receive
specific comments concerning its
burden estimates and uses the same
estimates here in the Final Rule, as
modified to reflect the elimination of
the requirement that applicants granted
market-based rate approval after the
effective date of a Final Rule file an
updated market power analysis once
every five years. The burden estimates
for complying with additional filing
requirements of this rule pursuant to the
procedures in proposed new sections
284.503 and 284.505 are set forth below.
For the most part, the burden on
applicants seeking market-based rates
for open-access storage services will not
be changed by this proposed rule. Since
1996, applications for authority to
charge market-based rates have been
filed under the Commission’s
procedures applicable to NGA section 7
initial rate determinations, NGA section
4 rate changes, or NGPA section 311 rate
determinations under the Commission’s
existing data collection authorities. This
rule codifies application procedures and
filing requirements which are little
changed from the process followed
since 1996. Codification of filing
requirements will allow applicants to
know what information must be filed
with such an application and should
reduce the need for staff to send out
follow-up data requests and respondents
to file data responses. To the extent
respondents seek market-based rate
authority under the new NGA section
4(f) authorization process, also codified
in these regulations, the burdens may be
lower than if they had filed to seek
authorization under the Commission’s
76 5
CFR 1302.11 (2005).
U.S.C. 3507(d) (2000).
77 44
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
1996 Policy Statement. On average, we
expect the burden of making an
application for authority to charge
market-based rates under this proposed
rule to be 350 hours.
202. Over the past several years the
Commission has approved market-based
rates for storage services at an average
pace of about 4.5 per year. The
Commission is issuing this Final Rule in
hopes that more storage will be
constructed and operated, especially in
underserved areas. In reflection of this
36635
policy goal, the Commission estimates
that up to 8 filings may be made in a
typical year. While this estimate may be
high, in light of recent experience, at
worst the Commission is overestimating
the burden.
Number of
respondents
Number of
responses per
respondent
Hours per
response
Total annual
hours
FERC–545, FERC–546, or FERC–549 ...........................................................
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
Data collection
8
1
350
2,800
Total Annual Hours for Collection:
2,800 hours.
203. Information Collection Costs:
The Commission sought comments on
the cost to comply with these
requirements. No comments were
received. The Commission has projected
the average annualized cost for all
respondents to be $280,000 (3,500 hours
× $80.00 per hour).
204. Title: Gas Pipeline Rates: Rate
Change (FERC–545); Certificated Rate
Filings: Gas Pipeline Rates (FERC–546);
and Gas Pipeline Rates: NGPA Title III
Transactions (FERC–549).
205. Action: Proposed Information
Collection.
206. OMB Control Nos.: 1902–0154,
1902–0155 and 1902–0086.
207. The applicant shall not be
penalized for failure to respond to these
collections of information unless the
collections of information display valid
OMB control numbers.
208. Respondents: Business or other
for profit.
209. Frequency of Responses: On
occasion.
210. Necessity of Information: On
August 8, 2005, Congress enacted EPAct
2005. Section 312 of EPAct 2005
amends the NGA to insert a new
section, 4(f), which allows the
Commission to permit natural gas
storage service providers authority to
charge market-based rates, subject to
conditions and requirements set forth in
the statute. The Commission considers
the issuance of these regulations
necessary to implement this
Congressional mandate and to
encourage the development of new
natural gas storage facilities. The
proposed rule updates the
Commission’s market power analysis to
better reflect the competitive
alternatives to storage available in
today’s wholesale natural gas
marketplace. These changes should ease
the applicant’s burden in showing that
a Commission grant of market-based rate
authority is appropriate, thus
encouraging the construction and
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
operation of needed new storage
infrastructure. The proposed rule in
implementing EPAct 2005 creates
regulations that allow qualifying storage
providers to seek authority to charge
market-based rates when the providers
cannot or do not demonstrate they lack
market power. The proposed rule
revises the requirements contained in 18
CFR part 284 to add a new subpart M
to require that applications by storage
providers requesting market-based rates
contain certain information showing
why market-based rates are necessary to
encourage storage services and
including a method for protecting
customers.
211. Internal Review: The
Commission has assured itself, by
means of internal review, that there is
specific, objective support for the
burden estimates associated with the
information requirements. The
Commission staff will review the data
included in the application to determine
whether the proposed rates are in the
public interest as well as for general
industry oversight. The Commission
staff will review periodically the
transactional and operational
information provided by those granted
authority to charge market-based rates
pursuant to NGA section 4(f) to
determine ‘‘whether the market-based
rate is just, reasonable, and not unduly
discriminatory or preferential.’’ These
requirements conform to the
Commission’s plan for efficient
information collection, communication
and management within the natural gas
industry.
212. Interested persons may obtain
information on the reporting
requirements by contacting the
following: Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426 (Attention:
Michael Miller, Office of the Executive
Director, 202–502–8415, fax: 202–273–
0873, e-mail: michael.miller@ferc.gov).
213. For submitting comments
concerning the collection of information
and the associated burden estimate(s)
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
including suggestions for reducing this
burden, please send your comments to
the contact listed above and to the
Office of Management and Budget,
Room 10202 NEOB, 725 17th Street,
NW., Washington, DC 20503 (Attention:
Desk Officer for the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 202–395–4650,
fax: 202–395–7285).
VII. Environmental Analysis
214. The Commission is required to
prepare an Environmental Assessment
or an Environmental Impact Statement
for any action that may have a
significant adverse effect on the human
environment.78 The Commission has
categorically excluded certain actions
from these requirements as not having a
significant effect on the human
environment.79 The actions proposed to
be taken here fall within categorical
exclusions in the Commission’s
regulations for rules that are clarifying,
corrective, or procedural, for
information gathering, analysis, and
dissemination, and for sales, exchange,
and transportation of natural gas that
requires no construction of facilities.80
Therefore, an environmental review is
unnecessary and has not been prepared
in this rulemaking. We note that
environmental review will be prepared
in each proceeding in which an
applicant requests authority to construct
facilities that might become subject to
the rate-setting requirements of this
rule.
VIII. Regulatory Flexibility Act
Certification
215. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 (RFA) 81 generally requires a
description and analysis of the impact
the proposed rule will have on small
78 Order No. 486, Regulations Implementing the
National Environmental Policy Act, 52 FR 47897
(Dec. 17, 1987), FERC Stats. & Regs. Preambles
1986–1990 ¶ 30,783 (1987).
79 18 CFR 380.4 (2005).
80 See 18 CFR 380.4(a)(2)(ii), 380.4(a)(5),
380.4(a)(27) (2005).
81 5 U.S.C. 601–612.
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36636
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
entities or a certification that the
proposed rule will not have significant
economic impact on a substantial
number of small entities. The
Commission concludes that the Final
Rule would not have such an impact on
small entities. The amendments to our
regulations would apply only to natural
gas companies, most of which are not
small businesses. Accordingly, pursuant
to section 605(b) of the RFA, the
Commission certifies that the
regulations proposed herein will not
have a significant adverse impact on a
substantial number of small entities.
IX. Document Availability
216. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through
FERC’s Home Page (https://www.ferc.gov)
and in FERC’s Public Reference Room
during normal business hours (8:30 a.m.
to 5 p.m. Eastern time) at 888 First
Street, NE., Room 2A, Washington, DC
20426.
217. From FERC’s Home Page on the
Internet, this information is available in
the Commission’s document
management system, eLibrary. The full
text of this document is available in
eLibrary, in PDF and Microsoft Word
format for viewing, printing, and
downloading. To access this document
in eLibrary, type the docket number
excluding the last three digits of this
document in the docket number field.
218. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the FERC’s Web site during
normal business hours from our Help
line at (202) 502–8222 or the Public
Reference Room at (202) 502–8371 Press
0, TTY (202) 502–8659. E-Mail the
Public Reference Room at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov.
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
X. Effective Date
219. These regulations are effective
July 27, 2006. The Commission has
determined, with the concurrence of the
Administrator of the Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs of
OMB, that this rule is not a major rule
defined in section 351 of the Small
Business Regulatory Enforcement
Fairness Act of 1996.82 The Commission
will submit the Final Rule to both
houses of Congress and the Government
Accountability Office.83
82 See
83 See
U.S.C. 804(2) (2000).
U.S.C. 801(a)(1)(A) (2000).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 284
Continental shelf, Natural gas,
Reporting and recordkeeping
requirements.
By the Commission.
Magalie R. Salas,
Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission amends part 284, Chapter I,
Title 18, Code of Federal Regulations, as
set forth below.
I
PART 284—CERTAIN SALES AND
TRANSPORTATION OF NATURAL GAS
UNDER THE NATURAL GAS POLICY
ACT OF 1978 AND RELATED
AUTHORITIES
1. The authority citation for part 284
continues to read as follows:
I
Authority: 15 U.S.C. 717–717w, 3301–
3432; 42 U.S.C. 7101–7352; 43 U.S.C. 1331–
1356.
2. New subpart M is added to read as
follows:
I
Subpart M—Applications for MarketBased Rates for Storage
Sec.
284.501 Applicability.
284.502 Procedures for applying for marketbased rates.
284.503 Market-power determination.
284.504 Standard requirements for marketpower authorizations.
284.505 Market-based rates for storage
providers without a market-power
determination.
§ 284.501
Applicability.
Any pipeline or storage service
provider that provides or will provide
service under subparts B, C, or G of this
part, and that wishes to provide storage
and storage-related services at marketbased rates must conform to the
requirements in subpart M.
§ 284.502 Procedures for applying for
market-based rates.
(a) Applications for market-based
rates may be filed with certificate
applications. Service, notice,
intervention, and protest procedures for
such filings will conform with those
applicable to the certificate application.
(b) With respect to applications not
filed as part of certificate applications,
(1) Applicants providing service
under subpart B or subpart G of this part
must file a request for declaratory order
and comply with the service and filing
requirements of part 154 of this chapter.
Interventions and protests to
applications for market-based rates must
be filed within 30 days of the
application unless the notice issued by
the Commission provides otherwise. An
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
applicant providing service under
subpart B or subpart G of this part
cannot charge market-based rates under
this subpart of this part until its
application has been accepted by the
Commission. Once accepted, the
applicant can make the appropriate
filing necessary to set its market-based
rates into effect.
(2) Applicants providing service
under subpart C of this part must file in
accordance with the requirements of
that subpart.
§ 284.503
Market-power determination.
An applicant may apply for marketbased rates by filing a request for a
market-power determination that
complies with the following:
(a) The applicant must set forth its
specific request and adequately
demonstrate that it lacks market power
in the market to be served, and must
include an executive summary of its
statement of position and a statement of
material facts in addition to its complete
statement of position. The statement of
material facts must include citation to
the supporting statements, exhibits,
affidavits, and prepared testimony.
(b) The applicant must include with
its application the following
information:
(1) Statement A—geographic market.
This statement must describe the
geographic markets for storage services
in which the applicant seeks to establish
that it lacks significant market power. It
must include the market related to the
service for which it proposes to charge
market-based rates. The statement must
explain why the applicant’s method for
selecting the geographic markets is
appropriate.
(2) Statement B—product market.
This statement must identify the
product market or markets for which the
applicant seeks to establish that it lacks
significant market power. The statement
must explain why the particular product
definition is appropriate.
(3) Statement C—the applicant’s
facilities and services. This statement
must describe the applicant’s own
facilities and services, and those of all
parent, subsidiary, or affiliated
companies, in the relevant markets
identified in Statements A and B in
paragraphs (b)(1) and (2) of this section.
The statement must include all
pertinent data about the storage
facilities and services.
(4) Statement D—competitive
alternatives. This statement must
describe available alternatives in
competition with the applicant in the
relevant markets and other competition
constraining the applicant’s rates in
those markets. Such proposed
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
alternatives may include an appropriate
combination of other storage, local gas
supply, LNG, financial instruments and
pipeline capacity. These alternatives
must be shown to be reasonably
available as a substitute in the area to be
served soon enough, at a price low
enough, and with a quality high enough
to be a reasonable alternative to the
applicant’s services. Capacity
(transportation, storage, LNG, or
production) owned or controlled by the
applicant and affiliates of the applicant
in the relevant market shall be clearly
and fully identified and may not be
considered as alternatives competing
with the applicant. Rather, the capacity
of an applicant’s affiliates is to be
included in the market share calculated
for the applicant. To the extent
available, the statement must include all
pertinent data about storage or other
alternatives and other constraining
competition.
(5) Statement E—potential
competition. This statement must
describe potential competition in the
relevant markets. To the extent
available, the statement must include
data about the potential competitors,
including their costs, and their distance
in miles from the applicant’s facilities
and major consuming markets. This
statement must also describe any
relevant barriers to entry and the
applicant’s assessment of whether ease
of entry is an effective counter to
attempts to exercise market power in the
relevant markets.
(6) Statement F—maps. This
statement must consist of maps showing
the applicant’s principal facilities,
pipelines to which the applicant intends
to interconnect and other pipelines
within the area to be served, the
direction of flow of each line, the
location of the alternatives to the
applicant’s service offerings, including
their distance in miles from the
applicant’s facility. The statement must
include a general system map and maps
by geographic markets. The information
required by this statement may be on
separate pages.
(7) Statement G—market-power
measures. This statement must set forth
the calculation of the market
concentration of the relevant markets
using the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index.
The statement must also set forth the
applicant’s market share, inclusive of
affiliated service offerings, in the
markets to be served. The statement
must also set forth the calculation of
other market-power measures relied on
by the applicant. The statement must
include complete particulars about the
applicant’s calculations.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
(8) Statement H—other factors. This
statement must describe any other
factors that bear on the issue of whether
the applicant lacks significant market
power in the relevant markets. The
description must explain why those
other factors are pertinent.
(9) Statement I—prepared testimony.
This statement must include the
proposed testimony in support of the
application and will serve as the
applicant’s case-in-chief, if the
Commission sets the application for
hearing. The proposed witness must
subscribe to the testimony and swear
that all statements of fact contained in
the proposed testimony are true and
correct to the best of his or her
knowledge, information, and belief.
§ 284.504 Standard requirements for
market-power authorizations.
(a) Applicants granted the authority to
charge market-based rates under
§ 284.503 that provide cost-based
service(s) must separately account for
all costs and revenues associated with
facilities used to provide the marketbased services. When it files to change
its cost-based rates, applicant must
provide a summary of the costs and
revenues associated with market-based
rates with applicable cross references to
§§ 154.312 and 154.313 of this chapter.
The summary statement must provide
the formulae and explain the bases used
in the allocation of common costs
between the applicant’s cost-based
services and its market-based services.
(b) A storage service provider granted
the authority to charge market-based
rates under § 284.503 is required to
notify the Commission within 10 days
of acquiring knowledge of significant
changes occurring in its market power
status. Such notification should include
a detailed description of the new
facilities/services and their relationship
to the storage service provider.
Significant changes include, but are not
limited to:
(1) The storage provider expanding its
storage capacity beyond the amount
authorized in this proceeding;
(2) The storage provider acquiring
transportation facilities or additional
storage capacity;
(3) An affiliate providing storage or
transportation services in the same
market area; and
(4) The storage provider or an affiliate
acquiring an interest in or is acquired by
an interstate pipeline.
§ 284.505 Market-based rates for storage
providers without a market-power
determination.
(a) Any storage service provider
seeking market-based rates for storage
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
36637
capacity, pursuant to the authority of
section 4(f) of the Natural Gas Act,
related to a specific facility put into
service after August 8, 2005, may apply
for market-based rates by complying
with the following requirements:
(1) The storage service provider must
demonstrate that market-based rates are
in the public interest and necessary to
encourage the construction of the
storage capacity in the area needing
storage services; and
(2) The storage service provider must
provide a means of protecting customers
from the potential exercise of market
power.
(b) Any storage service provider
seeking market-based rates for storage
capacity pursuant to this section will be
presumed by the Commission to have
market power.
Note: The following appendix will not be
published in the Code of Federal
Regulations.
Appendix—Commentors Filing Initial
Comments
American Gas Association (AGA)
American Public Gas Association (APGA)
Arizona Public Service Company (APS)
Bay Gas Storage Company, LTD (Bay Gas)
Bridgeline Storage Company LLC (Bridgeline)
Columbia Gas Transmission Corporation,
Columbia Gulf Transmission Company,
Crossroads Pipeline Company, and Granite
State Gas Transmission, Inc. (collectively
NiSource Pipelines):
Dominion Transmission Inc. (Dominion)
DTE Gas Storage, Pipelines, and Processing
Company (DTE)
Duke Energy Gas Transmission, LLC (Duke)
EnCana Gas Storage Inc. (EnCana)
The East Ohio Gas Company, d/b/a Dominion
East Ohio, The Peoples Natural Gas
Company, d/b/a Dominion Peoples, and
Hope Gas, Inc. d/b/a Dominion Hope
(collectively, Dominion LDCs)
Edison Electric Institute and the Alliance of
Energy Suppliers (together, EEI)
Enstor Operating Company, LLC (Enstor)
Falcon Gas Storage Company, Inc. (Falcon
Gas)
Haddington Ventures, LLC (Haddington
Ventures)
Honeoye Storage Corporation (‘‘Honeoye’’)
Independent Petroleum Association of
America (IPAA)
Interstate Natural Gas Association of America
(INGAA)
Kinder Morgan Interstate Pipelines (KM)
National Association of State Utility
Consumer Advocates (NASUCA)
Natural Gas Supply Association (NGSA)
New York Public Service Commission
(NYPSC)
Northern Natural Gas Company (Northern)
Port Barre Investments, LLC (Port Barre)
Process Gas Consumers Group (PGC)
Sempra Energy (Sempra)
SGR Holdings, L.L.C. (SGR)
Southern California Edison Co. (SCE)
Williston Basin Interstate Pipeline Company
(Williston Basin)
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
36638
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules and Regulations
jlentini on PROD1PC65 with RULES2
United Energy Trading LLC (UET)
Unocal Keystone Gas Storage, LLC (Unocal)
Xcel Energy Services, Inc. (Xcel)
Commentors Filing Reply Comments
Duke Energy Gas Transmission LLC (Duke)
El Paso Natural Gas Company (El Paso)
VerDate Aug<31>2005
17:52 Jun 26, 2006
Jkt 208001
Enstor Operating Company, LLC (Enstor)
Interstate Natural Gas Association of America
(INGAA)
Jefferson Island Storage & Hub, L.L.C.
(Jefferson Storage)
Natural Gas Supply Association (NGSA)
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Southern California Gas Company (SoCal)
[FR Doc. 06–5642 Filed 6–26–06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
E:\FR\FM\27JNR2.SGM
27JNR2
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 71, Number 123 (Tuesday, June 27, 2006)]
[Rules and Regulations]
[Pages 36612-36638]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 06-5642]
[[Page 36611]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Part II
Department of Energy
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
18 CFR Part 284
Rate Regulation of Certain Natural Gas Storage Facilities; Final Rule
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 123 / Tuesday, June 27, 2006 / Rules
and Regulations
[[Page 36612]]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 284
[Docket Nos. RM05-23-000, AD04-11-000; Order No. 678]
Rate Regulation of Certain Natural Gas Storage Facilities
Issued June 19, 2006.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, DOE.
ACTION: Final rule.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (Commission) is
amending its regulations to establish criteria for obtaining market-
based rates for storage services offered under part 284. First, the
Commission is modifying its market-power analysis to better reflect the
competitive alternatives to storage. Second, pursuant to the Energy
Policy Act of 2005, the Commission is promulgating rules to implement
new section 4(f) of the Natural Gas Act, to permit underground natural
gas storage service providers that are unable to show that they lack
market power to negotiate market-based rates in circumstances where
market-based rates are in the public interest and necessary to
encourage the construction of the storage capacity in the area needing
storage services, and where customers are adequately protected. These
revisions are intended to facilitate the development of new natural gas
storage capacity while protecting customers.
DATES: Effective Date: The rule will become effective July 27, 2006.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Sandra Delude, Office of the General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502-
8583.
Robert McLean, Office of General Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502-
8156.
Ed Murrell, Office of Energy Markets and Reliability, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426.
(202) 502-8703.
Berne Mosley, Office of Energy Projects, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426. (202) 502-
8625.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Before Commissioners: Joseph T. Kelliher, Chairman; Nora Mead Brownell,
and Suedeen G. Kelly
I. Introduction
1. The Final Rule reforms the Commission's current pricing policies
to ensure access to storage services on a nondiscriminatory basis at
just and reasonable rates and to ensure that sufficient storage
capacity will be available to meet anticipated increases in market
demand. To achieve these goals, the Commission is modifying its market-
power analysis to permit the consideration of close substitutes to
storage in defining the relevant product market. This will ensure that
market-based rates are not denied because of an overly narrow
definition of the relevant market. Second, the Commission is adopting
regulations implementing section 312 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005
(EPAct 2005 or the Act),\1\ which permits the Commission, in
appropriate circumstances, to authorize storage providers to charge
market-based rates for service utilizing new capacity even when the
storage providers cannot (or do not) demonstrate that they lack market
power. The revisions adopted in the Final Rule are intended to
facilitate the development of new natural gas storage capacity while
protecting customers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Energy Policy Act of 2005, Pub. L. 109-58, 119 Stat. 594
(2005).(2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
II. Background
2. On August 8, 2005, EPAct 2005 was signed into law. Section 312
of the Act, adding a new section 4(f) to the Natural Gas Act (NGA),\2\
permits the Commission to allow a natural gas storage service provider
placing new facilities in service to negotiate market-based rates even
if it is unable to show that it lacks market power if the Commission
determines that market-based rates are in the public interest and
necessary to encourage the construction of the storage capacity in the
area needing storage services, and that customers are adequately
protected.\3\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ 15 U.S.C. 717, et seq. (2000).
\3\ Energy Policy Act of 2005, Pub. L. 109-58, section 312, 119
Stat. 594, 688 (2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. The enactment of EPAct 2005 added momentum to efforts already
underway at the Commission to adopt policy reforms that would encourage
the development of new natural gas storage facilities while continuing
to protect consumers from the exercise of market power. On September
30, 2004, the Commission issued a staff report that examined
underground natural gas storage.\4\ On October 21, 2004, the Commission
held a public conference with representatives of the industry to
discuss the Staff Storage Report and issues relevant to underground
storage.\5\ The Commission received oral and written comments in
connection with the Staff Storage Report and conference.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ Current State of and Issues Concerning Underground Natural
Gas Storage, FERC Staff Report, Docket No. AD04-11-000 (Sept. 30,
2004) (Staff Storage Report).
\5\ State of the Natural Gas Industry Conference, Docket No.
PL04-17-000, October 21, 2004; see State of Natural Gas Industry
Conference; Staff Report on Natural Gas Storage; Notice of Public
Conference, 69 FR 59917 (Oct. 6, 2004) (summarizing the issues to be
discussed at the conference).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. On December 22, 2005, the Commission issued a notice of proposed
rulemaking (NOPR) in which it proposed a two-prong approach for
reforming its current storage pricing policy.\6\ First, the Commission
proposed modifications to its traditional market-power analysis to
permit the consideration of close substitutes to storage in defining
the relevant product market. Second, the Commission proposed
regulations to implement section 312 of EPAct 2005 that permits the
Commission, in appropriate circumstances, to authorize storage
providers to charge market-based rates for service utilizing new
capacity even when the storage providers cannot (or do not) demonstrate
that they lack market power.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ Rate Regulation of Certain Underground Storage Facilities,
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 70 FR 77079 (Dec. 22, 2005), FERC
Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles ] 32,595 (Dec. 29, 2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
5. The Commission received numerous comments from a variety of
entities.\7\ Based on careful consideration of the comments submitted
in response to the NOPR, the Commission adopts a Final Rule that
generally follows the approach of the NOPR with certain exceptions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ A list of the commentors is included as an appendix to this
Final Rule. We have not considered the supplemental reply comments
filed by INGAA on May 31, 2006, due to the lateness of the filing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
6. First, the Final Rule modifies the Commission's market-power
analysis to better reflect the competitive alternatives to storage.
Specifically, we adopt a more expansive definition of the relevant
product market for storage to explicitly include close substitutes for
gas storage services, including pipeline capacity, local production,
and liquefied natural gas (LNG) supplies. The Commission will evaluate
potential substitutes in the context of individual applications for
market-based rates. The Final Rule eliminates the NOPR's requirement
that storage providers
[[Page 36613]]
granted market-based rates on the basis of a market power analysis file
updated market-power analyses every five years. Instead, storage
providers with market shares of ten percent or less would generally be
exempt from such a requirement. We will consider in individual cases
whether the specific facts and circumstances presented require
additional reporting for other storage providers.
7. Second, the Final Rule adopts regulations implementing section
312 of EPAct 2005, which permits the Commission to authorize market-
based rates even if a lack of market power has not been demonstrated,
in circumstances where market-based rates are in the public interest
and necessary to encourage the construction of storage capacity in the
area needing storage services and that customers are adequately
protected. Finding that the definition of facilities eligible for
treatment under new NGA section 4(f) is ambiguous, the Commission
defines ``facilities'' as it traditionally has for purposes of the
certification requirements of section 7(c). However, to receive market-
based rate authorization, the storage provider will still need to
satisfy the other requirements of section 4(f).
III. Need and Purpose for the Rule
8. The underground storage of natural gas is critical in assuring
that overall demands and specific requirements of natural gas customers
are met. Currently, there are approximately 200 storage facilities
subject to the Commission's jurisdiction, with an aggregate working gas
capacity of approximately 2.5 Tcf. Estimates of total domestic working
gas capacity (both subject to and exempt from NGA jurisdiction) range
up to 4.7 Tcf.\8\ Considering future storage needs of the United States
and Canada together, the National Petroleum Council (NPC) estimates an
additional 700 Bcf will be required by 2025.\9\ Although current and
projected storage development is keeping pace with aggregate national
storage demands, underground storage development in some market areas,
such as New England \10\ and the Southwest, is not.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ The Department of Energy's Energy Information Administration
(EIA) reports that in 2002 working gas storage capacity varied
between 4.4 and 4.7 Tcf, whereas the Department of Energy's Office
of Fossil Energy reports that in 2003 there were 415 underground
storage facilities with a working gas capacity of 3.9 Tcf. The Staff
Storage Report considered the range of estimated aggregate existing
working gas and concluded that the present working gas capacity is
3.5 Tcf, of which 2.5 Tcf is subject to NGA jurisdiction, and that
by improving existing storage reservoirs (i.e., by reengineering
existing facilities to enhance efficiency, rather than by expanding
cavern capacity), there is the potential to obtain another 200 to
500 Bcf. See Staff Storage Report at 7-10.
\9\ Balancing Natural Gas Policy--Fueling the Demands of a
Growing Economy, NPC, Volume II at 261 (2003).
\10\ New England appears to have little geologic potential for
the development of underground storage facilities.
\11\ See, e.g., Southwestern Gas Storage Technical Conference,
Docket No. AD03-11-000, Transcript at 23, lines 10-14 (Aug. 26,
2003).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
9. Over the last several years, there has been a marked increase in
the cost of natural gas and sharp swings in gas prices. Storage can
have a moderating influence on gas prices. As a physical hedge,
customers can build up underground inventories during times of lower
demand, and then rely on these supply stores to avoid paying high spot
market gas prices. Among the key findings highlighted by the Staff
Storage Report is that the ``continued commodity price volatility
indicates that more storage may be appropriate'' and that storage ``may
be the best way of managing gas commodity price, so the long-term
adequacy of storage investment depends on how much price volatility
customers consider `acceptable.' '' \12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ Staff Storage Report, at 1 (Sept. 30, 2004).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
10. In consideration of these factors, the Commission is amending
its regulatory policies in the Final Rule in order to facilitate the
development of new natural gas storage capacity to ensure that adequate
storage capacity will be available to meet anticipated market demand
and to mitigate natural gas price volatility, while continuing to
protect consumers from the exercise of market power.
IV. Discussion
A. Market-Power Test
11. The Commission evaluates requests to charge market-based rates
for storage services under the analytical framework of its 1996 Policy
Statement on Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for
Natural Gas Pipelines and Regulation of Negotiated Transportation
Services of Natural Gas Pipelines (Policy Statement).\13\ In the NOPR,
the Commission observed that in applying its market-concentration and
market-share screens in these cases to date, the Commission has looked
only to the availability of other storage alternatives (in the relevant
geographic market), in assessing whether a storage provider can
exercise significant market power. Noting that its current approach to
analyzing market power may be too limiting in some circumstances in
today's natural gas markets, the Commission proposed to reform its
market-power test for natural gas storage operators to more accurately
reflect the competitive conditions in the market for gas storage
services. The Commission proposed to adopt a more expansive definition
of the relevant product market for storage to explicitly include close
substitutes for gas storage service, such as appropriate combinations
of available pipeline capacity, and local gas production or LNG
terminals, on a case-by-case basis in the context of individual
applications for market-based rates. We posited that consideration of
these alternative products will ensure that the Commission's market-
power analysis accurately reflects whether a storage applicant is able
to exercise significant market power.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\13\ Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for
Natural Gas Pipelines and Regulation of Negotiated Transportation
Services of Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ] 61,076 (1996), reh'g
and clarification denied, 75 FERC ] 61,024 (1996), petitions denied
and dismissed, Burlington Resources Oil & Gas Co. v. FERC, 172 F.3d
918 (D.C. Cir. 1998).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. We explained that, as a general matter, competition to a
storage provider can come from entities that have the ability to
deliver gas in the same market as the storage facility. In producing
areas, storage may compete with production or LNG supply, in addition
to other storage facilities. In market areas, there may also be local
production or LNG available. In addition, available pipeline capacity
can function as a close substitute by delivering gas at peak times to
compete with storage. For these reasons, we suggested it would be
appropriate to permit applicants to present evidence that both
available pipeline capacity and local production/LNG supply in the
geographic market area can reasonably be considered as alternative
products to storage services.
13. In addition, we suggested that firm capacity available through
capacity release can be a good alternative in appropriate
circumstances. Under the Commission's capacity release regulations,
holders of firm capacity are free to release the capacity to other
shippers, as well as to make bundled sales at alternate delivery
points. Because of this flexibility, some portion of firm, contracted-
for capacity may have a sufficiently elastic demand (a willingness to
re-sell firm capacity when price rises) to serve as a good alternative
to an applicant's storage service. While pipeline capacity held by a
local distribution company (LDC) that is needed to meet state-mandated
service obligations for captive retail customers may not be considered
a good alternative during peak periods, LDCs
[[Page 36614]]
and marketers also serve industrial and other customers under
interruptible contracts. That portion of the LDC's capacity might
constitute a reasonable alternative.
14. Moreover, we stated that, in some circumstances, an applicant
may be able to show that even when firm capacity on a pipeline is
reserved for captive customers, e.g., residential and small commercial
customers, potential product or service substitution in downstream
markets might result in capacity becoming available in upstream markets
to compete with storage while captive customers continued to be served.
Under the Commission's open-access program, competition in a downstream
market may create competition in upstream markets, particularly due to
Order No. 636's requirement that pipelines provide flexible receipt and
delivery points and segmentation including backhaul. Thus, an LDC's
ability to buy capacity from another pipeline or storage facility or to
purchase gas in the downstream market may free it to release upstream
capacity to compete with storage in the upstream market. This ability
to buy capacity from another pipeline or storage facility or to buy gas
in the market area is present in the large downstream markets in the
United States including California, Chicago and the Northeast.
15. The Commission requested comments on these alternatives, as
well as suggestions regarding other approaches for quantifying the
amount of pipeline capacity that might be available to compete with an
applicant's storage services.
1. Expansion of the Product Market Definition
Comments
16. A number of commentors generally support the Commission's
proposal to liberalize the Commission's market-power test for market-
based rate authorization by expanding the kinds of storage alternatives
that it will consider in analyzing an applicant's market power with
certain proposed changes discussed below.\14\ They agree with the
Commission that available pipeline capacity, capacity release, local
gas production and LNG terminals all may serve as adequate substitutes
for gas storage in appropriate circumstances. These commentors also
state that they believe that the Commission's proposal should provide
further incentives for the development of new natural gas storage
capacity that will improve gas service reliability and promote price
stability in the future. The NYPSC agrees with the Commission that
local gas production, pipeline capacity and LNG potentially can be
offered as alternatives to storage service but requests the Commission
to adhere to the case-by-case approach and to allow for consideration
of whether there are realistic alternatives available on a firm and
long-term basis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ Comments of INGAA, Northern Natural, Duke, Williston Basin,
the NiSource Pipelines, Dominion, Sempra, DTE, NYPSC, Falcon,
EnCana, Bridgeline, Unocal, Enstor and Jefferson Storage. The full
names of commentors and the abbreviations used in this document are
shown in the appendix.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
17. On the other hand, several commentors oppose changes to the
current market-power standards on grounds that liberalizing these
standards is unnecessary and potentially harmful to customers. AGA,
APGA, NGSA, SGR and UET all question whether the proposed changes would
actually encourage meaningful development of new storage facilities.
APGA questions the NOPR's assumption that a storage capacity shortage
exists. APGA states that while the NOPR discusses the upcoming need for
an additional 700 Bcf of storage capacity by 2025, the NOPR does not
suggest, much less demonstrate, that the need will not be fulfilled.
NGSA submits that there is little evidence to suggest that the
Commission's current pricing policies have had a major influence on
developers' decisions to move forward with potential storage projects.
Rather, NGSA contends that there are multitudes of technical and
commercial factors that influence a potential storage developer's
decision to build storage that are equal or paramount to the
Commission's regulatory pricing policies including geological
limitations, environmental requirements and NIMBY issues.
18. AGA and SGR assert that the proposed changes would simply
provide existing storage providers the opportunity to charge higher
prices for services already available to the market and create
opportunities for cross-subsidies between storage and transportation
services. AGA also fears that liberalizing the market-power standards
would vastly increase the scope and complexity of the market-power
determination, while APGA submits that the NOPR's proposal to expand
the definition of the relevant product market for storage would
diminish substantially the showing required to obtain market-based
rates.
19. APGA also argues that the proposal is inconsistent with the
Policy Statement that defines a ``good alternative'' as one that must
have the same qualities of timeliness, price and quality of the storage
service it would replace. Specifically, APGA submits that pipeline
capacity (and local production/LNG and released capacity) are not good
alternatives, much less ``close substitutes'' in terms of quality of
service to the high deliverability storage service that the NOPR seeks
to promote. Similarly, APGA argues that in terms of price, pipeline
capacity is not a good alternative or close substitute to storage
service, because pipeline capacity is more expensive than storage
capacity.
20. NGSA submits that the expansion of the relevant product market
will not provide customers with the equivalent services uniquely
offered by new storage facilities and examining market elasticity to
determine whether product substitution can occur in downstream markets,
as suggested in the NOPR, is simply not realistic. NGSA and PGC stress
that the criteria and framework that the Commission utilizes to review
market-based rate applications have proven to be effective and
flexible, resulting in the approval of market-based rates for the
majority of applicants. Moreover, NGSA points out there are flexible
cost-based rates available to promote new storage capacity without
making wholesale changes to the Commission's exiting market-power
analysis. NGSA urges the Commission to consider whether it would be
more appropriate instead to adopt changes that will rectify the unique
problems identified in specific regions by undertaking a generic
proceeding to: (1) Identify where new storage capacity is needed; (2)
document known proposals in these regions; (3) determine what specific
obstacles may exist; and (4) establish regulatory policies to encourage
additional storage construction in those areas.
21. IPAA expresses concern with the Commission's proposal to adopt
a more expansive definition of the relevant product market for storage
to explicitly include close substitutes for gas storage services. IPAA
urges the Commission to carefully consider the potential impact of this
expanded definition of relevant product market for storage on other
cost-based services regulated by the Commission. (e.g., the regulation
of interstate pipeline transportation rates). For example, IPAA states
that if pipeline capacity and released capacity can serve as possible
substitutes for competing storage, then the potential exists for
storage to serve as a substitute for the availability of competing
pipeline capacity in evaluating applications for market-based
transportation rates. IPAA states it most likely would have concern
with efforts to expand the acceptance of market-
[[Page 36615]]
based transportation rates. Thus, IPAA strongly encourages the
Commission to consider the effect the expanded definition of relevant
product market could have on all services under the Commission's
jurisdiction, not just within the confines of an individual application
by a storage operator. NGSA requests that the Commission clarify that
these changes will not be used for the future evaluation of market
power for interstate transportation services but only for new storage
facilities as it has proposed for the EPAct 2005 provisions.
22. UET asserts that the Commission has not demonstrated that the
proposed change in the market-power analysis is needed to reduce
natural gas price volatility because price volatility is mitigated on a
national, as opposed to a regional basis, and storage development is
keeping pace with national demands. UET also argues the proposed change
is not necessary to solve regional storage capacity shortages in
underserved markets such as New England and the Southwest, because
proposals for new storage in these areas have failed for reasons other
than rate treatment. Finally, UET asserts that the proposed rule is not
necessary to cater to power generation load because the Commission is
able to meet the needs of power generation customers by developing rate
designs that would permit storage operators to earn higher revenues
from short-term services during peak periods.
23. UET also maintains that changing the market-power analysis as
proposed could discourage rather than encourage expansion of existing
storage facilities. It asserts that cost-based rates treat the storage
company fairly and also enable storage customers to participate
sufficiently in the natural gas value chain that runs from the wellhead
to the burner tip. UET alleges that market-based rates may disrupt the
value chain to such an extent that potential storage customers,
particularly marketers, will simply choose to exit the market rather
than serve as the vehicle for funneling market-based rate revenues to
storage providers. Thus, UET maintains that storage projects, for which
there is a demand at cost-based rates, may not be built because the
demand is not there for a project that would qualify for market-based
rates under the relaxed proposed standards. In addition, noting that
price volatility has increased as the number of major marketers has
decreased, UET urges the Commission to exercise care in embracing
market-based rates to encourage new storage in the name of price
volatility mitigation when those rates may actually increase price
volatility by further decreasing the number of marketers.
24. Finally, AGA, NGSA and Process Consumers argue that the NOPR is
unnecessary given the alternative of section 4(f) of the NGA. For
example, AGA asserts that the proposed regulations pursuant to new NGA
section 4(f) fully address the need to provide incentives for new
storage services and there is no need to provide more latitude for
qualifying for market-based rates for existing storage facilities. At
most, AGA asserts the Commission should considering broadening the
market-power test only after it has had an opportunity to assess the
impact and outcome of the new rules under section 4(f), a minimum of
two years after implementing regulations under section 4(f). Similarly,
NGSA while supporting the Commission's goal of maximizing storage
believes that liberalizing the traditional market-power test is
unsupported and unnecessary. Given that Congress enacted EPAct 2005 as
the primary vehicle to encourage the development of new storage
facilities, NGSA urges the Commission to focus its attention in this
proceeding on properly implementing EPAct 2005, and not engaging in an
unnecessary effort to provide incentives for new storage by revising
the existing market-power test. At a minimum, NGSA urges the Commission
to take an incremental approach and maintain the existing market-power
procedures, at least until it can assess whether its implementation of
the EPAct 2005 provisions can provide a sufficient and workable program
that provides a valid incentive to potential new storage developers.
Commission Determination
25. The Commission finds it is appropriate to adopt a more
expansive definition of the relevant product market for storage to
explicitly include close substitutes for gas storage services,
including pipeline capacity and local production/LNG supplies. As
explained below, this modification to our market-power analysis better
reflects the competitive alternatives to storage and is supported by
changes in the natural gas markets that have occurred since the mid
1990s. In today's markets, these non-storage products may well serve as
adequate substitutes for gas storage in appropriate circumstances.
26. As we explained in Order No. 637, the deregulation of wellhead
natural gas prices, the advent of open-access transportation and the
requirement that interstate pipelines offer unbundled open-access
transportation service, has increased competition and efficiency in
both the gas commodity and transportation market.\15\ Market centers
have developed both upstream in the production area and downstream in
the market area, providing shippers with greater gas and capacity
choices. The wholesale market has grown with new participants that have
the ability to deliver gas into many markets. The expansion of the
product market definition to include close substitutes simply
recognizes that buyers and sellers have a greater number of
alternatives from which to choose in order to obtain and deliver gas
supplies. From an end-use customer's perspective, gas is fungible,
whether it comes from storage, local production or more distant
supplies transported by pipelines. Competition with storage can come
from any of these sources that can deliver gas in the same market as
the storage facility. For these reasons, we will permit a storage
applicant to include non-storage products and services, including
pipeline capacity and local production/LNG supply in the calculation of
its market concentration and market share.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ Regulation of Short-Term Natural Gas Transportation
Services and Regulation of Interstate Natural Gas Transportation
Services, Order No. 637, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles
(July 1996-December 2000) ] 31,091 at 31,249-63 (Feb. 9, 2000).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
27. The Commission recognizes, however, that local production, LNG
and pipeline capacity may not be good alternatives to an applicant's
storage services in all circumstances. For a non-storage product to be
a good alternative it must be available soon enough, have a price low
enough and have a quality high enough to permit customers to substitute
the alternative for the applicant's services. For this reason, we will
evaluate potential substitutes in the context of individual
applications for market-based rates. In those proceedings, the
applicant will have the burden to demonstrate that the non-storage
products and services, as well as the other storage services, used in
its calculation of market concentration and market share are good
substitutes. Any party to the proceeding can challenge the inclusion of
a particular product on the grounds that it does not meet the
qualifications for a good alternative. Based on the record in the
proceeding, the Commission will determine if the proposed product is in
fact a good alternative that will limit the exercise of significant
market power by the applicant.
28. In the NOPR, we noted that although current and projected
storage development is keeping pace with aggregate demands, underground
storage development in some market
[[Page 36616]]
areas, such as New England and the Southwest, is not.\16\ We also
acknowledged that our rate policies will not guarantee the
proliferation of new storage projects because storage projects fail to
for reasons other than rate treatment.\17\ A few commentors claim that
the proposed expansion of the product market is not supported because
we have not shown that a storage capacity shortage exists or that
market-based rates will ensure that storage gets built. We disagree
that such findings are necessary to support the proposed change to our
market-power analysis. The courts have permitted the Commission to
institute flexible pricing to improve market efficiency so long as the
overall regulatory scheme protects against the exercise of market power
and protects and results in just and reasonable rates.\18\ Where the
Commission determines that an applicant lacks market power, the
Commission may depart from a strictly cost-based determination of
rates, and approve rates reached as the result of competition. The
Commission's authority to approve market-based rates has been approved
by the courts when the Commission has found sufficient protection
against the exercise of market power.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ NOPR at P 8.
\17\ Id. at P 14.
\18\ Environmental Action v. FERC, 996 F.2d 401, 410 (D.C. Cir.
1993).
\19\ Elizabethtown Gas Co. v. FERC, 10 F.3d 866, 870-71 (D.C.
1993) (Elizabethtown); Louisiana Energy and Power Authority v. FERC,
141 F.3d 364, 369-370 (D.C. Cir. 1998); Interstate Natural Gas
Association of America v. FERC, 285 F.3d 18, 31-34 ((D.C. Cir.)
2002); California ex rel. Lockyer v. FERC, 383 F.3d 1006, 1013-1014
(9th Cir. 2004).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
29. The Commission finds that its proposed regulatory change will
protect against the exercise of market power. In analyzing market-based
rate storage proposals, the Commission will continue to addresses
whether the applicant has market power; that is, can the applicant: (1)
Withhold or restrict services to increase price a significant amount
for a significant period of time, or (2) discriminate unduly in terms
of price or conditions. Before the Commission can conclude that a
seller cannot exercise market power it must either: (1) Find that there
is a lack of market power because customers have sufficient ``good
alternatives,'' or (2) mitigate the market power (i.e. permit market-
based pricing only if specified conditions are met that prevent the
exercise of market power). The only change the Commission is adopting
in this Final Rule is to recognize that in today's market, a storage
applicant's ability to exercise market power can be constrained not
only by other storage services but also by some combination of pipeline
and other gas supply alternatives.
30. Similarly, we do not share commentors' views that we should not
adopt the proposed revisions to the product market definition because
it may result in more complex proceedings or that there are flexible
cost-based rates available to storage providers. The Commission's
proposal is justified because it better reflects the competitive
alternatives to storage.
31. We also find that commentors' assertion that our action here
will inappropriately raise rates ignores the connection recognized by
the courts between competition and just and reasonable rates. In
Elizabethtown, the court concluded that because of the competition in
the pipeline's sales market it appeared that the pipeline would not be
able to raise its price above the competitive level without losing
substantial business to other sellers. ``Such market discipline
provides strong reason to believe that Transco will be able to charge
only a price that is `just and reasonable' within the meaning of
section 4 of the NGA.'' \20\ Granting market-based rates in situations
where there are sufficient alternatives prevents the exercise of
significant market power. A new entrant found to lack market power
offers another choice to existing customers, and in the Commission's
experience, more choice frequently leads to lower, not higher, rates.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\20\ 10 F.3d 866, at 871 (D.C. Cir. 1993).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
32. We also reject commentors' claim that Congress' enactment of
section 312 of EPAct 2005 bars the Commission from expanding the
product market definition for storage applicants seeking a finding that
the applicant does not possess market power. These commentors fail to
cite to any provision in section 312 of the Act that suggests Congress
intended to limit in any way the Commission's ability to revise or
modify its traditional market-power analysis. Rather in section 312,
Congress established an alternative procedure to permit storage service
providers that are unable to show that they lack market power to
negotiate market-based rates if the Commission determines that market-
based rates are in the public interest, are necessary to encourage
needed storage infrastructure and that customers are adequately
protected. The Commission finds it is reasonable to proceed under both
prongs.
33. As to IPAA's and NGSA's concern that our actions here not
prejudge the issue of whether storage can serve as a substitute for the
availability of competing pipeline capacity in evaluating applications
for market-based transportation rates, we clarify that it is not our
intent. Our actions here only address what non-storage products may be
considered a good alternative to storage services, and should not be
construed to address what products may be considered a good alternative
to transportation services.
34. Finally, we do not share UET's views that our action here will
negatively impact the number of marketers. Marketers, too, will have
choices in contracting for service from a newly authorized storage
service provider authorized to charge market-based rates and, as
discussed above, the price will remain just and reasonable within the
meaning of section 4 of the NGA due to the absence of significant
market power.
2. Scope of Applicability of Expanded Product Market Definition
Comments
35. Bay Gas requests that the Commission revise proposed Sec.
284.501, Applicability, to clarify that the newly proposed subpart M
requirements do not apply automatically to previously-ordered market-
based rate authorizations. Specifically, Bay Gas requests that the
Commission add the following language to the end of that section:
``provided, if such pipeline or storage service provider was authorized
to charge market-based rates before subpart M effective date, it need
not conform under that authorization to subpart M.''
36. Should the Commission decide to adopt its proposal to expand
the product market, AGA and NGSA urge the Commission to expressly limit
the application of any revised market-power regulations to new storage
capacity rather than to existing storage capacity that is currently
subject to cost-based rates.
37. NiSource Pipelines request that the Commission clarify whether
existing storage providers are permitted to seek market-based rate
authority using the proposed modified market-power analysis.
Commission Determination
38. As requested by Bay Gas, we clarify that applicants previously
granted market-based rates need not resubmit an application under the
broader definition of product market we are adopting in the Final Rule.
If an applicant has demonstrated a lack of market power under the
traditional definition of product market, it follows
[[Page 36617]]
that the applicant would qualify for market-based rates using an
expanded definition of product market that includes additional
substitutes. However, we do not agree that a revision to the regulatory
text is necessary.
39. We find that NGSA and AGA have provided no support for their
request to limit the applicability of the expanded product market
definition to only new storage capacity. Pursuant to the Policy
Statement, an entity can file an application for market-based rates for
storage services if it can demonstrate that it does not have
significant market power or has sufficiently mitigated that market
power. Where a company can show a lack of market power, then
competition in the market will ensure that the company's rates will be
just and reasonable and the purpose of the NGA is met. Accordingly,
existing storage providers are permitted to seek market-based rate
authority using the proposed modified market-power analysis. However,
the Commission will consider in the case of existing storage all
relevant facts of the applicant's potential to exercise market power,
including for example, impacts on existing customers and the
applicant's relationship with transmission service providers in the
relevant market.
3. Determination and Quantification of a Good Alternative
40. In order to show that a non-storage product or service such as
transportation is a good alternative, the Commission stated that the
storage applicant would need to meet the criteria set forth in the
Commission's Policy Statement. A good alternative is one that is
available soon enough, has a price that is low enough, and has a
quality high enough to permit customers to substitute the alternative
for the applicant's services.
Comments
41. SCE stresses that the Commission needs to adopt an analysis
that is as robust as its analysis of the electric markets and takes
into consideration the interdependence of gas and electric markets'
competitiveness. SCE urges the Commission to seriously examine the
limits on ``substitutability'' among the various products in each
market, noting the complex dynamic relationships involved in
determining this. SCE states that storage serves three basic functions:
price arbitrage, balancing and peak reliability, and customers consider
different kinds of storage and transportation products to perform each
function. Thus, each alternate product must be examined in the context
of its ability to provide competitive discipline on the operation of an
applicant's storage facility. Depending on the market structure, SCE
asserts that some facilities or products may only be able to perform
one of the three storage functions while others might serve all of
these functions. In addition, SCE stresses that the Commission also
must be willing to examine whether, and the extent to which, an
exercise of market power in the storage market may ultimately result in
supracompetitive prices elsewhere in the gas markets, i.e., other
geographic markets or other products.
42. Enstor urges the Commission to provide more clarity as to what
is, and is not, a good alternative, and how a market-based rate
applicant can demonstrate the same. In addition, Enstor seeks further
Commission amplification on whether an alternative is ``available.''
For example, Enstor asks in regards to LNG terminals in service, will
availability depend on the terminals' capacity or their deliverability?
43. EEI supports the Commission's proposal to include alternatives
to storage in its market-power analysis. EEI submits that this analysis
is fact specific and should be applied in the context of the region of
the country and the users that would be supplied by the proposed
storage services. With regard to released capacity as a competitive
alternative to storage, EEI asserts that the applicant should be
required to demonstrate that there is a viable market in released
capacity. In making this determination, EEI urges the Commission to
rely on historic information on the extent of trading in released
capacity on a relevant pipeline because such information is a better
indicator of substitutes for storage service than a theoretical
analysis of possible releases in the future.
44. With respect to quantifying firm transportation capacity that
could be available to compete with an applicant's storage service, DTE
recommends that all firm transportation capacity on all pipeline
systems that serve the applicant's geographic market that is not
committed to meeting the state-mandated obligation of LDCs to serve
captive customers be considered as available to compete with the
applicant's storage services, particularly during swing periods when
deliverability is most critical. DTE explains that capacity not under
LDC contract is generally held by marketers, end users, and producers
who are in a position to divert gas on short notice from contractual
primary delivery points to higher-valued markets in response to rapidly
changing market conditions.
45. Given that non-LDC shippers are in the best position to respond
to swings in the market and control where gas is delivered, DTE
recommends that firm transportation capacity be quantified on a
shipper-by-shipper basis for the purpose of calculating swing period
deliverability market shares and a Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI).
Under this approach, each pipeline shipper would be considered a
potential competitor to the applicant. On the other hand, DTE claims
that market-power studies should not assume that pipelines control
deliverability and can use shipper deliverability to respond to market
swings in a manner and time period that is competitive with storage.
That is, pipeline deliverability should not be quantified and assigned
to each individual pipeline for the purpose of calculating market
shares and HHIs. Pipelines are purely transporters and are not in a
position to divert gas on short notice to higher valued markets in
response to changes in market conditions.
46. DTE agrees with the Commission's statement in the NOPR that to
the extent an LDC holds pipeline capacity in order to meet state-
mandated service obligations to captive customers, it is not likely
that such pipeline capacity would be available to respond to market
needs nor would it be a good substitute for storage capacity and
deliverability. Similarly, DTE urges the Commission to exclude storage
capacity and deliverability associated with storage fields owned by
LDCs and used to meet state-mandated service obligations to captive
customers from market share and HHI calculations contained in market-
power studies submitted by applicants seeking market-based rates. DTE
states that like firm transportation used to meet LDC market needs,
firm storage capacity and deliverability associated with storage fields
owned by LDCs are committed to meet captive retail customer needs and
should not be considered available to the market to meet changing
economic conditions.
Commission Determination
47. As we have stated above, we intend to continue to evaluate
requests for market-based rates for storage on a case-by-case basis. An
applicant is required to identify ``the specific products or services
and the suppliers of those products and services that provide good
alternatives to the applicant's ability to exercise market power.\21\ A
[[Page 36618]]
good alternative has been defined as one that is available soon enough,
has a price that is low enough, and has a quality high enough to permit
customers to substitute the alternative for the applicant's service.
The burden is on the applicant to ``show how each of the substitute
services in the product market are adequate substitutes to the
applicant's service in terms of quality, price, and availability.''
\22\ Therefore, we will not endorse any particular method for
determining the substitutability of a product here, but rather base our
determination on the record developed in individual proceedings.
Regarding Enstor's request that we clarify whether the availability of
LNG terminal service will depend on the terminal's capacity or
deliverability, we find that both elements would be relevant in
analyzing the availability of LNG supply.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\21\ Policy Statement at 61,230-231.
\22\ Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
48. In order for an applicant to show that non-storage products are
a good alternative to storage, they must demonstrate that for peak
demand periods customers will be able to choose the non-storage product
as a comparable substitute for storage services offered by the
applicant. This demonstration must show that in terms of quality,
timeliness, and price that non-storage products will be able to serve
customers' needs as well as storage service. For example, an applicant
may be able to demonstrate that pipeline capacity in combination with
spot market purchases and appropriate financial market instruments,
such as futures contracts, can reasonably be expected to be available
at prices competitive with storage service so that it can act as a
substitute for storage gas purchased, stored and/or redelivered when
needed. Applicants may also be able to show that available park and
loan services or liquid market-center spot markets provide sufficient
liquidity during peak periods to constitute an adequate substitute to
storage for balancing purposes or to serve peak demand.
4. Additional Revisions to Market-Power Test
a. Inclusion of Other Gas Supply Alternatives in the Product Market
Comments
49. In addition to the pipeline capacity and LNG supply identified
by the Commission in its NOPR, Duke urges the Commission to recognize
that other gas supply alternatives may be available in a given market,
such as financial instruments, that can compete with storage. Duke
explains that storage allows a consumer of natural gas to manage price
risk by allowing the consumer to choose a price at which to buy natural
gas, store it, and then withdraw that gas as needed. According to Duke,
there are an increasing number of financial instruments that can be
used to manage this same natural gas price risk. Williston Basin claims
that other types of alternatives may exist as well, and accordingly
market-based rate applications should be looked at individually, to
determine what types of alternatives are available.
Commission Determination
50. As discussed above, we will continue to evaluate requests for
market-based rates on a case-by-case basis. An applicant may propose to
include other non-storage products as alternatives to storage services
to the extent it can demonstrate the proposed alternatives can be
delivered into the relevant geographic market and otherwise meet the
criteria of a good alternative.
b. Modification to HHI Threshold
51. Under the Policy Statement, the Commission's initial screening
tool for significant market power is the HHI, a formula that focuses on
the relevant market's concentration as an indicator of the potential of
an applicant to act together with other sellers to raise prices.\23\
The Commission uses an HHI of 1,800 as an indicator of the level of
scrutiny to be given to an applicant for market-based rates. An HHI at
this level indicates that there are four to five good alternatives to
the applicant's service in the relevant market. An HHI below 1,800
suggests limited market concentration with less potential for any
participant to exercise significant market power. However, an HHI above
1,800 suggests a higher level of concentration, and will cause the
Commission to increase its scrutiny of other factors such as the
applicant's market share, ease of entry into the market, the relative
size of the applicant's capacity, and/or the sustainability of a
potential attempt by the applicant to exercise market power.\24\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\23\ The HHI is the sum of the squared market shares. For
example, in a market with five equal size firms, each would have a
20 percent market share. For that market, HHI = (20)2 +
(20)2 + (20)2 + (20)2 +
(20)2 = 400 + 400 + 400 + 400 + 400 = 2,000.
\24\ Policy Statement at 61,235-36.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Comments
52. INGAA and KM urge the Commission to adopt an HHI level of 2,500
rather than the 1,800 that it currently employs as a benchmark for
measuring market concentration. INGAA asserts the current level is far
too conservative and is inconsistent with standards recommended by the
Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice (DOJ) for analogous oil
pipeline cases.
53. KM asserts that the Commission's reliance on the 1,800 HHI
level inappropriately relies on the DOJ's and the Federal Trade
Commission's (FTC) Horizontal Merger Guidelines (Merger Guidelines)
which apply to merger cases where two companies are merging and the
number of competitors is reduced. KM argues that the 1,800 threshold is
too conservative as applied to potential new storage entrants seeking
market-based rates because, in this situation, the number of
competitors will be increasing and the Commission will exercise
regulatory oversight. KM also points out that the Commission applies
the 2,500 threshold to oil pipelines where there is no merger issue and
the adoption of that threshold was supported by DOJ in filed comments.
Similarly, KM argues the Commission should adopt a 2,500 HHI threshold
for applicants seeking market-based rate authority for gas pipelines
where continued regulation of an industry rather than a merger is at
issue. KM also asserts that adherence to the 1,800 HHI threshold is at
odds with the actual DOJ and FTC enforcement decisions regarding
horizontal merger review, where it states that out of 11,263 challenges
initiated by the agencies, only 175 involved markets with HHIs under
2,500.\25\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\25\ Citing Federal Trade Commission and the U.S. Department of
Justice, Merger Challenges Data, Fiscal years 1999-2003, December
18, 2003.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
54. Finally, KM asserts that in today's markets, purchasers of
storage capacity are generally large LDCs or even larger and more
powerful marketing arms of large producers and the presence of this
buyer power is not accounted for in the Commission's HHI analysis.
According to KM, use of a higher initial screen would partially take
into account other factors such as buying power.
Commission Determination
55. We are not persuaded by the commentors' arguments that there is
a need to change the HHI threshold level. Significantly, as recognized
by KM and INGAA, the 1,800 HHI level is not a bright-line test below
which an applicant would automatically qualify for market-based rates,
or above which an applicant would be excluded from market-based rates.
Rather, the Commission uses the 1,800 HHI level as
[[Page 36619]]
an indicator of the level of scrutiny to be given to the applicant. As
explained in the Policy Statement, if the HHI is above 1,800 the
Commission will give the applicant closer scrutiny because the index
indicates that the market is more concentrated and the applicant may
have significant market power. Conversely, an HHI below 1,800 would
result in less scrutiny of the applicant's potential to exercise
significant market power because it would indicate that the market is
less concentrated.\26\ The Commission has applied this policy in its
analysis of individual cases and has approved market-based rates for
several applicants with HHIs above 1,800 after examining other
competitive factors. For example, in Avoca Natural Gas Storage
(Avoca),\27\ the Commission approved market-based rates despite an HHI
for deliverability of 4,100 in the relevant New York/Pennsylvania
market, specifically noting the small size of Avoca's market share and
the apparent ease of entry into the market as factors mitigating the
market concentration reflected in the HHI.\28\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ Policy Statement at 61,235.
\27\ 68 FERC ] 61,045 (1994).
\28\ The Commission reached a similar result analyzing storage
services in Steuben Gas Storage Co., 72 FERC ] 61,102 (1995); New
York State Electric and Gas Corp., 81 FERC ] 61,020 (1997); N.E. Hub
Partners, L.P., 83 FERC ] 61,043 (1998); Seneca Lake Storage, Inc.,
98 FERC ] 61,163 (2002); and Honeoye Storage Corp., 91 FERC ] 62,165
(2000).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
56. We disagree with INGAA's and KM's assertion that the 1,800 HHI
level is too conservative. First of all, it is not true that applicants
seeking market-based rates will always increase the number of
competitors in a market. For example, a storage provider may apply for
market-based rates for existing cost-based service. More importantly,
we believe that use of the more conservative approach will ensure that
the impact of other competitive factors will be given careful scrutiny
when the market is relatively concentrated (less than four or five good
alternatives). In addition, contrary to KM's assertion, we have not
adopted a generic 2,500 HHI level in analyzing whether an oil pipeline
has market power.\29\ Moreover, the use of HHI levels in determining
whether an oil pipeline has market power in individual cases reflects
the specific competitive circumstances affecting oil pipelines.
Specifically, oil pipelines face competition not only from other oil
pipeline providers but also from other modes of delivering oil such as
rail, barges and trucks.\30\ In general, there are not similar
alternative modes of delivering or storing natural gas. Further, as
common carriers, oil pipelines operate in a different regulatory
context.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ Market-Based Ratemaking for Oil Pipelines, Order No. 572,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,007 at 31,192 (Oct. 28, 1994) (``[T]he
Commission is not proposing any particular HHI level, such as 1,800
or 2,500, as a screen or presumption, rebuttable or otherwise. All
factors must be considered in determining whether an oil pipeline
lacks significant market power.'').
\30\ Id. at 31,191.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
57. Additionally, we do not agree with KM that a higher initial
screen is appropriate to take into account the fact that purchasers of
storage capacity are generally large LDCs or marketing arms of large
producers. First of all, the purchasers of storage services are not
always large LDCs and marketers and to implement an analysis premised
on the assumption that they are is not appropriate. Under the Policy
Statement we consider issues related to buyer power separately (outside
the context of the HHI threshold) which permits the Commissions to
consider the specific facts presented in a case. We find this approach
superior to the approach advocated by KM.
c. Entry and Other Competitive Factors
Comments
58. Duke asserts that while the inclusion of currently available
competitive alternatives in the definition of the market for the
purposes of calculating market concentration and market share values,
as advocated above, is a good starting point, such a revision alone,
while necessary, will not address the barriers to development faced by
markets with little existing gas supply infrastructure. To promote the
development of additional storage infrastructure in these areas, Duke
urges the Commission to shift the overall focus of its market-based
rate analysis away from requiring evidence of an existing market to an
analysis of the extent to which a new entrant increases the potential
gas supply options available to market participants. Duke states the
Commission's market-based rate policy should focus on: (1) Whether the
new entrant adds new storage options to the market, and (2) whether
there are further opportunities for additional entrants to take similar
risks and develop competitive storage. Duke urges the Commission to
adjust its existing approach to focus less on the status of existing
competition and more upon the potential benefits of adding additional
storage by: (1) Making it clear that applicants may rely upon evidence
of potential developments of storage in circumstances where there is
little or no existing competition, or (2) by making a generic
determinations concerning the potential competitiveness of particular
areas of the country.
Commission Determination
59. The Commission believes that the analytical framework for
establishing market-based rates set forth in the Policy Statement
already adequately accommodates other competitive factors such as the
ability of other entities to enter the market. In the Policy Statement,
the Commission specifically recognized that having a large market share
in a concentrated market does not constitute market power if ease of
entry and other competitive factors can prevent the applicant from
exercising significant market power.\31\ In a recent order in Rendevous
Gas Services, L.L.C., the Commission granted market-based rates for hub
transportation service based on the ease of entry into the market
center and the fact that the proposed pipeline was a new entrant with
no captive customers.\32\ Similarly, when requesting market-based rates
for storage services, an applicant is permitted to establish that it
lacks market power by demonstrating that if it increases its price,
ease of entry by other providers into the market will make such a price
increase unprofitable. Moreover, in response to Duke's assertion that
we should focus more on the benefits of new entry than market
concentration statistics, we recognize that there are significant
benefits to competition and customers from new storage and note that,
under our policy, HHI calculations of market concentration are used as
a screening tool and are not dispositive of whether we will grant a
request for market-based rates. Instead, we will consider all relevant
factors, including the benefits of new entry, in determining whether to
approve market based rates. The Commission will evaluate such proposals
on a case-by-case basis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ Policy Statement at 61,235.
\32\ Rendevous Gas Services, L.L.C., order issuing certificates,
112 FERC ] 61,141; reh'g. denied, 113 FERC ] 61,169 (2005). See also
Avoca, 68 FERC ] 61,045 (1994); Steuben Gas Storage Co., 72 FERC ]
61,102 (1995); New York State Electric and Gas Corp., 81 FERC ]
61,020 (1997); N.E. Hub Partners, L.P., 83 FERC ] 61,043 (1998);
Seneca Lake Storage, Inc., 98 FERC ] 61,163 (2002); and Honeoye
Storage Corp., 91 FERC ] 62,165 (2000).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
d. Definition of Geographic Market
Comments
60. DTE states that while the Commission's NOPR takes the important
step of presenting an expanded definition for storage substitutes, the
NOPR does not clarify how an applicant seeking to demonstrate a lack of
market power
[[Page 36620]]
should define its geographic market. DTE seeks Commission guidance as
to how to define the relevant geographic storage market in order to
provide more certainty to an applicant seeking market-based rates for
new storage capacity in more competitive markets needing new capacity
or improved service flexibility. DTE recommends that, in developing a
geographic market definition for a market power study, the Commission
should base its geographic market definition on the ability of storage
customers to access storage providers in various regions. In addition,
DTE argues that customer access to alternative storage providers can be
confirmed by reviewing the applicant's potential shippers or shippers
accessed by comparably located and situated storage providers, for
example, as shown in a shipper index.
Commission Deter