Milk in the Upper Midwest Marketing Area; Recommended Decision and Opportunity To File Written Exceptions on Proposed Amendments to Tentative Marketing Agreement and Order, 9004-9015 [06-1585]
Download as PDF
9004
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
Dated: February 15, 2006.
Lloyd C. Day,
Administrator, Agricultural Marketing
Service.
[FR Doc. E6–2436 Filed 2–21–06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 3410–02–P
DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE
Agricultural Marketing Service
7 CFR Part 1030
[Docket No. AO–361–A39; DA–04–03B]
Milk in the Upper Midwest Marketing
Area; Recommended Decision and
Opportunity To File Written Exceptions
on Proposed Amendments to Tentative
Marketing Agreement and Order
Agricultural Marketing Service,
USDA.
ACTION: Proposed rule; Recommended
Decision.
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: This decision recommends
adoption of proposals that would amend
certain features of the Upper Midwest
(UMW) Federal milk marketing order.
Specifically, this decision recommends
adoption of proposals that would deter
the de-pooling of milk and increase the
order’s maximum administrative
assessment rate.
DATES: Comments must be submitted on
or before April 24, 2006.
ADDRESSES: Comments (six copies)
should be filed with the Hearing Clerk,
United States Department of
Agriculture, STOP 9200—Room 1031,
1400 Independence Avenue, SW.,
Washington, DC 20250–9200.
Comments may also be submitted at the
Federal e-Rulemaking portal: https://
www.regulations.gov or by e-mail:
amsdairycomments@usda.gov.
Reference should be made to the title of
action and docket number.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Gino Tosi, Associate Deputy
Administrator, Order Formulation and
Enforcement Branch, USDA/AMS/Dairy
Programs, STOP 0231—Room 2968,
1400 Independence Avenue, SW.,
Washington, DC 20250–0231, (202) 690–
1366, e-mail gino.tosi@usda.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This
decision recommends adoption of
amendments that would: (1) Establish a
limit on the volume of milk a handler
may pool during the months of April
through February to 125 percent of the
volume of milk pooled in the prior
month; (2) Establish a limit on the
volume of milk a handler may pool
during the month of March to 135
percent of the volume of milk pooled in
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
the prior month; and (3) Allow the
market administrator to increase the
maximum administrative assessment
rate up to 8 cents per hundredweight on
all pooled milk if necessary to maintain
the required fund reserves.
This administrative action is governed
by the provisions of sections 556 and
557 of Title 5 of the United States Code
and, therefore, is excluded from the
requirements of Executive Order 12866.
The amendments to the rules
proposed herein have been reviewed
under Executive Order 12988, Civil
Justice Reform. They are not intended to
have a retroactive effect. If adopted, the
proposed amendments would not
preempt any state or local laws,
regulations, or policies, unless they
present an irreconcilable conflict with
this rule.
The Agricultural Marketing
Agreement Act of 1937, as amended (7
U.S.C. 601–674), provides that
administrative proceedings must be
exhausted before parties may file suit in
court. Under section 608c(15)(A) of the
Act, any handler subject to an order may
request modification or exemption from
such order by filing with the
Department a petition stating that the
order, any provision of the order, or any
obligation imposed in connection with
the order is not in accordance with the
law. A handler is afforded the
opportunity for a hearing on the
petition. After a hearing, the Department
would rule on the petition. The Act
provides that the district court of the
United States in any district in which
the handler is an inhabitant, or has its
principal place of business, has
jurisdiction in equity to review the
Department ruling on the petition,
provided a bill in equity is filed not
later than 20 days after the date of the
entry of the ruling.
Regulatory Flexibility Act and
Paperwork Reduction Act
In accordance with the Regulatory
Flexibility Act (5 U.S.C. 601 et seq.), the
Agricultural Marketing Service has
considered the economic impact of this
action on small entities and has certified
that this proposed rule will not have a
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities.
For the purpose of the Regulatory
Flexibility Act, a dairy farm is
considered a ‘‘small business’’ if it has
an annual gross revenue of less than
$750,000, and a dairy products
manufacturer is a ‘‘small business’’ if it
has fewer than 500 employees. For the
purposes of determining which dairy
farms are ‘‘small businesses,’’ the
$750,000 per year criterion was used to
establish a production guideline of
PO 00000
Frm 00011
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
500,000 pounds per month. Although
this guideline does not factor in
additional monies that may be received
by dairy producers, it should be an
inclusive standard for most ‘‘small’’
dairy farmers. For purposes of
determining a handler’s size, if the plant
is part of a larger company operating
multiple plants that collectively exceed
the 500-employee limit, the plant will
be considered a large business even if
the local plant has fewer than 500
employees.
During August 2004, the month
during which the hearing occurred,
there were 15,802 dairy producers
pooled on and 60 handlers regulated by
the UMW order. Approximately 15,608
producers, or 97 percent, were
considered small businesses based on
the above criteria. Of the 60 handlers
regulated by the UMW during August
2004, 49 handlers, or 82 percent, were
considered small businesses.
The recommended amendments for
adoption of the pooling standards serve
to revise established criteria that
determine those producers, producer
milk, and plants that have a reasonable
association with and consistently serve
the fluid needs of the UMW marketing
area. Criteria for pooling milk are
established on the basis of performance
standards that are considered adequate
to meet the Class I fluid needs of the
market and, by doing so, determine
those producers who are eligible to
share in the revenue that arises from the
classified pricing of milk.
Criteria for pooling are established
without regard to the size of any dairy
industry organization or entity.
Administrative assessments are
similarly charged without regard to the
size of any dairy industry organization
or entity. Therefore, the proposed
amendments will not have a significant
economic impact on a substantial
number of small entities.
A review of reporting requirements
was completed under the Paperwork
Reduction Act of 1995 (44 U.S.C.
Chapter 35). It was determined that
these proposed amendments would
have no impact on reporting,
recordkeeping, or other compliance
requirements because they would
remain identical to the current
requirements. No new forms are
proposed and no additional reporting
requirements would be necessary.
This recommended decision does not
require additional information
collection that requires clearance by the
Office of Management and Budget
(OMB) beyond currently approved
information collection. The primary
sources of data used to complete the
approved forms are routinely used in
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
most business transactions. The forms
require only a minimal amount of
information which can be supplied
without data processing equipment or a
trained statistical staff. Thus, the
information collection and reporting
burden is relatively small. Requiring the
same reports for all handlers does not
significantly disadvantage any handler
that is smaller than the industry
average.
No other burdens are expected to fall
on the dairy industry as a result of
overlapping Federal rules. This
rulemaking proceeding does not
duplicate, overlap, or conflict with any
existing Federal rules.
Interested parties are invited to
submit comments on the probable
regulatory and informational impact of
this proposed rule on small entities.
Also, parties may suggest modifications
of this proposal for the purpose of
tailoring their applicability to small
businesses.
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
Prior Documents in This Proceeding
Notice of Hearing: Issued June 15,
2004; published June 23, 2004 (69 FR
34963).
Notice of Hearing Delay: Issued July
14, 2004; published July 21, 2004 (69 FR
43538).
Tentative Partial Decision: Issued
April 8, 2005; published April 14, 2005
(70 FR 19709).
Interim Final Rule: Issued May 26,
2005; published June 1, 2005 (70 FR
31321).
Final Partial Decision: Issued
September 29, 2005; published October
5, 2005 (70 FR 58086).
Preliminary Statement
Notice is hereby given of the filing
with the Hearing Clerk of this
recommended decision with respect to
proposed amendments to the tentative
marketing agreement and the order
regulating the handling of milk in the
UMW marketing area. This notice is
issued pursuant to the provisions of the
Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act
and the applicable rules of practice and
procedure governing the formulation of
marketing agreements and marketing
orders (7 CFR part 900).
Interested parties may file written
exceptions to this decision with the
Hearing Clerk, U.S. Department of
Agriculture, STOP 9200—Room 1031,
1400 Independence Avenue, SW.,
Washington DC 20250–9200, by April
24, 2006. Six copies of the exceptions
should be filed. All written submissions
made pursuant to this notice will be
made available for public inspection at
the Office of the Hearing Clerk during
regular business hours (7 CFR 1.27(b)).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
The hearing notice specifically
invited interested persons to present
evidence concerning the probable
regulatory and informational impact of
the proposals on small businesses. Some
evidence was received that specifically
addressed these issues and some of the
evidence encompassed entities of
various sizes.
A public hearing was held upon
proposed amendments to the marketing
agreement and the order regulating the
handling of milk in the UMW marketing
area. The hearing was held pursuant to
the provisions of the Agricultural
Marketing Agreement Act of 1937
(AMAA), as amended (7 U.S.C. 601–
674), and the applicable rules of
practice and procedure governing the
formulation of marketing agreements
and marketing orders (7 CFR part 900).
The proposed amendments set forth
below are based on the record of a
public hearing held at Bloomington,
Minnesota, on August 16–19, 2004,
pursuant to a notice of hearing issued
June 16, 2004, published June 23, 2004,
and a notice of hearing delay issued July
14, 2004, and published July 21, 2004.
The material issues on the record of
hearing relate to:
1. Pooling Standards
A. Establishing Pooling Limits
B. Producer definition.
2. Administrative assessment rate.
Findings and Conclusions
This recommended decision
specifically addresses proposals
published in the hearing notice as
Proposals 3, 4, 5 and features of
Proposal 2 that seek to establish a limit
on the volume of milk that can be
pooled on the order, features of Proposal
6 intending to clarify the Producer
definition by providing a definition of
‘‘temporary loss of Grade A approval,’’
and Proposal 7 which seeks to increase
the order’s maximum administrative
assessment rate. As published in the
hearing notice, Proposals 1, 6, and a
portion of Proposal 2 concerning
diversion limit standards and
transportation credits were addressed in
a tentative partial decision published on
April 14, 2005 (70 FR 19709). For the
purpose of this recommended decision,
references to Proposal 2 will only
pertain to the first portion regarding depooling and references to Proposal 6
will only pertain to establishing a
definition of ‘‘temporary loss of Grade A
approval.’’
The following findings and
conclusions on the material issues are
based on evidence presented at the
hearing and the record thereof:
PO 00000
Frm 00012
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
9005
1. Pooling Standards
A. Establishing Pooling Limits
Preliminary Statement
Federal milk marketing orders rely on
the tools of classified pricing and
marketwide pooling to assure an
adequate supply of milk for fluid (Class
I) use and to provide for the equitable
sharing of the revenues arising from the
classified pricing of milk. Classified
pricing assigns a value to milk
according to how the milk is used.
Regulated handlers who buy milk from
dairy farmers are charged class prices
according to how they use the farmer’s
milk. Dairy farmers are then paid a
weighted average or ‘‘blend’’ price. The
blend price that dairy farmers are paid
for their milk is derived through the
marketwide pooling of all class uses of
milk in a marketing area. Thus each
producer receives an equal share of each
use class of milk and is indifferent as to
the actual Class for which the milk was
used. The Class I price is usually the
highest class price for milk. Historically
the Class I use of milk provides the
additional revenue to a marketing area’s
total classified use value of milk.
The series of Class prices that are
applicable for any given month are not
announced simultaneously. The Class I
price and the Class II skim milk price
are announced prior to the beginning of
the month for which they will be
effective. Class prices for milk in all
other uses are not determined until on
or before the 5th day of the following
month. The Class I price is determined
by adding a differential value to the
higher of either an advanced Class III or
Class IV value. These values are
calculated based on a formula using
National Agricultural Statistics Service
(NASS) survey prices of cheese, butter,
and nonfat dried milk powder for the
first two weeks of the preceding month.
For example, the Class I price for
August is announced in late July and is
based on the higher of the Class III or
IV value computed using NASS
commodity price surveys for the first
two weeks of July.
The Class III and IV prices for the
month are determined and announced
after the end of the month based on the
NASS survey prices for the selected
dairy commodities during the month.
For example, the Class III and IV prices
for August are based on NASS survey
commodity prices during August. A
large increase in the NASS survey price
for the selected dairy commodities from
one month to the next can result in the
Class III or IV price exceeding the Class
I price. This occurrence is commonly
referred to by the dairy industry as a
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
9006
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
‘‘Class price inversion.’’ A producer
price inversion generally refers to when
the Class III or IV price exceeds the
classified use value, or blend price, of
milk for the month. Price inversions
have occurred with increasing
frequency in Federal milk orders since
the current pricing plan was
implemented on January 1, 2000,
despite efforts made during Federal
Order Reform to reduce such
occurrences. Price inversions can create
an incentive for dairy farmers and
manufacturing handlers who voluntarily
participate in the marketwide pooling of
milk to elect not pool their milk on the
order. Class I handlers do not have this
option; their participation in the
marketwide pool is mandatory.
The producer price differential, or
PPD, is the difference between the Class
III price and the weighted average value
of all Classes. In essence, the PPD is the
dairy farmer’s share of the additional/
reduced revenues associated with the
Class I, II and IV milk pooled in the
market. If the value of the Class I, II and
IV milk in the pool is greater than the
Class III value, dairy farmers receive a
positive PPD. However a negative PPD
can occur if the value of the Class III
milk in the pool exceeds the value of the
remaining classes of milk in the pool.
This can occur as a result of the price
inversions discussed above.
The UMW Federal order operates a
marketwide pool. The Order contains
pooling provisions which specify
criteria that, if met, allow dairy farmers
to share in the benefits that arise from
classified pricing through pooling. The
equalization of all class prices among
handlers regulated by an order is
accomplished through a mechanism
known as the producer settlement fund
(PSF). Typically, Class I handlers pay
the difference between the blend price
and their use-value of milk into the PSF.
Manufacturing handlers typically
receive a draw from the PSF, usually the
difference between the Class II, III or IV
price and the blend price. In this way,
all handlers pay the Class value for milk
and all dairy farmer supplies receive at
least the order’s blend price.
When manufacturing class prices of
milk are high enough to result in a usevalue of milk for a handler that is higher
than the blend price, manufacturing
handlers may choose to not pool their
milk receipts. Opting to not pool their
milk receipts allows these handlers to
avoid the obligation of paying into the
PSF. The choice by a manufacturing
handler to not pool their milk receipts
is commonly referred to as ‘‘depooling’’. When the blend price rises
above the manufacturing class usevalues of milk these same handlers
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
again opt to pool their milk receipts.
This is often referred to as ‘‘re-pooling’’.
The ability of manufacturing handlers to
de-pool and re-pool manufacturing milk
is viewed by some market participants
as being inequitable to both producers
and handlers.
The ‘‘De-Pooling’’ Proposals
Proponents are in agreement that milk
marketing orders should contain
provisions that will tend to deter the
practice of de-pooling. Four proposals
intending to deter the de-pooling of
milk were considered in this
proceeding. The proposals offered
different degrees of deterrence against
de-pooling by establishing limits on the
amount of milk that can be re-pooled.
The proponents of these four proposals
are generally of the opinion that depooling erodes equity among producers
and handlers, undermines the orderly
marketing of milk and is detrimental to
the Federal order system.
Two different approaches on how to
best limit de-pooling are represented by
these four proposals. The first approach,
published in the hearing notice as
Proposals 2 and 5, addresses de-pooling
by limiting the volume of milk a handler
can pool in a month to a specified
percentage of what the handler pooled
in the prior month. The second
approach, published in the hearing
notice as Proposals 3 and 4, addresses
de-pooling by establishing what is
commonly referred to as a ‘‘dairy farmer
for other markets’’ provision. These
proposals would require milk of a
producer that was de-pooled to not be
able to be re-pooled by that producer for
a defined time period. All proponents
agreed that while none of the proposals
would completely eliminate de-pooling,
they would likely deter the practice.
Of the four proposals received that
would limit de-pooling, this decision
recommends adoption of Proposal 2,
offered by Mid-West Dairymen’s
Company (Mid-West) on behalf of CassClay Creamery Inc. (Cass-Clay), Dairy
Farmers of America, Inc. (DFA),
Foremost Farms USA Cooperative
(Foremost Farms), Land O’Lakes Inc.
(LOL), Milwaukee Cooperative Milk
Producers (MCMP), Manitowoc Milk
Producers Cooperative (MMPC), Swiss
Valley Farms Company (Swiss Valley),
and Woodstock Progressive Milk
Producers Association (Woodstock).
Hereinafter, this decision will refer to
these proponents as ‘‘Mid-West, et al.’’
Although Foremost Farms was a
proponent of Proposal 2, no testimony
was offered on their behalf. At the
hearing, Plainview Milk Products
Cooperative and Westby Cooperative
Creamery also supported the testimony
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
given on behalf of Mid-West, et al. The
proponents of Proposal 2 are all
cooperatives representing producers
whose milk supplies the milk needs of
the marketing area and is pooled on the
UMW order.
Specifically, adoption of Proposal 2
will limit the volume of milk a handler
could pool in a month to no more than
125 percent of the volume of milk
pooled in the prior month during the
months of April through February, and
to no more than 135 percent of the prior
month’s pooled volume in the month of
March. Milk diverted to nonpool plants
in excess of this limit will not be
pooled, and milk shipped to pool
distributing plants will not be subject to
the 125 or 135 percent limitation
As published in the hearing notice,
Proposal 5, offered by Dean Foods
Company (Dean), addresses de-pooling
in a similar manner as Proposal 2, but
would establish a limit on the total
volume of milk a handler could pool in
a given month to 115 percent of the
volume that was pooled in the prior
month. Dean is a handler who operates
manufacturing plants and distributing
plants in the UMW marketing area.
Producer milk shipped to and
physically received at a pool
distributing plant, and producer milk
that was pooled continuously on
another Federal Order during the
previous six months, would not be
subject to this pooling standard.
Proposal 5 is not recommended for
adoption.
As published in the hearing notice,
Proposals 3 and 4, also offered by Dean,
address de-pooling by establishing
defined time periods during which depooled milk could not be pooled.
Proposal 3 would require an annual
pooling commitment by a handler to the
UMW market. As advanced in Proposal
3, if the milk of a producer is de-pooled
in a month, the milk of a producer could
not re-establish eligibility for pooling on
the order during the following 11
months unless 10 days’ milk production
of a producer was delivered to a pool
distributing plant during the month.
Under Proposal 3, handlers that de-pool
milk have limited options to return milk
to the pool, either shipping 10 days’
milk production of a producer to a pool
distributing plant during the month or
waiting 11 months to regain pooling
eligibility
Proposal 4 is similar to Proposal 3 but
is less restrictive. Under Proposal 4, as
modified at the hearing, if a producer’s
milk is de-pooled in any of the months
of February through June, or during any
of the preceding three months, or during
any of the preceding months of July
through January, the equivalent of at
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
least 10 days’ milk production would
need to be physically received at a pool
distributing plant in order to pool all of
the dairy farmer’s production for the
month. Additionally, if the milk of a
dairy farmer is de-pooled in any of the
months of July through January, or in a
preceding month, at least 10 days’ milk
production of the dairy farmer would
need to be delivered to a pool
distributing plant to have all the milk of
the dairy farmer pooled for the month.
The current Producer milk provision
of the UMW order considers the milk of
a dairy farmer to be producer milk when
it is delivered directly from farms to
pool plant or diverted by a pool plant
or cooperative handler to a nonpool
plant. Milk is not eligible for diversion
to nonpool plants unless at least one
days’ production of such dairy farmer is
received at a pool plant anytime during
the initial qualifying month, often
referred to as ‘‘touching-base’’. To be
eligible to pool all of its milk receipts,
the pooling handler must ship at least
10 percent of its milk receipts to a pool
distributing plant, producer-handler, a
partially regulated distributing plant, or
a pool distributing plant regulated by
another Federal order. A handler’s
diversion of milk to nonpool plants can
only be made to nonpool plants located
in the States of Illinois, Iowa,
Minnesota, Wisconsin, North Dakota,
South Dakota, and the Upper Peninsula
of Michigan, or to a distributing plant
regulated under another Federal order.
Milk that is subject to inclusion in
another marketwide equalization
program operated by a state government
is not considered producer milk. The
order currently does not limit a
handler’s ability to de-pool milk.
The proponents of Proposals 2, 3, 4
and 5 are all of the opinion that the
current pooling standards are
inadequate because they enable
manufacturing handlers to de-pool milk
when advantageous to do so and
immediately re-pool milk in a following
month if advantageous to do so.
According to the proponents, the UMW
blend price is lowered when large
volumes of sometimes higher valued
milk used for manufacturing is depooled and when the large volumes of
de-pooled milk returns to the pool.
Furthermore, the witnesses argued that
de-pooling handlers do not account to
the UMW pool at the order’s classified
prices and therefore face different costs
than their similarly situated pooling
competitors. The proponents insisted
that the pooling standards of the order
need to be amended to ensure producer
and handler equity, even though the
proposals differed on how best to meet
this end.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
A witness appearing on behalf of MidWest, et al., testified in support of
Proposal 2. The witness was of the
opinion that the underlying principles
of the Federal order program are to
supply milk to the fluid market,
equitably share pool proceeds among all
participating producers, and promote
orderly marketing. The witness
explained that the Federal order
program achieves these objectives
through classified pricing, through
which Class I milk generates revenue for
the pool; and marketwide pooling,
which equalizes payments to all
participating producers who serve the
market regardless of how the milk of
any single producer is utilized.
The Mid-West, et al., witness said that
currently milk utilized at manufacturing
plants can be de-pooled and again
pooled in a subsequent month when it
is economically beneficial to the
handler. When choosing to pool or not
to pool, the witness explained, handlers
assess whether participating in the
marketwide pool would require them to
make a payment into or receive a
payment from the PSF. According to the
witness, milk utilized as Class I must
always be pooled regardless of whether
the pooling handler would make a
payment into, or receives a payment
from, the PSF.
The Mid-West, et al., witness testified
that because manufacturing milk can
freely exit and return to the pool,
producers who regularly and
consistently service the UMW fluid
market are not being treated equitably
under the terms of the order. According
to the witness, these producers receive
a lower blend price because the value of
the milk that was de-pooled was not
shared equitably among all the market’s
producers.
The Mid-West, et al., witness
maintained that the ability of
manufacturing handlers to de-pool milk
creates inequities among handlers and
producers. The witness said that when
the PPD is negative, dairy farmers
receive different payments for their milk
depending on if their milk was pooled,
and handlers are not required to account
to the pool at classified prices
depending on their pooling decisions.
Class I handlers who must pool their
milk receipts always have a
disadvantage when the PPD is negative,
explained the witness, because a
manufacturing handler can opt to depool and avoid paying into the PSF.
According to the witness this results in
higher prices that can be paid to the
producers supplying the manufacturing
handler. The witness contrasted that
when the PPD is positive, milk that had
been de-pooled seeks to return to the
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
9007
pool. According to the witness, this also
dilutes the blend price paid to
producers who had been supplying the
Class I handler.
The Mid-West, et al., witness, relying
on Market Administrator statistics,
noted that in May 2004, all producer
milk pooled on the order was subject to
a negative $1.97 per hundredweight
(cwt) PPD. However, the witness
emphasized that a manufacturing
handler who chose to de-pool their milk
supply and did not have to account to
the pool at classified prices had an
imputed PPD of zero. In other words,
the witness explained, milk used in
manufactured products was worth more
than milk used in fluid products.
Relying on additional Market
Administrator statistics, the witness
demonstrated that if 100 percent of
eligible Class III milk had pooled in July
2003 through May 2004, the estimated
PPD would have averaged a negative
$0.098 per cwt rather than the actual
average PPD of negative $0.773 per cwt.
The Midwest, et al., witness
explained how adoption of Proposal 2
would improve both producer and
handler equity. The witness said that
Proposal 2 would only limit the amount
of milk a handler could pool up to 125
or 135 percent of the previous month’s
pooled volume and clarified that any
milk delivered to a distributing plant
would not be subject to the 125 or 135
percent pooling calculation. If Proposal
2 were adopted, the witness claimed, no
current handler would have to change
the physical operations of their plant.
While adoption of this proposal would
not end the practice of de-pooling,
speculated the witness, it would
establish financial consequences for
handlers who might not otherwise
consistently pool their milk receipts.
In explaining why adoption of
Proposal 2 would be reasonable and
appropriate for the UMW order, the
Mid-West, et al., witness said that a 125
percent standard should accommodate
any change in the potential growth of a
handler’s pooled milk volume resulting
from seasonal fluctuations in milk
supply or the addition of new
producers, assuming that the handler
did not de-pool. Additionally, the
witness added that to ensure no handler
would need to change its physical
operations, Proposal 2 allows a 135
percent re-pooling standard in March
because of the fewer calendar days in
February. The witness stressed that the
125 and 135 percent standards allow a
handler to de-pool a portion of its milk
supply and over a period of months,
regain the ability to again pool its entire
supply. The witness added that the
proposal does not restrict the volume of
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
9008
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
milk able to be pooled in August since
this is generally considered the start of
the new marketing year
The Mid-West, et al., witness also
emphasized that establishing a standard
on the basis of the prior month’s pooled
volume has been done in other orders.
The Northeast order has a ‘‘producer for
other markets’’ provision that restricts
the ability to pool the milk of a producer
if the milk of that producer had been
previously de-pooled, noted the
witness. Furthermore, the witness said,
milk orders in the south and
southeastern part of the country had
provisions which limited the sharing of
marketwide returns in the spring
months to only those producers whose
milk served the fluid market during the
fall months.
The Mid-West, et al., witness
predicted that price volatility would
continue in the future and result in
negative PPD’s and the further depooling of milk. The witness was of the
opinion that price volatility and depooling have created emergency
marketing conditions that would
warrant the Department to omit issuing
a recommended decision.
A witness from DFA, appearing on
behalf of Mid-West, et al., testified in
support of Proposal 2. The witness
testified that DFA engages in the
practice of de-pooling when warranted
to earn sufficient revenue to pay their
producer members a competitive milk
price. The DFA witness emphasized that
de-pooling creates disorderly marketing
conditions and supported Proposal 2 as
the best option to deter the practice of
de-pooling. The witness offered
scenarios that demonstrated the
financial incentives available to
handlers who de-pool milk. The witness
asserted that the current pooling
standards of the UMW order where
producers qualify for pooling by
meeting a one-day touch base standard
allow handlers the opportunity to reap
financial rewards from the market by
de-pooling and re-pooling their milk
receipts.
The DFA witness explained that
Proposal 2 was a compromise position
among all the entities of Mid-West, et
al., noting that its adoption would
improve the current disorderly market
conditions arising from the practice of
de-pooling. The witness noted that
many alternatives were considered but
the proponents were of the opinion that
Proposal 2 is a significant improvement
to the order’s pooling provisions while
still allowing handlers to make their
own pooling decisions.
Witnesses from LOL, Swiss Valley,
Cass-Clay, MMPC, and DFA Central
Council, all appearing on behalf of Mid-
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
West, et al., testified in support of
Proposal 2. Many of the witnesses
testified that their respective
organizations engage in the practice of
de-pooling when it is to their advantage
but that they recognize that the practice
has a negative impact on the PPD and
creates disorderly marketing conditions.
Consequently, they are of the opinion
that while a moderate level of depooling should be tolerated, a set of
standards should be established to deter
de-pooling in order to maintain orderly
marketing conditions.
The Mid-West, et al., witnesses
identified above expressed support for
Proposal 2 as an acceptable and
moderate approach to limiting the
practice of de-pooling. The proposal
would allow flexibility in making
pooling decisions, explained the
witnesses, but would also establish
significant consequences for those who
opt to de-pool large volumes of their
producer milk supply. In this regard, the
witnesses said that Proposal 2 would
result in ensuring more equity among
handlers and producers during times of
price inversions.
A DFA dairy farmer member, whose
milk is pooled on the UMW order,
testified in support of Proposal 2. The
witness was of the opinion that if a
dairy farmer wants to participate in the
UMW marketwide pool and share in the
revenue generated from the market, they
should be prepared to service the
market every month. When handlers
engage in the practice of de-pooling
their milk receipts, the witness said, the
results are severe price fluctuations and
larger negative PPDs that negatively
impact the price paid to pooled
producers. The witness was of the
opinion that the adoption of Proposal 2
would result in more stable pooled milk
volumes and consequently would lessen
the severe and volatile price changes
that producers have experienced.
A dairy farmer appearing on behalf of
MCMP, whose milk is pooled on the
UMW order, testified in support of
Proposal 2. The witness said that their
farm income was negatively impacted
during May 2004 as a result of the
negative $1.97 per cwt PPD. The witness
added that neighboring farms that
shipped milk to other handlers reported
receiving a higher price for their milk.
The opinion of the witness was that the
practice of de-pooling has led to nonuniform prices received by farmers and
that adoption of Proposal 2 would
restore price equity among producers.
A witness appearing on behalf of
Dean testified in opposition to Proposal
2. The witness said that the pooling
standards of Proposal 2 are too liberal
and that unlimited pooling in the month
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
of August could allow handlers to again
take advantage of the pooling system.
A witness appearing on behalf of
Northwest Dairy Association (NDA)
testified in opposition to Proposal 2.
NDA is a dairy cooperative that markets
7 billion pounds of milk annually with
members in the States of Washington,
Oregon, Idaho, and Northern California.
The witness explained that NDA
engages in the practice of de-pooling in
other Federal orders as a way to recover
costs in their manufacturing of butter
and cheese because the Class III and IV
make allowances that do not adequately
reflect such costs. The NDA witness was
of the opinion that the practice of depooling should be addressed at a
national hearing that would also
consider other issues such as the make
allowances used in the Class III and IV
price formulas.
A witness appearing on behalf of
Dean testified in support of Proposals 3,
4, and 5. The witness asserted that the
intent of the Federal order system is to
ensure a sufficient supply of milk for
fluid use and provide for uniform
payments to producers who stand ready,
willing, and able to serve the fluid
market. While some entities are of the
opinion that the Federal order system
should ensure a sufficient milk supply
to all plants, the Dean witness was of
the opinion that the Federal order
system addresses only the need for
ensuring a milk supply to distributing
plants. The witness elaborated on this
opinion by citing examples of order
provisions that stress providing for a
regular supply of milk to distributing
plants as a priority of the Federal milk
order program.
The Dean witness was of the opinion
that for the Federal milk order system to
ensure orderly marketing, orders need to
provide adequate economic incentives
that will attract milk to fluid plants and
also need to properly define regulations
to determine the milk of those
producers who can participate in the
marketwide pool. The witness argued
that a major flaw in the current
regulations is that they allow handlers
to choose when to participate in the
pool. In this regard, the witness said, the
order lacks the economic incentive for
pool participation by its lack of an
economic disincentive to the practice of
de-pooling.
The Dean witness testified that
Proposals 3, 4, and 5 are designed to
establish proper economic incentives for
supplying the fluid market and maintain
equity among handlers and producers.
While each proposal offered a slightly
different solution to the problem, the
witness said Dean Foods supports their
adoption in the following order or
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
preference: Proposal 3, Proposal 4, and
then Proposal 5.
A second witness appearing on behalf
of Dean testified in support of Proposals
3, 4, and 5. The witness argued that
when handlers engage in the practice of
de-pooling it creates a burden on the
producers who consistently serve the
Class I needs of the market. According
to the witness, when the PPD is
negative, there is an incentive for
handlers to de-pool Class III and Class
IV milk. When a handler opts to depool, it decreases the amount of pooled
milk and makes the PPD more negative
than it would have been had all milk
been pooled, the witness said. When the
PPD is positive, milk previously depooled seeks to be re-pooled which
increases the volume of pooled milk
valued at lower classified prices and
lowers the blend price paid to all
producers, the witness asserted. The
major ‘‘losers’’ in this process,
concluded the witness, are the
producers whose milk is continuously
pooled regardless of the PPD.
The second Dean witness said that
Proposal 3 was designed to increase the
availability of milk for fluid use and
ensure that pool proceeds are only
shared among producers who
consistently service the fluid market.
The witness said that if Proposal 3 is
adopted, de-pooled milk could again
become pooled as long as the producer
delivered ten-day’s milk production to a
pool distributing plant for twelve
consecutive months. Once that standard
was met, the witness added, the
producer’s milk could then be pooled
under the more flexible provisions of
the UMW order.
The Dean witness asserted that there
are three benefits to adoption of
Proposal 3: (1) When the PPD is
negative, more Class III milk would stay
in the pool resulting in a less negative
PPD; (2) Some Class III de-pooled milk
would never be re-pooled which would
result in a more positive PPD; and (3)
Class III de-pooled milk would have to
demonstrate regular and significant
deliveries to distributing plants in order
to be re-pooled.
In explaining Proposal 4 as an
alternative to Proposal 3, the second
Dean witness indicated that the
difference in the two proposals is the
number of months that the ten-day
touch base provision would be
applicable before de-pooled milk could
again be pooled under normal
circumstances. The witness was of the
opinion that Proposal 4 would
discourage some de-pooling, however,
the harm caused by the practice of depooling would be better prevented by
the adoption of Proposal 3.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
The Dean witness also discussed
Proposal 5 as a less desirable alternative
to Proposals 3 and 4. According to the
witness, Proposal 5 would limit the
amount of milk that can be pooled to
115 percent of the handler’s previous
month’s pooled milk volume. The
witness explained that the greater the
volume of de-pooled milk, the more
time needed under Proposal 5 for a
handler to re-pool all its milk receipts.
This, the witness said, ensures that the
entities that benefit the most from the
practice of de-pooling would not receive
an immediate benefit that would
otherwise occur when re-pooling.
A third witness appearing on behalf of
Dean testified in support of Proposal 3.
The witness said that the current liberal
pooling standards of the UMW order are
one source of disorderly marketing and
are preventing all producers from
sharing equally in pool proceeds. The
witness asserted that the Federal milk
order system was designed so that
through marketwide pooling all
producers would share equally in pool
proceeds, and that through classified
pricing milk would move to the
market’s highest-valued use.
Relying on Market Administrator
statistics for January 2000 through June
2004, the witness asserted that the
volume of pooled Class III milk varied
from 1.5 billion pounds in January 2004
to 11 million pounds in April 2004.
Furthermore, the witness said, the blend
price in April 2004 would have been
$2.97 higher if all Class III milk had
been pooled. The witness was of the
opinion that these large swings in the
volume of pooled milk results in the
disorderly marketing condition of
inequitable sharing of pool proceeds
among producers.
A witness appearing on behalf of
Oberweis Dairy testified in support of
Proposals 2 and 3. Oberweis Dairy
operates a distributing plant with
approximately 40 dairy farmer suppliers
and 32 ice cream stores in the Chicago
and St. Louis area markets. The witness
was of the opinion that it is inequitable
to producers and Class I handlers when
manufacturing handlers engage in the
practice of de-pooling. The witness was
of the opinion that either all handlers
should be able to engage in the practice
of de-pooling or de-pooling should be
prohibited. While no proposal at the
hearing proposed such a restriction, the
witness was of the opinion that Proposal
3 would be the best option to restore
equity among producers. Nevertheless,
the witness said that Oberweis would
support the adoption of Proposal 2 if the
Department finds it to be more
appropriate.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
9009
A witness appearing on behalf of the
Wisconsin Farmers Union, Minnesota
Farmers Union, and the North Dakota
Farmers Union testified about the
negative effects of de-pooling on dairy
producers. These organizations
represent farmers of various agricultural
products in their respective States. The
witness asserted that when a
cooperative engages in the practice of
de-pooling, dairy farmers are negatively
impacted because the revenue a
cooperative gains from de-pooling is not
paid to producers by the cooperatives.
The witness insisted that the practice of
de-pooling should be curbed so that
producers are adequately paid for the
total value of their milk.
A witness appearing on behalf of
Galloway Company (Galloway) testified
in support of all proposals that would
limit the practice of de-pooling.
Galloway owns and operates a dairy
manufacturing plant in the UMW
marketing area. The witness was of the
opinion that large negative PPD’s are
due, in part, to de-pooling and that has
a negative impact on the income of
Galloway. The witness was of the
opinion that changes to order provisions
to limit the ability to re-pool are
necessary but had no opinion as to
which proposal would be the best
option.
A post-hearing brief submitted by
Dean reiterated their opinion that the
pooling standards of the order need to
be amended to correct the disorderly
marketing conditions arising from the
practice of de-pooling. The brief argued
that the practice of de-pooling is
disorderly because a handler who depools milk avoids accounting to the
pool at classified prices and is not
required to pay its suppliers the
minimum blend price. However,
asserted Dean, a pooled handler not
only accounts to the pool at classified
prices and pays its suppliers the
minimum blend price, the handler also
finds it necessary to pay large premiums
to keep its suppliers.
According to the Dean brief, negative
PPD’s and the resulting practice of depooling are not a national issue, noting
that de-pooling typically occurs in
markets with low Class I utilization
such as the UMW. The Dean brief
predicted that the practice of de-pooling
would occur in the future and therefore
concluded that the disorderly marketing
conditions arising from the practice of
de-pooling warrant emergency action
from the Department by omitting a
recommended decision.
A post hearing brief submitted on
behalf of Lamers Dairy, Inc. (Lamers)
asserted that the ability of some
handlers to engage in the practice of de-
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
9010
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
pooling when it is economically
advantageous is a disorderly marketing
condition. Furthermore, the brief
expressed the opinion that de-pooling
causes inequitable treatment among
handlers because pooling handlers must
account to the PSF at minimum
classified prices while handlers who depool their milk receipts do not. The
Lamers brief supported adoption of
Proposal 3 as the most appropriate
solution to limit the practice of depooling.
A witness appearing on behalf of MidWest, et al., testified in opposition to
Proposal 3. According to the witness,
requiring a producer whose milk was
de-pooled to deliver 10-day’s milk
production to a pool distributing plant
is a standard that would be extremely
difficult to meet. The witness stressed
that finding access to a pool distributing
plant for 10-day’s production would not
only be extremely difficult, it would
also be costly. The Mid-West, et al.,
brief also contended that the proposals
offered by Dean would require physical
changes in plant operations that are not
necessary to address the practice of depooling in the UMW market.
The Mid-West, et al., brief disagreed
with others who were of the opinion
that the de-pooling issue should be
addressed at a national hearing. The
brief explained that historical Federal
milk order policy is that the pooling
provisions of orders be reflective of each
order’s individual marketing conditions.
Therefore, the brief concluded, it is
appropriate to address the practice of
de-pooling on an individual order basis.
A witness appearing on behalf of
Associated Milk Producers, Inc. (AMPI)
testified in opposition to all proposals
intended to limit the practice of depooling as specified in Proposals 2, 3, 4,
and 5. The witness’ testimony was given
on behalf of Alto Dairy Cooperative,
Bongards’ Creameries, Ellsworth
Cooperative Creamery, Family Dairies
USA, First District Association, Davisco
Foods, Valley Queen Cheese Company
and Wisconsin Cheesemakers
Association (WCA). The members
consist of cooperative associations and
handlers who market or purchase milk
in the UMW marketing area.
Hereinafter, this coalition of members
will be referred to collectively as
‘‘AMPI, et al.’’
The AMPI, et al., witness testified that
the option to engage in the practice of
de-pooling in response to price
inversions has been a longstanding part
of the Federal milk order system. The
witness testified that as a result of
timing differences in announcing
classified prices, a lag between changes
in the market value of milk used in
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
manufacturing and corresponding
changes in the Federal order Class I
price sometimes results in price
inversions. The witness explained that
the occasional price inversion is caused
by the announcement of the Class I
price approximately two weeks prior to
the month and the announcement of the
price for milk used in Class II, III, and
IV products occurring after the close of
the month—a difference of six weeks.
The witness drew attention to April
2004 where the value of Class III milk
increased $6.02 per cwt during the sixweek lag. This resulted in a blend price
that was substantially less than the
estimated Class III price, resulting in a
large amount of de-pooled Class III milk
because, the witness said, there was no
incentive for manufacturing handlers to
pool all of their milk receipts.
The AMPI, et al., witness asserted that
the argument that de-pooled milk does
not serve, nor is available to serve, the
fluid market is false. According to the
witness, milk that is de-pooled is
available to the Class I market during
the month it is marketed and a decision
to de-pool the milk is made after the end
of the month when the Class II, III and
IV prices are known. Additionally, the
witness asserted that fluid milk plants
always receive a continuous supply of
fluid milk because of their contractual
supply agreements.
The AMPI, et al., witness
characterized the proposals under
consideration to address the practice of
de-pooling as designed to penalize
handlers who engage in de-pooling their
Class III milk. AMPI, et al., the witness
stated, is strongly opposed to this
change in pooling philosophy. The
witness was of the opinion that the
Federal order system should continue to
provide for the marketwide sharing of
money derived from sales of Class I milk
since it is Class I sales that historically
generate additional revenue to
producers. However, the witness said,
the order should not force handlers to
share money generated from
manufactured milk products to offset a
low Class I price.
The AMPI, et al., witness was of the
opinion that the practice of de-pooling
is a national issue that should be
addressed in a national hearing. The
witness believed that a better solution to
the practice of de-pooling would be to
eliminate the advanced pricing of Class
I milk and instead announce all Class
prices after the end of the month.
The AMPI, et al., witness also testified
that emergency marketing conditions do
not exist to warrant the omission of a
recommended decision by the
Department. The witness stressed that
price inversions and the practice of de-
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
pooling have occurred in the Federal
order system for decades and any major
change in Department policy regarding
this practice should be addressed in a
recommended decision where interested
parties can file comments and
exceptions.
A post-hearing brief submitted on
behalf of AMPI, et al., reiterated their
opposition to all of the proposals that
seek to deter de-pooling. The brief
argued that the AMAA intended for the
government to only require the sharing
of the revenues generated from fluid
sales. According to the brief, requiring
manufactured milk to remain pooled
oversteps the authority of the AMAA.
The brief also expressed the opinion
that Proposals 3, 4, and 5 are designed
to limit a producer’s access to the
market and should therefore be denied.
Furthermore, the brief stressed that
Proposals 3 through 5 would unfairly
increase costs of some UMW handlers
because of the increased transportation
and capital investment that would be
needed to comply with the proposed
amendments.
A witness appearing on behalf of
WCA, testified in opposition to all
proposals intended to limit the practice
of de-pooling as specified in Proposals
2, 3, 4, and 5. The witness testified that
WCA represents dairy manufacturers
and marketers with 32 of its members
operating 42 pooled dairy facilities on
the UMW order. According to the
witness, 30 of the 42 pooled dairy
facilities are small businesses and if the
proposals to limit the practice of depooling were adopted, these small
businesses would face new and
significant costs to comply with the
proposed new standards without benefit
to their dairy farmer suppliers.
The WCA witness expressed concern
that Proposal 2 addressed the practice of
de-pooling without regard to the cause
of negative PPD’s, specifically the
inversion of classified prices. The
witness also said that Proposals 2, 3, 4
and 5 would put an additional
administrative burden on handlers by
requiring them to designate which
producers would remain pooled or depooled. The witness asserted that access
to distributing plants in the UMW
market is very limited and it would be
hard for a de-pooled producer to reassociate with a distributing plant in
order to be eligible to again pool their
milk on the order.
The WCA witness was of the opinion
that Proposals 3 and 4 also would add
additional transportation costs,
administrative costs, and the potential
need for additional silo capacity to
accommodate the increased volume of
milk that would be needed to meet the
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
10-day production delivery standard at
a pool distributing plant. The witness
explained that many WCA members do
not have the capacity to accommodate
meeting a 10-day production delivery
standard for each month. The witness
was also of the opinion that existing
supply contracts provide ample milk
supplies for the Class I market and
concluded that additional deliveries to
pool plants are not needed to assure an
adequate supply to Class I facilities.
A witness appearing on behalf of the
National Family Farm Coalition, an
organization representing family farms
located in 32 states including those
states comprising the UMW marketing
area, testified in opposition to all
proposals at the hearing. The witness
was of the opinion that the entire
Federal order system was in need of a
complete reform. The witness asserted
that the proponents of the proposals
being heard were entities whose past
actions have lowered prices received by
family farmers.
A post-hearing brief submitted on
behalf of Alto Dairy (Alto), a cooperative
with 580 dairy farmer members in
Wisconsin and Michigan, reiterated
their opposition to all proposals seeking
to limit the practice of de-pooling. The
brief stressed that a decision to de-pool
is made separately from the decision to
adequately supply the Class I needs of
the market.
An Extension Dairy Marketing
Specialist at the University of
Wisconsin testified on the issues
surrounding the practice of de-pooling
but did not support or oppose any
specific proposal. The witness referred
to and explained a research paper which
identified and explained problems
arising in the UMW marketing area by
pooling distant milk, the practice of depooling, and the resulting economic
impacts to producers. The witness said
that if manufacturing prices for milk
rapidly increase during the month there
will be a negative PPD but as prices
begin to decline, the PPD will again
become positive over time. The witness
also explained that a negative PPD does
not mean that producers lost money.
Rather, the witness clarified, the PPD is
a calculation of the difference between
the Class III price and the blend price
that producers receive. However,
concluded the witness, the ability to
engage in the practice of de-pooling
does result in volatile PPD’s and gives
rise to inequities among producers and
handlers.
All Federal milk marketing orders
require the pooling of milk received at
pool distributing plants—which is
predominantly Class I milk—and all
pooled producers and handlers on an
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
order share in the additional revenue
arising from higher valued Class I sales.
Manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives of Class II, III and IV uses
of milk who meet the pooling and
performance standards make all of their
milk receipts eligible to be pooled and
usually find it advantageous.
Manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives who supply a portion of
their total milk receipts to Class I
distributing plants receive the difference
between their use-value of milk and the
order’s blend price. Federal milk orders,
including the UMW order, establish
limits on the volume of milk eligible to
be pooled that is not used for fluid uses
primarily through diversion limit
standards. However, manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives are not
required, as are Class I handlers, to pool
all their eligible milk receipts.
According to the record,
manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives have opted to not pool
their milk receipts when the
manufacturing class prices of milk are
higher than the order’s blend price—
commonly referred to as being
‘‘inverted.’’ During such months,
manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives have elected to not pool all
of their eligible milk receipts because
doing so would require them to pay into
the PSF of the order, the mechanism
through which handler and producer
prices are equalized. When prices are
not inverted, handlers would pool all of
their eligible receipts and receive a
payment or draw from the PSF. In
receiving a draw from the PSF, such
handlers will have sufficient money to
pay at least the order’s blend price to
their supplying dairy farmers.
When manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives opt to not pool all of their
eligible milk receipts in a month, they
are essentially avoiding a payment to
the PSF. This, in turn, enables them to
avoid the marketwide sharing of the
additional value of milk that accrues in
the higher-valued uses of milk other
than Class I. When the Class I price
again becomes the highest valued use of
milk, or when other class-price
relationships become favorable, the
record reveals that these same handlers
opt to again pool their eligible milk
receipts and draw money from the PSF.
It is the ability of manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives opting to not
pool milk and thereby avoid the
marketwide sharing of the revenue
accruing from non-Class I milk sales
that is viewed by proponents as giving
rise to disorderly marketing conditions.
According to proponents, producers and
handlers who cannot escape being
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
9011
pooled and priced under the order are
not assured of equitable prices.
The record reveals that since the
implementation of Federal milk
marketing order reform in January 2000,
and especially in more recent years,
large and rapid increases in
manufactured product prices during
certain months have provided the
economic incentives for manufacturing
handlers to opt not to pool eligible milk
on the UMW order. For example, during
the three-month period of February to
April 2004, the Class III price increased
over 65 percent from $11.89 per cwt to
$19.66 per cwt. During the same time
period, total producer milk pooled on
the UMW order decreased by over 60
percent from 1.94 billion pounds to 608
million pounds. When milk volumes of
this magnitude are not pooled the
impacts on producer blend prices are
significant. Producers who incur the
additional costs of consistently
servicing the Class I needs of the market
receive a lower return than would
otherwise have been received if they did
not continue to service the Class I
market. Prices received by dairy farmers
who supplied the other milk needs of
the market are not known. However, it
is reasonable to conclude that prices
received by dairy farmers were not
equitable or uniform.
The record reveals that ‘‘inverted’’
prices of milk are generally the result of
the timing of Class price
announcements. Despite changes made
as part of Federal milk order reform to
shorten the time period of setting and
announcing Class I milk prices and
basing the Class I price on the higher of
the Class III or Class IV price to avoid
price inversions, large month-to-month
price increases in Class III and Class IV
product prices sometimes trumped the
intent of better assuring that the Class I
price for the month would be the
highest-valued use of milk. In all orders,
the Class I price (and the Class II skim
price) is announced prior to or in
advance of the month for which it will
apply. The Class I price is calculated by
using the National Agricultural
Statistics Service (NASS) surveyed
cheese, butter, nonfat dry milk and dry
whey prices for the two most current
weeks prior to the 24th day of the
preceding month and then adding a
differential value to the higher of either
the advanced Class III or Class IV price.
Historically, the advance pricing of
Class I milk has been used in all Federal
orders because Class I handlers cannot
avoid regulation and are required to
pool all of their Class I milk receipts,
they should know their product costs in
advance of notifying their customers of
price changes. However, milk receipts
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
9012
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
for Class III and IV uses are not required
to be pooled thus, Class III and IV
product prices (and the Class II butterfat
value) are not announced in advance.
These prices are announced on or before
the 5th of the following month. Of
importance here is that manufacturing
plant operators and cooperatives have
the benefit of knowing all the classified
prices of milk before making a decision
to pool or not pool eligible receipts.
The record reveals that the decision of
manufacturing handlers or cooperatives
to pool or not pool milk is made on a
month-to-month basis and is generally
independent of past pooling decisions.
Manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives that elected to not pool
their milk receipts did so to avoid
making payments to the PSF and they
anticipated that all other manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives would do the
same. However, the record indicates
that normally pooled manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives met the
pooling standards of the order to ensure
that the Class I market was adequately
supplied and that they established
eligibility to pool their physical
receipts, including diversions to
nonpool plants. Opponents to proposals
to deter de-pooling are of the view that
meeting the pooling standards of the
order and deciding how much milk to
pool are unrelated events. Proponents
took the view that participation in the
marketwide pool should be based on a
long-term commitment to supply the
market because in the long-term it is the
sales of higher priced Class I milk that
adds additional revenue to the pool.
The producer price differential, or
PPD, is the difference between the Class
III price and the weighted average value
of all Class I, II and IV milk pooled. In
essence, the PPD is the residual revenue
remaining after all butterfat, protein and
other solids values are paid to
producers. If the pooled value of Class
I, II and IV milk is greater than the Class
III value, dairy farmers receive a
positive PPD. While the PPD is usually
positive, a negative PPD can occur when
class prices rise rapidly during the sixweek period between the time the Class
I price is announced and the time the
Class II butterfat and III and IV milk
prices are announced. When
manufacturing prices fall, this same lag
in the announcement of class prices
yields a positive PPD.
As revealed by the record, when
manufacturing plants and cooperatives
opted to not pool milk because of
inverted price relationships, PPD’s were
much more negative. When this milk is
not pooled, a larger percentage of the
milk remaining pooled will be ‘‘lower’’
priced Class I milk. When
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
manufacturing milk is not pooled the
weighted average value of milk
decreases relative to the Class II, III or
IV value making the PPD more negative.
For example, record evidence
demonstrated that in April 2004, a
month when a sizeable volume of milk
was not pooled, the PPD was a negative
$4.11 per cwt. If all eligible milk had
been pooled, the PPD would have been
$2.97 per cwt higher or a negative $1.14
per cwt.
The record reveals that when
manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives opt to not pool milk,
unequal pay prices may result to
similarly located dairy farmers. For
example, Dean noted that when a
cooperative delivers a high percentage
of their milk receipts to a distributing
plant, it lessens their ability to not pool
milk, making them less competitive in
a marketplace relative to other
producers and handlers. Other evidence
in the record supports conclusions
identical to Dean that when a dairy
farmer or cooperative is able to receive
increased returns from shipping milk to
a manufacturing handler during times of
price inversions, other dairy farmers or
cooperatives who may have shipped
more milk to a pool distributing plant
are competitively disadvantaged.
The record of this proceeding reveals
that the ability of manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives to not pool
all of their eligible milk receipts gives
rise to disorderly marketing conditions
and warrants the establishment of
additional pooling standards to
safeguard marketwide pooling. Current
pooling provisions do not require or
prohibit handlers and cooperatives from
pooling all eligible milk receipts.
However, the record reveals that when
handlers and cooperatives opt to not
pool milk inequities arise among
producers and handlers that are
contrary to the intent of the Federal
milk marketing order program—
maintaining orderly marketing
conditions.
The record contains extensive
testimony regarding the effects on the
milk order program resulting from
advance pricing and the priority the
milk order program has placed on the
Class I price being the highest valued
use of milk. It remains true that the
Class I use of milk is still the highest
valued use of milk notwithstanding
those occasional months when milk
used in usually lower-valued classes
may be higher. This has been
demonstrated by an analysis of the
effective Class I differential values—the
difference in the Class I price at the base
zone of Cook County, Illinois, and the
higher of the Class III or Class IV price—
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
for the 65 month period of January 2000
through May 2005 performed by
USDA.1 These computations reveal that
the effective monthly Class I differential
averaged $1.76 per cwt. Accordingly, it
can only be concluded that in the
longer-term Class I sales continue to be
the source of additional revenue
accruing to the pool even when, in some
months, the effective differential is
negative.
Price inversions occur when the
wholesale price for manufactured
products rises rapidly indicating a
tightening of milk supplies to produce
those products. It is for this reason that
the Department chose the higher of the
Class III or Class IV prices as the mover
of the Class I price. Distributing plants
must have a price high enough to attract
milk away from manufacturing uses to
meet Class I demands. As revealed by
the record, this method has not been
sufficient to provide the appropriate
price signals to assure an adequate
supply of milk for the Class I market.
Accordingly, additional measures are
needed as a means of assuring that milk
remains pooled and thus available to the
Class I market. Adoption of Proposal 2
is a reasonable measure to meet the
objectives of orderly marketing.
This decision does find that
disorderly marketing conditions are
present when producers do not receive
uniform prices. Handlers and
cooperatives opting to not pool milk do
not account to the pool at the classified
use-value of those milk receipts. They
do not share the higher classified usevalue of their milk receipts with all
other producers who are pooled on the
order, primarily the producers who are
pooled on the order are incurring the
additional costs of servicing the Class I
needs of the market. This is not a
desired or reasonable outcome
especially when the same handlers and
cooperatives will again pool all of their
eligible receipts when class-price
relationships change in a subsequent
month. These inequities borne by the
market’s producers are contrary to the
intent of the Federal order program’s
reliance on marketwide pooling—
ensuring that all producers supplying
the market are paid uniform prices for
their milk regardless of how the milk of
any single producer is used.
It is reasonable that the order contain
pooling provisions intended to deter the
disorderly conditions that arise when
de-pooling occurs. Such provisions
maintain and enhance orderly
1 Official notice is taken of data and information
published in Market Administrator Bulletins as
posted on individual Market Administrator web
sites.
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
marketing. Accordingly, this decision
finds it reasonable to recommend
adoption of provisions that would limit
the volume of milk a handler or
cooperative may pool during the months
of April through February to 125
percent of the total volume pooled by
the handler or cooperative in the prior
month and to 135 percent of the prior
month’s pooled volume during the
month of March. Adoption of this
standard will not prevent manufacturing
handlers or cooperatives from electing
to not pool milk. However, it should
serve to maintain and enhance orderly
marketing by encouraging participation
in the marketwide pooling of all
classified uses of milk.
Consideration was given on whether
de-pooling should be considered at a
national hearing with other, broader
national issues of milk marketing.
However, each marketing area has
unique marketing conditions and
characteristics which have area-specific
pooling provisions to address those
specific conditions. Because of this,
pooling issues are considered unique to
each order. This decision finds that it
would be unreasonable to address
pooling issues, including de-pooling on
a national basis.
Some manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives argue that their milk did
perform in meeting the Class I needs
during the month and this occurred
before making their pooling decisions.
They argue that the Class I market is
therefore not harmed and that the
intents and goals of the order program
are satisfied. With respect to this
proceeding and in response to these
arguments, this decision finds that the
practice of de-pooling undermines the
intent of the Federal order program to
assure producers uniform prices across
all uses of milk normally associated
with the market as a critical indicator of
orderly marketing conditions. Similarly,
handlers and cooperatives that de-pool
purposefully do so to gain a momentary
financial benefit (by avoiding making
payments to the PSF) which would
otherwise be equitably shared among all
market participants. While the order’s
performance standards tend to assure
that distributing plants are adequately
supplied with fresh, fluid milk, the
goals of marketwide pooling are
undermined by the practice of depooling. Producers and handlers who
regularly and consistently serve the
Class I needs of the market will not
equitably share in the additional value
arising momentarily from non-fluid uses
of milk. These same producers and
handlers will, in turn, be required to
share the additional revenue arising
from higher-valued Class I sales in a
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
subsequent month when class-price
relationships change.
The four proposals considered in this
proceeding to deter the practice of depooling in the UMW order have
differences. They all seek to address the
market disorder arising from the
practice of de-pooling. However, this
decision does not find adoption of the
two ‘‘dairy farmer for other market’’
proposals—Proposals 3 and 4—
reasonable because they would make it
needlessly difficult for milk to be repooled and because their adoption may
disrupt prevailing marketing channels
or cause the inefficient movement of
milk. Likewise, Proposal 5, to restrict
pooling in a month to 115 percent of the
prior month’s volume pooled by the
handler, is not recommended for
adoption. Adoption of this proposal
would disrupt current marketing
conditions beyond what the record
justifies. Therefore, this decision
recommends adoption of Proposal 2 to
limit the pooling of milk by a handler
during the months of April through
February to 125 percent of the total milk
receipts the handler pooled in the prior
month and to 135 percent of the prior
month’s pooled volume during the
month of March because it provides the
most reasonable measure to deter the
practice of de-pooling.
Consideration was given to omitting a
recommended decision on the issue to
de-pooling. The record does not support
a conclusion that adoption of measures
to deter de-pooling warrant emergency
action. The recommended adoption of
provisions to limit the volume of milk
that can be pooled during the month on
the basis of what was pooled in the
preceding month warrant public
comments before a final decision is
issued.
B. Producer Definition
A proposal published in the hearing
notice as Proposal 6, seeking to specify
the length of time a dairy farmer may
lose Grade A status before losing
producer status on the order, is not
recommended for adoption. Proposal 6,
offered by Dean, would amend the
Producer definition by explicitly stating
that a dairy farmer may lose Grade A
status for up to 21 calendar days per
year before needing to requalify as a
producer on the order. The UMW order
currently does not specify the specific
length of time a dairy farmer may lose
Grade A status before needing to
requalify as a producer on the order.
Currently, a dairy farmer must deliver
one day’s milk production to a pool
plant during the first month a producer
is to be pooled in order to have their
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
9013
milk pooled and priced under the terms
of the order.
A witness appearing on behalf of
Dean testified in support of Proposal 6.
The witness said the UMW order
currently does not specify how long a
dairy farmer who temporarily loses their
Grade A status can retain producer
status before they must requalify as a
producer on the order. Proposal 6, the
witness stated, sets a reasonable limit to
the number of days a producer can lose
Grade A status within a calendar year.
A witness appearing on behalf of MidWest, et al., testified in opposition to
Proposal 6. The witness said that many
situations could arise where a producer
is unable to regain Grade A status in less
than 21 days due to damages resulting
from situations beyond their control.
The current order language provides for
waivers in pooling standards for pool
plants due to such ‘‘acts of God’’ and,
in the witness’ opinion, is adequately
provided for in the Producer definition
of the current order language.
The Producer definition of the UMW
order does not define the length of time
a producer may lose Grade A status
before needing to requalify for producer
status on the order. The issue of
qualifying for producer status is
important since it determines which
producers and which producer milk is
entitled to share in the revenues arising
from the marketwide pooling of milk on
the UMW order.
The definition of ‘‘temporary’’ used
by the Market Administrator has
accommodated the Upper Midwest
market by giving producers a reasonable
amount of time to regain Grade A status
without burdening the market with
excessive touch-base shipments or
recordkeeping requirements. Limiting
the time period a producer can lose
Grade A status would require handlers
and the Market Administrator to track
the producer’s loss of Grade A status
throughout the year to determine when
the 21 day limit is reached.
This decision finds that the additional
touch-base shipments that would be
required for a dairy farmer to requalify
for producer status on the order would
cause uneconomic shipments of milk.
Additionally, the increased
recordkeeping requirements would
burden handlers without contributing to
the goals and application of the
proposed amendments to the pooling
standards contained in this decision.
Accordingly, Proposal 6 is not
recommended for adoption.
2. Administrative Assessment Rate
A proposal, published in the hearing
notice as Proposal 7, seeking to increase
the maximum assessment rate of the
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
9014
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
UMW order, should be adopted.
Specifically, the maximum
administrative assessment rate should
be increased from the current rate of 5
cents per cwt to 8 cents per cwt. At the
time of the hearing, the administrative
assessment rate of 5 cents per cwt
applied to all milk pooled on the order
and was the maximum assessment rate
that could be charged. Adoption of this
proposal will not increase the
administrative assessment above the
current rate but it will give the market
administrator the ability to increase the
assessment up to a maximum 8 cents
per cwt, if necessary.2
According to the Market
Administrator, Proposal 7 was offered
because there is not sufficient milk
volume being consistently pooled on the
UMW order to generate adequate
funding for the proper administration of
the order. Administration of the UMW
order generates substantial costs for the
many services provided to UMW
marketing area participants including
pooling, auditing, gathering market
information, and providing market
services such as laboratory testing,
explained the witness. The witness
noted that there are also fixed expenses
such as salaries and office leases and
that the order must maintain a specified
minimum level of operating reserves.
The Market Administrator stated that
from 2000 to 2002, the amount of
producer milk on the UMW order
ranged from 1.7 to 1.95 billion pounds
per month. According to the witness,
this volume of pooled milk generated
sufficient funds for the administration
of the order for the 4-cent per cwt
assessment rate being assessed on
pooled milk during that time. However,
the witness said, from July through
November 2003 almost 6.2 billion
pounds of producer milk was de-pooled
which resulted in the loss of nearly $2.5
million in potential revenue for the
administration of the order. According
to the Market Administrator, this loss of
revenue caused the assessment rate to
be increased from 4 cents to 5 cents per
cwt. The Market Administrator stressed
that substantial de-pooling occurred
again from March through May 2004
when nearly 4.7 billion pounds of
producer milk was de-pooled.
The Market Administrator
emphasized that the UMW order still
services the de-pooled milk because
handlers make decisions to de-pool
2 Official notice is taken of a letter from the UMW
Market Administrator to UMW handlers,
cooperatives and interested persons, dated
September 28, 2005, that decreases the
administrative assessment from 5 cents to 4 cents
per cwt, effective with milk produced on or after
September 1, 2005.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
their milk receipts after the end of the
month after already utilizing many of
the UMW order services. According to
the Market Administrator, the UMW
order must sometimes service an
approximately 2 billion pound market
per month while only collecting an
assessment on 600 to 700 million
pounds of milk. At the current
assessment rate of 5 cents per cwt, noted
the Market Administrator, the order
needs approximately 1.5 billion pounds
of pooled producer milk per month to
operate and provide the services
expected by market participants.
The Market Administrator said that
actions to reduce operating costs have
taken place but an increase in the
maximum assessment rate is needed to
ensure the proper administration of the
order and to maintain necessary
operating reserves. The Market
Administrator explained that increasing
the maximum administrative
assessment rate to 8 cents per cwt
would not necessarily be the actual rate
that would be charged to pooling
handlers. The Market Administrator
stressed that the proposed 8-cent
assessment rate is a maximum level, and
the actual assessment rate charged
would only be as high as needed to
operate the order.
The Mid-West, et al., brief expressed
support of the Proposal 7 but
emphasized that the assessment rate
should be viewed as a maximum. The
brief speculated that if Proposal 2 is
adopted, the volume of milk pooled
consistently will stabilize making it
unnecessary to raise the assessment rate.
The brief also discussed the option of
having the assessment rate vary to
ensure that milk which is consistently
pooled does not pay for services on milk
that is de-pooled and does not pay an
assessment.
A witness appearing on behalf of
Dean viewed Proposal 7 as an extra tax
on those producers who already pay for
the administration of the order every
month, unlike those producers whose
milk is de-pooled. The witness
contended that if Proposal 3, 4, or 5
were adopted, the amount of milk being
de-pooled on the UMW order would
decrease significantly, thus giving the
Market Administrator a more consistent
income stream. However, asserted the
witness, if the Department decided to
increase the administrative assessment,
Dean would encourage an amended
provision that would charge a higher
assessment on milk not pooled in the
previous month.
Dean’s post-hearing brief reiterated
support for increasing the maximum
administrative rate while maintaining
that adoption of Proposal 3 would
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
prevent the need to actually increase the
administrative assessment rate. The
brief proposed that if the administrative
assessment rate is increased, the Market
Administrator should be granted the
authority to insulate continuously
pooled producers from paying the
increased assessment.
A witness appearing on behalf of
WCA testified in opposition to Proposal
7. The witness asserted that the Market
Administrator should use other means
to address what the witness
characterized as short-term funding
declines.
A witness representing Oberweis
Dairy also opposed adoption of Proposal
7 because it would increase costs to
producers.
The hearing record reveals that
fluctuations in the volume of milk
pooled on the UMW order attributed to
de-pooling can reduce the Market
Administrator revenues to a level too
low for proper administration of the
order. At the current assessment rate of
5 cents per cwt, 1.5 billion pounds of
pooled milk is needed to generate
sufficient funds for the administration
of the order. However, de-pooling has
resulted in pooled volumes far below
that needed to generate an adequate
revenue stream.
The recommended adoption of a
proposal to deter the de-pooling of milk
should result in a more stable revenue
stream for the administration of the
UMW order. Nevertheless, it is
reasonable to increase the maximum
administrative assessment rate to ensure
that the Market Administrator has the
proper funds to carry out all of the
services provided by the UMW order.
While the maximum administrative rate
should be increased to 8 cents per cwt,
the actual rate charged will only be as
high as necessary to properly administer
the order and provide the necessary
services to market participants.
Rulings on Proposed Findings and
Conclusions
Briefs and proposed findings and
conclusions were filed on behalf of
certain interested parties. These briefs,
proposed findings and conclusions, and
the evidence in the record were
considered in making the findings and
conclusions set forth above. To the
extent that the suggested findings and
conclusions filed by interested parties
are inconsistent with the findings and
conclusions set forth herein, the
requests to make such findings or reach
such conclusions are denied for the
reasons previously stated in this
decision.
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 35 / Wednesday, February 22, 2006 / Proposed Rules
General Findings
§ 1030.13
The findings and determinations
hereinafter set forth supplement those
that were made when the UMW order
was first issued and when it was
amended. The previous findings and
determinations are hereby ratified and
confirmed, except where they may
conflict with those set forth herein.
(a) The tentative marketing agreement
and the order, as hereby proposed to be
amended, and all of the terms and
conditions thereof, will tend to
effectuate the declared policy of the Act;
(b) The parity prices of milk as
determined pursuant to section 2 of the
Act are not reasonable in view of the
price of feeds, available supplies of
feeds, and other economic conditions
which affect market supply and demand
for milk in the marketing area, and the
minimum prices specified in the
tentative marketing agreement and the
order, as hereby proposed to be
amended, are such prices as will reflect
the aforesaid factors, insure a sufficient
quantity of pure and wholesome milk,
and be in the public interest; and
(c) The tentative marketing agreement
and the order, as hereby proposed to be
amended, will regulate the handling of
milk in the same manner as, and will be
applicable only to persons in the
respective classes of industrial and
commercial activity specified in, the
marketing agreement upon which a
hearing has been held.
*
Recommended Marketing Agreement
and Order Amending the Order
The recommended marketing
agreement is not included in this
decision because the regulatory
provisions thereof would be the same as
those contained in the order, as hereby
proposed to be amended. The following
order amending the order, as amended,
regulating the handling of milk in the
UMW marketing area is recommended
as the detailed and appropriate means
by which the foregoing conclusions may
be carried out.
List of Subjects in 7 CFR Part 1030
cprice-sewell on PROD1PC66 with PROPOSALS
Milk marketing orders.
For the reasons set forth in the
preamble, 7 CFR part 1030, is proposed
to be amended as follows:
PART 1030—MILK IN THE UPPER
MIDWEST MARKETING AREA
1. The authority citation for 7 CFR
part 1030 continues to read as follows:
Authority: 7 U.S.C. 601–674.
2. Section 1030.13 is amended by
adding a new paragraph (f), to read as
follows:
VerDate Aug<31>2005
14:42 Feb 21, 2006
Jkt 208001
Producer milk.
*
*
*
*
(f) The quantity of milk reported by a
handler pursuant to § 1030.30(a)(1) and/
or § 1030.30(c)(1) for April through
February may not exceed 125 percent,
and March may not exceed 135 percent
of the producer milk receipts pooled by
the handler during the prior month.
Milk diverted to nonpool plants
reported in excess of this limit shall be
removed from the pool. Milk in excess
of this limit received at pool plants,
other than pool distributing plants, shall
be classified pursuant to
§ 1000.44(a)(3)(v) and § 1000.44(b)(3)(v)
of this title. The handler must designate,
by producer pick-up, which milk is to
be removed from the pool. If the handler
fails to provide this information, the
market administrator will make the
determination. The following provisions
apply:
(1) Milk shipped to and physically
received at pool distributing plants shall
not be subject to the 125 or 135 percent
limitation;
(2) Producer milk qualified pursuant
to ll.13 of any other Federal Order
and continuously pooled in any Federal
Order for the previous six months shall
not be included in the computation of
the 125 or 135 percent limitation;
(3) The market administrator may
waive the 125 or 135 percent limitation:
(i) For a new handler on the order,
subject to the provisions of
§ 1030.13(f)(3), or
(ii) For an existing handler with
significantly changed milk supply
conditions due to unusual
circumstances;
(4) A bloc of milk may be considered
ineligible for pooling if the market
administrator determines that handlers
altered the reporting of such milk for the
purpose of evading the provisions of
this paragraph (f).
3. Section 1030.85 is revised, to read
as follows:
§ 1030.85 Assessment for order
administration.
On or before the payment receipt date
specified under § 1030.71, each handler
shall pay to the market administrator its
pro rata share of the expense of
administration of the order at a rate
specified by the market administrator
that is no more than 8 cents per
hundredweight with respect to:
(a) Receipts of producer milk
(including the handler’s own
production) other than such receipts by
a handler described in § 1000.9(c) that
were delivered to pool plants of other
handlers;
(b) Receipts from a handler described
in § 1000.9(c) of this title;
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
9015
(c) Receipts of concentrated fluid milk
products from unregulated supply
plants and receipts of nonfluid milk
products assigned to Class I use
pursuant to § 1000.43(d) of this title and
other source milk allocated to Class I
pursuant to § 1000.44(a)(3) and (8) of
this title and the corresponding steps of
§ 1000.44(b) of this title, except other
source milk that is excluded from the
computations pursuant to § 1030.60(h)
and (i); and
(d) Route disposition in the marketing
area from a partially regulated
distributing plant that exceeds the skim
milk and butterfat subtracted pursuant
to § 1000.76(a)(1)(i) and (ii) of this title.
Dated: February 15, 2006.
Lloyd C. Day,
Administrator, Agricultural Marketing
Service.
[FR Doc. 06–1585 Filed 2–21–06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 3410–02–P
DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE
Agricultural Marketing Service
7 CFR Part 1032
[Docket No. AO–313–A48; DA–04–06]
Milk in the Central Marketing Area;
Recommended Decision and
Opportunity To File Written Exceptions
on Proposed Amendments to Tentative
Marketing Agreement and to Order
Agricultural Marketing Service,
USDA.
ACTION: Proposed rule; recommended
decision.
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: This decision recommends
adoption of proposals that would amend
certain features of the Central Federal
milk marketing order. Specifically, this
decision recommends adoption of
proposals that would increase supply
plant performance standards, amend
features of the ‘‘touch-base’’ provision,
amend certain features of the ‘‘split
plant’’ provision and decrease the
diversion limit standards of the order.
This decision also recommends
adoption of a proposal that would limit
the volume of milk a handler can pool
in a month to 125 percent of the total
volume of milk pooled in the previous
month.
DATES: Comments should be submitted
on or before April 24, 2006.
ADDRESSES: Comments (6 copies) should
be filed with the Hearing Clerk, STOP
9200-Room 1031, United States
Department of Agriculture, 1400
Independence Avenue, SW.,
Washington, DC 20250–9200.
E:\FR\FM\22FEP1.SGM
22FEP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 71, Number 35 (Wednesday, February 22, 2006)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 9004-9015]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 06-1585]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE
Agricultural Marketing Service
7 CFR Part 1030
[Docket No. AO-361-A39; DA-04-03B]
Milk in the Upper Midwest Marketing Area; Recommended Decision
and Opportunity To File Written Exceptions on Proposed Amendments to
Tentative Marketing Agreement and Order
AGENCY: Agricultural Marketing Service, USDA.
ACTION: Proposed rule; Recommended Decision.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: This decision recommends adoption of proposals that would
amend certain features of the Upper Midwest (UMW) Federal milk
marketing order. Specifically, this decision recommends adoption of
proposals that would deter the de-pooling of milk and increase the
order's maximum administrative assessment rate.
DATES: Comments must be submitted on or before April 24, 2006.
ADDRESSES: Comments (six copies) should be filed with the Hearing
Clerk, United States Department of Agriculture, STOP 9200--Room 1031,
1400 Independence Avenue, SW., Washington, DC 20250-9200. Comments may
also be submitted at the Federal e-Rulemaking portal: https://
www.regulations.gov or by e-mail: amsdairycomments@usda.gov. Reference
should be made to the title of action and docket number.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Gino Tosi, Associate Deputy
Administrator, Order Formulation and Enforcement Branch, USDA/AMS/Dairy
Programs, STOP 0231--Room 2968, 1400 Independence Avenue, SW.,
Washington, DC 20250-0231, (202) 690-1366, e-mail gino.tosi@usda.gov.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This decision recommends adoption of
amendments that would: (1) Establish a limit on the volume of milk a
handler may pool during the months of April through February to 125
percent of the volume of milk pooled in the prior month; (2) Establish
a limit on the volume of milk a handler may pool during the month of
March to 135 percent of the volume of milk pooled in the prior month;
and (3) Allow the market administrator to increase the maximum
administrative assessment rate up to 8 cents per hundredweight on all
pooled milk if necessary to maintain the required fund reserves.
This administrative action is governed by the provisions of
sections 556 and 557 of Title 5 of the United States Code and,
therefore, is excluded from the requirements of Executive Order 12866.
The amendments to the rules proposed herein have been reviewed
under Executive Order 12988, Civil Justice Reform. They are not
intended to have a retroactive effect. If adopted, the proposed
amendments would not preempt any state or local laws, regulations, or
policies, unless they present an irreconcilable conflict with this
rule.
The Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, as amended (7
U.S.C. 601-674), provides that administrative proceedings must be
exhausted before parties may file suit in court. Under section
608c(15)(A) of the Act, any handler subject to an order may request
modification or exemption from such order by filing with the Department
a petition stating that the order, any provision of the order, or any
obligation imposed in connection with the order is not in accordance
with the law. A handler is afforded the opportunity for a hearing on
the petition. After a hearing, the Department would rule on the
petition. The Act provides that the district court of the United States
in any district in which the handler is an inhabitant, or has its
principal place of business, has jurisdiction in equity to review the
Department ruling on the petition, provided a bill in equity is filed
not later than 20 days after the date of the entry of the ruling.
Regulatory Flexibility Act and Paperwork Reduction Act
In accordance with the Regulatory Flexibility Act (5 U.S.C. 601 et
seq.), the Agricultural Marketing Service has considered the economic
impact of this action on small entities and has certified that this
proposed rule will not have a significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities.
For the purpose of the Regulatory Flexibility Act, a dairy farm is
considered a ``small business'' if it has an annual gross revenue of
less than $750,000, and a dairy products manufacturer is a ``small
business'' if it has fewer than 500 employees. For the purposes of
determining which dairy farms are ``small businesses,'' the $750,000
per year criterion was used to establish a production guideline of
500,000 pounds per month. Although this guideline does not factor in
additional monies that may be received by dairy producers, it should be
an inclusive standard for most ``small'' dairy farmers. For purposes of
determining a handler's size, if the plant is part of a larger company
operating multiple plants that collectively exceed the 500-employee
limit, the plant will be considered a large business even if the local
plant has fewer than 500 employees.
During August 2004, the month during which the hearing occurred,
there were 15,802 dairy producers pooled on and 60 handlers regulated
by the UMW order. Approximately 15,608 producers, or 97 percent, were
considered small businesses based on the above criteria. Of the 60
handlers regulated by the UMW during August 2004, 49 handlers, or 82
percent, were considered small businesses.
The recommended amendments for adoption of the pooling standards
serve to revise established criteria that determine those producers,
producer milk, and plants that have a reasonable association with and
consistently serve the fluid needs of the UMW marketing area. Criteria
for pooling milk are established on the basis of performance standards
that are considered adequate to meet the Class I fluid needs of the
market and, by doing so, determine those producers who are eligible to
share in the revenue that arises from the classified pricing of milk.
Criteria for pooling are established without regard to the size of
any dairy industry organization or entity. Administrative assessments
are similarly charged without regard to the size of any dairy industry
organization or entity. Therefore, the proposed amendments will not
have a significant economic impact on a substantial number of small
entities.
A review of reporting requirements was completed under the
Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995 (44 U.S.C. Chapter 35). It was
determined that these proposed amendments would have no impact on
reporting, recordkeeping, or other compliance requirements because they
would remain identical to the current requirements. No new forms are
proposed and no additional reporting requirements would be necessary.
This recommended decision does not require additional information
collection that requires clearance by the Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) beyond currently approved information collection. The
primary sources of data used to complete the approved forms are
routinely used in
[[Page 9005]]
most business transactions. The forms require only a minimal amount of
information which can be supplied without data processing equipment or
a trained statistical staff. Thus, the information collection and
reporting burden is relatively small. Requiring the same reports for
all handlers does not significantly disadvantage any handler that is
smaller than the industry average.
No other burdens are expected to fall on the dairy industry as a
result of overlapping Federal rules. This rulemaking proceeding does
not duplicate, overlap, or conflict with any existing Federal rules.
Interested parties are invited to submit comments on the probable
regulatory and informational impact of this proposed rule on small
entities. Also, parties may suggest modifications of this proposal for
the purpose of tailoring their applicability to small businesses.
Prior Documents in This Proceeding
Notice of Hearing: Issued June 15, 2004; published June 23, 2004
(69 FR 34963).
Notice of Hearing Delay: Issued July 14, 2004; published July 21,
2004 (69 FR 43538).
Tentative Partial Decision: Issued April 8, 2005; published April
14, 2005 (70 FR 19709).
Interim Final Rule: Issued May 26, 2005; published June 1, 2005 (70
FR 31321).
Final Partial Decision: Issued September 29, 2005; published
October 5, 2005 (70 FR 58086).
Preliminary Statement
Notice is hereby given of the filing with the Hearing Clerk of this
recommended decision with respect to proposed amendments to the
tentative marketing agreement and the order regulating the handling of
milk in the UMW marketing area. This notice is issued pursuant to the
provisions of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act and the
applicable rules of practice and procedure governing the formulation of
marketing agreements and marketing orders (7 CFR part 900).
Interested parties may file written exceptions to this decision
with the Hearing Clerk, U.S. Department of Agriculture, STOP 9200--Room
1031, 1400 Independence Avenue, SW., Washington DC 20250-9200, by April
24, 2006. Six copies of the exceptions should be filed. All written
submissions made pursuant to this notice will be made available for
public inspection at the Office of the Hearing Clerk during regular
business hours (7 CFR 1.27(b)).
The hearing notice specifically invited interested persons to
present evidence concerning the probable regulatory and informational
impact of the proposals on small businesses. Some evidence was received
that specifically addressed these issues and some of the evidence
encompassed entities of various sizes.
A public hearing was held upon proposed amendments to the marketing
agreement and the order regulating the handling of milk in the UMW
marketing area. The hearing was held pursuant to the provisions of the
Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (AMAA), as amended (7
U.S.C. 601-674), and the applicable rules of practice and procedure
governing the formulation of marketing agreements and marketing orders
(7 CFR part 900).
The proposed amendments set forth below are based on the record of
a public hearing held at Bloomington, Minnesota, on August 16-19, 2004,
pursuant to a notice of hearing issued June 16, 2004, published June
23, 2004, and a notice of hearing delay issued July 14, 2004, and
published July 21, 2004.
The material issues on the record of hearing relate to:
1. Pooling Standards
A. Establishing Pooling Limits
B. Producer definition.
2. Administrative assessment rate.
Findings and Conclusions
This recommended decision specifically addresses proposals
published in the hearing notice as Proposals 3, 4, 5 and features of
Proposal 2 that seek to establish a limit on the volume of milk that
can be pooled on the order, features of Proposal 6 intending to clarify
the Producer definition by providing a definition of ``temporary loss
of Grade A approval,'' and Proposal 7 which seeks to increase the
order's maximum administrative assessment rate. As published in the
hearing notice, Proposals 1, 6, and a portion of Proposal 2 concerning
diversion limit standards and transportation credits were addressed in
a tentative partial decision published on April 14, 2005 (70 FR 19709).
For the purpose of this recommended decision, references to Proposal 2
will only pertain to the first portion regarding de-pooling and
references to Proposal 6 will only pertain to establishing a definition
of ``temporary loss of Grade A approval.''
The following findings and conclusions on the material issues are
based on evidence presented at the hearing and the record thereof:
1. Pooling Standards
A. Establishing Pooling Limits
Preliminary Statement
Federal milk marketing orders rely on the tools of classified
pricing and marketwide pooling to assure an adequate supply of milk for
fluid (Class I) use and to provide for the equitable sharing of the
revenues arising from the classified pricing of milk. Classified
pricing assigns a value to milk according to how the milk is used.
Regulated handlers who buy milk from dairy farmers are charged class
prices according to how they use the farmer's milk. Dairy farmers are
then paid a weighted average or ``blend'' price. The blend price that
dairy farmers are paid for their milk is derived through the marketwide
pooling of all class uses of milk in a marketing area. Thus each
producer receives an equal share of each use class of milk and is
indifferent as to the actual Class for which the milk was used. The
Class I price is usually the highest class price for milk. Historically
the Class I use of milk provides the additional revenue to a marketing
area's total classified use value of milk.
The series of Class prices that are applicable for any given month
are not announced simultaneously. The Class I price and the Class II
skim milk price are announced prior to the beginning of the month for
which they will be effective. Class prices for milk in all other uses
are not determined until on or before the 5th day of the following
month. The Class I price is determined by adding a differential value
to the higher of either an advanced Class III or Class IV value. These
values are calculated based on a formula using National Agricultural
Statistics Service (NASS) survey prices of cheese, butter, and nonfat
dried milk powder for the first two weeks of the preceding month. For
example, the Class I price for August is announced in late July and is
based on the higher of the Class III or IV value computed using NASS
commodity price surveys for the first two weeks of July.
The Class III and IV prices for the month are determined and
announced after the end of the month based on the NASS survey prices
for the selected dairy commodities during the month. For example, the
Class III and IV prices for August are based on NASS survey commodity
prices during August. A large increase in the NASS survey price for the
selected dairy commodities from one month to the next can result in the
Class III or IV price exceeding the Class I price. This occurrence is
commonly referred to by the dairy industry as a
[[Page 9006]]
``Class price inversion.'' A producer price inversion generally refers
to when the Class III or IV price exceeds the classified use value, or
blend price, of milk for the month. Price inversions have occurred with
increasing frequency in Federal milk orders since the current pricing
plan was implemented on January 1, 2000, despite efforts made during
Federal Order Reform to reduce such occurrences. Price inversions can
create an incentive for dairy farmers and manufacturing handlers who
voluntarily participate in the marketwide pooling of milk to elect not
pool their milk on the order. Class I handlers do not have this option;
their participation in the marketwide pool is mandatory.
The producer price differential, or PPD, is the difference between
the Class III price and the weighted average value of all Classes. In
essence, the PPD is the dairy farmer's share of the additional/reduced
revenues associated with the Class I, II and IV milk pooled in the
market. If the value of the Class I, II and IV milk in the pool is
greater than the Class III value, dairy farmers receive a positive PPD.
However a negative PPD can occur if the value of the Class III milk in
the pool exceeds the value of the remaining classes of milk in the
pool. This can occur as a result of the price inversions discussed
above.
The UMW Federal order operates a marketwide pool. The Order
contains pooling provisions which specify criteria that, if met, allow
dairy farmers to share in the benefits that arise from classified
pricing through pooling. The equalization of all class prices among
handlers regulated by an order is accomplished through a mechanism
known as the producer settlement fund (PSF). Typically, Class I
handlers pay the difference between the blend price and their use-value
of milk into the PSF. Manufacturing handlers typically receive a draw
from the PSF, usually the difference between the Class II, III or IV
price and the blend price. In this way, all handlers pay the Class
value for milk and all dairy farmer supplies receive at least the
order's blend price.
When manufacturing class prices of milk are high enough to result
in a use-value of milk for a handler that is higher than the blend
price, manufacturing handlers may choose to not pool their milk
receipts. Opting to not pool their milk receipts allows these handlers
to avoid the obligation of paying into the PSF. The choice by a
manufacturing handler to not pool their milk receipts is commonly
referred to as ``de-pooling''. When the blend price rises above the
manufacturing class use-values of milk these same handlers again opt to
pool their milk receipts. This is often referred to as ``re-pooling''.
The ability of manufacturing handlers to de-pool and re-pool
manufacturing milk is viewed by some market participants as being
inequitable to both producers and handlers.
The ``De-Pooling'' Proposals
Proponents are in agreement that milk marketing orders should
contain provisions that will tend to deter the practice of de-pooling.
Four proposals intending to deter the de-pooling of milk were
considered in this proceeding. The proposals offered different degrees
of deterrence against de-pooling by establishing limits on the amount
of milk that can be re-pooled. The proponents of these four proposals
are generally of the opinion that de-pooling erodes equity among
producers and handlers, undermines the orderly marketing of milk and is
detrimental to the Federal order system.
Two different approaches on how to best limit de-pooling are
represented by these four proposals. The first approach, published in
the hearing notice as Proposals 2 and 5, addresses de-pooling by
limiting the volume of milk a handler can pool in a month to a
specified percentage of what the handler pooled in the prior month. The
second approach, published in the hearing notice as Proposals 3 and 4,
addresses de-pooling by establishing what is commonly referred to as a
``dairy farmer for other markets'' provision. These proposals would
require milk of a producer that was de-pooled to not be able to be re-
pooled by that producer for a defined time period. All proponents
agreed that while none of the proposals would completely eliminate de-
pooling, they would likely deter the practice.
Of the four proposals received that would limit de-pooling, this
decision recommends adoption of Proposal 2, offered by Mid-West
Dairymen's Company (Mid-West) on behalf of Cass-Clay Creamery Inc.
(Cass-Clay), Dairy Farmers of America, Inc. (DFA), Foremost Farms USA
Cooperative (Foremost Farms), Land O'Lakes Inc. (LOL), Milwaukee
Cooperative Milk Producers (MCMP), Manitowoc Milk Producers Cooperative
(MMPC), Swiss Valley Farms Company (Swiss Valley), and Woodstock
Progressive Milk Producers Association (Woodstock). Hereinafter, this
decision will refer to these proponents as ``Mid-West, et al.''
Although Foremost Farms was a proponent of Proposal 2, no testimony was
offered on their behalf. At the hearing, Plainview Milk Products
Cooperative and Westby Cooperative Creamery also supported the
testimony given on behalf of Mid-West, et al. The proponents of
Proposal 2 are all cooperatives representing producers whose milk
supplies the milk needs of the marketing area and is pooled on the UMW
order.
Specifically, adoption of Proposal 2 will limit the volume of milk
a handler could pool in a month to no more than 125 percent of the
volume of milk pooled in the prior month during the months of April
through February, and to no more than 135 percent of the prior month's
pooled volume in the month of March. Milk diverted to nonpool plants in
excess of this limit will not be pooled, and milk shipped to pool
distributing plants will not be subject to the 125 or 135 percent
limitation
As published in the hearing notice, Proposal 5, offered by Dean
Foods Company (Dean), addresses de-pooling in a similar manner as
Proposal 2, but would establish a limit on the total volume of milk a
handler could pool in a given month to 115 percent of the volume that
was pooled in the prior month. Dean is a handler who operates
manufacturing plants and distributing plants in the UMW marketing area.
Producer milk shipped to and physically received at a pool distributing
plant, and producer milk that was pooled continuously on another
Federal Order during the previous six months, would not be subject to
this pooling standard. Proposal 5 is not recommended for adoption.
As published in the hearing notice, Proposals 3 and 4, also offered
by Dean, address de-pooling by establishing defined time periods during
which de-pooled milk could not be pooled. Proposal 3 would require an
annual pooling commitment by a handler to the UMW market. As advanced
in Proposal 3, if the milk of a producer is de-pooled in a month, the
milk of a producer could not re-establish eligibility for pooling on
the order during the following 11 months unless 10 days' milk
production of a producer was delivered to a pool distributing plant
during the month. Under Proposal 3, handlers that de-pool milk have
limited options to return milk to the pool, either shipping 10 days'
milk production of a producer to a pool distributing plant during the
month or waiting 11 months to regain pooling eligibility
Proposal 4 is similar to Proposal 3 but is less restrictive. Under
Proposal 4, as modified at the hearing, if a producer's milk is de-
pooled in any of the months of February through June, or during any of
the preceding three months, or during any of the preceding months of
July through January, the equivalent of at
[[Page 9007]]
least 10 days' milk production would need to be physically received at
a pool distributing plant in order to pool all of the dairy farmer's
production for the month. Additionally, if the milk of a dairy farmer
is de-pooled in any of the months of July through January, or in a
preceding month, at least 10 days' milk production of the dairy farmer
would need to be delivered to a pool distributing plant to have all the
milk of the dairy farmer pooled for the month.
The current Producer milk provision of the UMW order considers the
milk of a dairy farmer to be producer milk when it is delivered
directly from farms to pool plant or diverted by a pool plant or
cooperative handler to a nonpool plant. Milk is not eligible for
diversion to nonpool plants unless at least one days' production of
such dairy farmer is received at a pool plant anytime during the
initial qualifying month, often referred to as ``touching-base''. To be
eligible to pool all of its milk receipts, the pooling handler must
ship at least 10 percent of its milk receipts to a pool distributing
plant, producer-handler, a partially regulated distributing plant, or a
pool distributing plant regulated by another Federal order. A handler's
diversion of milk to nonpool plants can only be made to nonpool plants
located in the States of Illinois, Iowa, Minnesota, Wisconsin, North
Dakota, South Dakota, and the Upper Peninsula of Michigan, or to a
distributing plant regulated under another Federal order. Milk that is
subject to inclusion in another marketwide equalization program
operated by a state government is not considered producer milk. The
order currently does not limit a handler's ability to de-pool milk.
The proponents of Proposals 2, 3, 4 and 5 are all of the opinion
that the current pooling standards are inadequate because they enable
manufacturing handlers to de-pool milk when advantageous to do so and
immediately re-pool milk in a following month if advantageous to do so.
According to the proponents, the UMW blend price is lowered when large
volumes of sometimes higher valued milk used for manufacturing is de-
pooled and when the large volumes of de-pooled milk returns to the
pool. Furthermore, the witnesses argued that de-pooling handlers do not
account to the UMW pool at the order's classified prices and therefore
face different costs than their similarly situated pooling competitors.
The proponents insisted that the pooling standards of the order need to
be amended to ensure producer and handler equity, even though the
proposals differed on how best to meet this end.
A witness appearing on behalf of Mid-West, et al., testified in
support of Proposal 2. The witness was of the opinion that the
underlying principles of the Federal order program are to supply milk
to the fluid market, equitably share pool proceeds among all
participating producers, and promote orderly marketing. The witness
explained that the Federal order program achieves these objectives
through classified pricing, through which Class I milk generates
revenue for the pool; and marketwide pooling, which equalizes payments
to all participating producers who serve the market regardless of how
the milk of any single producer is utilized.
The Mid-West, et al., witness said that currently milk utilized at
manufacturing plants can be de-pooled and again pooled in a subsequent
month when it is economically beneficial to the handler. When choosing
to pool or not to pool, the witness explained, handlers assess whether
participating in the marketwide pool would require them to make a
payment into or receive a payment from the PSF. According to the
witness, milk utilized as Class I must always be pooled regardless of
whether the pooling handler would make a payment into, or receives a
payment from, the PSF.
The Mid-West, et al., witness testified that because manufacturing
milk can freely exit and return to the pool, producers who regularly
and consistently service the UMW fluid market are not being treated
equitably under the terms of the order. According to the witness, these
producers receive a lower blend price because the value of the milk
that was de-pooled was not shared equitably among all the market's
producers.
The Mid-West, et al., witness maintained that the ability of
manufacturing handlers to de-pool milk creates inequities among
handlers and producers. The witness said that when the PPD is negative,
dairy farmers receive different payments for their milk depending on if
their milk was pooled, and handlers are not required to account to the
pool at classified prices depending on their pooling decisions. Class I
handlers who must pool their milk receipts always have a disadvantage
when the PPD is negative, explained the witness, because a
manufacturing handler can opt to de-pool and avoid paying into the PSF.
According to the witness this results in higher prices that can be paid
to the producers supplying the manufacturing handler. The witness
contrasted that when the PPD is positive, milk that had been de-pooled
seeks to return to the pool. According to the witness, this also
dilutes the blend price paid to producers who had been supplying the
Class I handler.
The Mid-West, et al., witness, relying on Market Administrator
statistics, noted that in May 2004, all producer milk pooled on the
order was subject to a negative $1.97 per hundredweight (cwt) PPD.
However, the witness emphasized that a manufacturing handler who chose
to de-pool their milk supply and did not have to account to the pool at
classified prices had an imputed PPD of zero. In other words, the
witness explained, milk used in manufactured products was worth more
than milk used in fluid products. Relying on additional Market
Administrator statistics, the witness demonstrated that if 100 percent
of eligible Class III milk had pooled in July 2003 through May 2004,
the estimated PPD would have averaged a negative $0.098 per cwt rather
than the actual average PPD of negative $0.773 per cwt.
The Midwest, et al., witness explained how adoption of Proposal 2
would improve both producer and handler equity. The witness said that
Proposal 2 would only limit the amount of milk a handler could pool up
to 125 or 135 percent of the previous month's pooled volume and
clarified that any milk delivered to a distributing plant would not be
subject to the 125 or 135 percent pooling calculation. If Proposal 2
were adopted, the witness claimed, no current handler would have to
change the physical operations of their plant. While adoption of this
proposal would not end the practice of de-pooling, speculated the
witness, it would establish financial consequences for handlers who
might not otherwise consistently pool their milk receipts.
In explaining why adoption of Proposal 2 would be reasonable and
appropriate for the UMW order, the Mid-West, et al., witness said that
a 125 percent standard should accommodate any change in the potential
growth of a handler's pooled milk volume resulting from seasonal
fluctuations in milk supply or the addition of new producers, assuming
that the handler did not de-pool. Additionally, the witness added that
to ensure no handler would need to change its physical operations,
Proposal 2 allows a 135 percent re-pooling standard in March because of
the fewer calendar days in February. The witness stressed that the 125
and 135 percent standards allow a handler to de-pool a portion of its
milk supply and over a period of months, regain the ability to again
pool its entire supply. The witness added that the proposal does not
restrict the volume of
[[Page 9008]]
milk able to be pooled in August since this is generally considered the
start of the new marketing year
The Mid-West, et al., witness also emphasized that establishing a
standard on the basis of the prior month's pooled volume has been done
in other orders. The Northeast order has a ``producer for other
markets'' provision that restricts the ability to pool the milk of a
producer if the milk of that producer had been previously de-pooled,
noted the witness. Furthermore, the witness said, milk orders in the
south and southeastern part of the country had provisions which limited
the sharing of marketwide returns in the spring months to only those
producers whose milk served the fluid market during the fall months.
The Mid-West, et al., witness predicted that price volatility would
continue in the future and result in negative PPD's and the further de-
pooling of milk. The witness was of the opinion that price volatility
and de-pooling have created emergency marketing conditions that would
warrant the Department to omit issuing a recommended decision.
A witness from DFA, appearing on behalf of Mid-West, et al.,
testified in support of Proposal 2. The witness testified that DFA
engages in the practice of de-pooling when warranted to earn sufficient
revenue to pay their producer members a competitive milk price. The DFA
witness emphasized that de-pooling creates disorderly marketing
conditions and supported Proposal 2 as the best option to deter the
practice of de-pooling. The witness offered scenarios that demonstrated
the financial incentives available to handlers who de-pool milk. The
witness asserted that the current pooling standards of the UMW order
where producers qualify for pooling by meeting a one-day touch base
standard allow handlers the opportunity to reap financial rewards from
the market by de-pooling and re-pooling their milk receipts.
The DFA witness explained that Proposal 2 was a compromise position
among all the entities of Mid-West, et al., noting that its adoption
would improve the current disorderly market conditions arising from the
practice of de-pooling. The witness noted that many alternatives were
considered but the proponents were of the opinion that Proposal 2 is a
significant improvement to the order's pooling provisions while still
allowing handlers to make their own pooling decisions.
Witnesses from LOL, Swiss Valley, Cass-Clay, MMPC, and DFA Central
Council, all appearing on behalf of Mid-West, et al., testified in
support of Proposal 2. Many of the witnesses testified that their
respective organizations engage in the practice of de-pooling when it
is to their advantage but that they recognize that the practice has a
negative impact on the PPD and creates disorderly marketing conditions.
Consequently, they are of the opinion that while a moderate level of
de-pooling should be tolerated, a set of standards should be
established to deter de-pooling in order to maintain orderly marketing
conditions.
The Mid-West, et al., witnesses identified above expressed support
for Proposal 2 as an acceptable and moderate approach to limiting the
practice of de-pooling. The proposal would allow flexibility in making
pooling decisions, explained the witnesses, but would also establish
significant consequences for those who opt to de-pool large volumes of
their producer milk supply. In this regard, the witnesses said that
Proposal 2 would result in ensuring more equity among handlers and
producers during times of price inversions.
A DFA dairy farmer member, whose milk is pooled on the UMW order,
testified in support of Proposal 2. The witness was of the opinion that
if a dairy farmer wants to participate in the UMW marketwide pool and
share in the revenue generated from the market, they should be prepared
to service the market every month. When handlers engage in the practice
of de-pooling their milk receipts, the witness said, the results are
severe price fluctuations and larger negative PPDs that negatively
impact the price paid to pooled producers. The witness was of the
opinion that the adoption of Proposal 2 would result in more stable
pooled milk volumes and consequently would lessen the severe and
volatile price changes that producers have experienced.
A dairy farmer appearing on behalf of MCMP, whose milk is pooled on
the UMW order, testified in support of Proposal 2. The witness said
that their farm income was negatively impacted during May 2004 as a
result of the negative $1.97 per cwt PPD. The witness added that
neighboring farms that shipped milk to other handlers reported
receiving a higher price for their milk. The opinion of the witness was
that the practice of de-pooling has led to non-uniform prices received
by farmers and that adoption of Proposal 2 would restore price equity
among producers.
A witness appearing on behalf of Dean testified in opposition to
Proposal 2. The witness said that the pooling standards of Proposal 2
are too liberal and that unlimited pooling in the month of August could
allow handlers to again take advantage of the pooling system.
A witness appearing on behalf of Northwest Dairy Association (NDA)
testified in opposition to Proposal 2. NDA is a dairy cooperative that
markets 7 billion pounds of milk annually with members in the States of
Washington, Oregon, Idaho, and Northern California. The witness
explained that NDA engages in the practice of de-pooling in other
Federal orders as a way to recover costs in their manufacturing of
butter and cheese because the Class III and IV make allowances that do
not adequately reflect such costs. The NDA witness was of the opinion
that the practice of de-pooling should be addressed at a national
hearing that would also consider other issues such as the make
allowances used in the Class III and IV price formulas.
A witness appearing on behalf of Dean testified in support of
Proposals 3, 4, and 5. The witness asserted that the intent of the
Federal order system is to ensure a sufficient supply of milk for fluid
use and provide for uniform payments to producers who stand ready,
willing, and able to serve the fluid market. While some entities are of
the opinion that the Federal order system should ensure a sufficient
milk supply to all plants, the Dean witness was of the opinion that the
Federal order system addresses only the need for ensuring a milk supply
to distributing plants. The witness elaborated on this opinion by
citing examples of order provisions that stress providing for a regular
supply of milk to distributing plants as a priority of the Federal milk
order program.
The Dean witness was of the opinion that for the Federal milk order
system to ensure orderly marketing, orders need to provide adequate
economic incentives that will attract milk to fluid plants and also
need to properly define regulations to determine the milk of those
producers who can participate in the marketwide pool. The witness
argued that a major flaw in the current regulations is that they allow
handlers to choose when to participate in the pool. In this regard, the
witness said, the order lacks the economic incentive for pool
participation by its lack of an economic disincentive to the practice
of de-pooling.
The Dean witness testified that Proposals 3, 4, and 5 are designed
to establish proper economic incentives for supplying the fluid market
and maintain equity among handlers and producers. While each proposal
offered a slightly different solution to the problem, the witness said
Dean Foods supports their adoption in the following order or
[[Page 9009]]
preference: Proposal 3, Proposal 4, and then Proposal 5.
A second witness appearing on behalf of Dean testified in support
of Proposals 3, 4, and 5. The witness argued that when handlers engage
in the practice of de-pooling it creates a burden on the producers who
consistently serve the Class I needs of the market. According to the
witness, when the PPD is negative, there is an incentive for handlers
to de-pool Class III and Class IV milk. When a handler opts to de-pool,
it decreases the amount of pooled milk and makes the PPD more negative
than it would have been had all milk been pooled, the witness said.
When the PPD is positive, milk previously de-pooled seeks to be re-
pooled which increases the volume of pooled milk valued at lower
classified prices and lowers the blend price paid to all producers, the
witness asserted. The major ``losers'' in this process, concluded the
witness, are the producers whose milk is continuously pooled regardless
of the PPD.
The second Dean witness said that Proposal 3 was designed to
increase the availability of milk for fluid use and ensure that pool
proceeds are only shared among producers who consistently service the
fluid market. The witness said that if Proposal 3 is adopted, de-pooled
milk could again become pooled as long as the producer delivered ten-
day's milk production to a pool distributing plant for twelve
consecutive months. Once that standard was met, the witness added, the
producer's milk could then be pooled under the more flexible provisions
of the UMW order.
The Dean witness asserted that there are three benefits to adoption
of Proposal 3: (1) When the PPD is negative, more Class III milk would
stay in the pool resulting in a less negative PPD; (2) Some Class III
de-pooled milk would never be re-pooled which would result in a more
positive PPD; and (3) Class III de-pooled milk would have to
demonstrate regular and significant deliveries to distributing plants
in order to be re-pooled.
In explaining Proposal 4 as an alternative to Proposal 3, the
second Dean witness indicated that the difference in the two proposals
is the number of months that the ten-day touch base provision would be
applicable before de-pooled milk could again be pooled under normal
circumstances. The witness was of the opinion that Proposal 4 would
discourage some de-pooling, however, the harm caused by the practice of
de-pooling would be better prevented by the adoption of Proposal 3.
The Dean witness also discussed Proposal 5 as a less desirable
alternative to Proposals 3 and 4. According to the witness, Proposal 5
would limit the amount of milk that can be pooled to 115 percent of the
handler's previous month's pooled milk volume. The witness explained
that the greater the volume of de-pooled milk, the more time needed
under Proposal 5 for a handler to re-pool all its milk receipts. This,
the witness said, ensures that the entities that benefit the most from
the practice of de-pooling would not receive an immediate benefit that
would otherwise occur when re-pooling.
A third witness appearing on behalf of Dean testified in support of
Proposal 3. The witness said that the current liberal pooling standards
of the UMW order are one source of disorderly marketing and are
preventing all producers from sharing equally in pool proceeds. The
witness asserted that the Federal milk order system was designed so
that through marketwide pooling all producers would share equally in
pool proceeds, and that through classified pricing milk would move to
the market's highest-valued use.
Relying on Market Administrator statistics for January 2000 through
June 2004, the witness asserted that the volume of pooled Class III
milk varied from 1.5 billion pounds in January 2004 to 11 million
pounds in April 2004. Furthermore, the witness said, the blend price in
April 2004 would have been $2.97 higher if all Class III milk had been
pooled. The witness was of the opinion that these large swings in the
volume of pooled milk results in the disorderly marketing condition of
inequitable sharing of pool proceeds among producers.
A witness appearing on behalf of Oberweis Dairy testified in
support of Proposals 2 and 3. Oberweis Dairy operates a distributing
plant with approximately 40 dairy farmer suppliers and 32 ice cream
stores in the Chicago and St. Louis area markets. The witness was of
the opinion that it is inequitable to producers and Class I handlers
when manufacturing handlers engage in the practice of de-pooling. The
witness was of the opinion that either all handlers should be able to
engage in the practice of de-pooling or de-pooling should be
prohibited. While no proposal at the hearing proposed such a
restriction, the witness was of the opinion that Proposal 3 would be
the best option to restore equity among producers. Nevertheless, the
witness said that Oberweis would support the adoption of Proposal 2 if
the Department finds it to be more appropriate.
A witness appearing on behalf of the Wisconsin Farmers Union,
Minnesota Farmers Union, and the North Dakota Farmers Union testified
about the negative effects of de-pooling on dairy producers. These
organizations represent farmers of various agricultural products in
their respective States. The witness asserted that when a cooperative
engages in the practice of de-pooling, dairy farmers are negatively
impacted because the revenue a cooperative gains from de-pooling is not
paid to producers by the cooperatives. The witness insisted that the
practice of de-pooling should be curbed so that producers are
adequately paid for the total value of their milk.
A witness appearing on behalf of Galloway Company (Galloway)
testified in support of all proposals that would limit the practice of
de-pooling. Galloway owns and operates a dairy manufacturing plant in
the UMW marketing area. The witness was of the opinion that large
negative PPD's are due, in part, to de-pooling and that has a negative
impact on the income of Galloway. The witness was of the opinion that
changes to order provisions to limit the ability to re-pool are
necessary but had no opinion as to which proposal would be the best
option.
A post-hearing brief submitted by Dean reiterated their opinion
that the pooling standards of the order need to be amended to correct
the disorderly marketing conditions arising from the practice of de-
pooling. The brief argued that the practice of de-pooling is disorderly
because a handler who de-pools milk avoids accounting to the pool at
classified prices and is not required to pay its suppliers the minimum
blend price. However, asserted Dean, a pooled handler not only accounts
to the pool at classified prices and pays its suppliers the minimum
blend price, the handler also finds it necessary to pay large premiums
to keep its suppliers.
According to the Dean brief, negative PPD's and the resulting
practice of de-pooling are not a national issue, noting that de-pooling
typically occurs in markets with low Class I utilization such as the
UMW. The Dean brief predicted that the practice of de-pooling would
occur in the future and therefore concluded that the disorderly
marketing conditions arising from the practice of de-pooling warrant
emergency action from the Department by omitting a recommended
decision.
A post hearing brief submitted on behalf of Lamers Dairy, Inc.
(Lamers) asserted that the ability of some handlers to engage in the
practice of de-
[[Page 9010]]
pooling when it is economically advantageous is a disorderly marketing
condition. Furthermore, the brief expressed the opinion that de-pooling
causes inequitable treatment among handlers because pooling handlers
must account to the PSF at minimum classified prices while handlers who
de-pool their milk receipts do not. The Lamers brief supported adoption
of Proposal 3 as the most appropriate solution to limit the practice of
de-pooling.
A witness appearing on behalf of Mid-West, et al., testified in
opposition to Proposal 3. According to the witness, requiring a
producer whose milk was de-pooled to deliver 10-day's milk production
to a pool distributing plant is a standard that would be extremely
difficult to meet. The witness stressed that finding access to a pool
distributing plant for 10-day's production would not only be extremely
difficult, it would also be costly. The Mid-West, et al., brief also
contended that the proposals offered by Dean would require physical
changes in plant operations that are not necessary to address the
practice of de-pooling in the UMW market.
The Mid-West, et al., brief disagreed with others who were of the
opinion that the de-pooling issue should be addressed at a national
hearing. The brief explained that historical Federal milk order policy
is that the pooling provisions of orders be reflective of each order's
individual marketing conditions. Therefore, the brief concluded, it is
appropriate to address the practice of de-pooling on an individual
order basis.
A witness appearing on behalf of Associated Milk Producers, Inc.
(AMPI) testified in opposition to all proposals intended to limit the
practice of de-pooling as specified in Proposals 2, 3, 4, and 5. The
witness' testimony was given on behalf of Alto Dairy Cooperative,
Bongards' Creameries, Ellsworth Cooperative Creamery, Family Dairies
USA, First District Association, Davisco Foods, Valley Queen Cheese
Company and Wisconsin Cheesemakers Association (WCA). The members
consist of cooperative associations and handlers who market or purchase
milk in the UMW marketing area. Hereinafter, this coalition of members
will be referred to collectively as ``AMPI, et al.''
The AMPI, et al., witness testified that the option to engage in
the practice of de-pooling in response to price inversions has been a
longstanding part of the Federal milk order system. The witness
testified that as a result of timing differences in announcing
classified prices, a lag between changes in the market value of milk
used in manufacturing and corresponding changes in the Federal order
Class I price sometimes results in price inversions. The witness
explained that the occasional price inversion is caused by the
announcement of the Class I price approximately two weeks prior to the
month and the announcement of the price for milk used in Class II, III,
and IV products occurring after the close of the month--a difference of
six weeks. The witness drew attention to April 2004 where the value of
Class III milk increased $6.02 per cwt during the six-week lag. This
resulted in a blend price that was substantially less than the
estimated Class III price, resulting in a large amount of de-pooled
Class III milk because, the witness said, there was no incentive for
manufacturing handlers to pool all of their milk receipts.
The AMPI, et al., witness asserted that the argument that de-pooled
milk does not serve, nor is available to serve, the fluid market is
false. According to the witness, milk that is de-pooled is available to
the Class I market during the month it is marketed and a decision to
de-pool the milk is made after the end of the month when the Class II,
III and IV prices are known. Additionally, the witness asserted that
fluid milk plants always receive a continuous supply of fluid milk
because of their contractual supply agreements.
The AMPI, et al., witness characterized the proposals under
consideration to address the practice of de-pooling as designed to
penalize handlers who engage in de-pooling their Class III milk. AMPI,
et al., the witness stated, is strongly opposed to this change in
pooling philosophy. The witness was of the opinion that the Federal
order system should continue to provide for the marketwide sharing of
money derived from sales of Class I milk since it is Class I sales that
historically generate additional revenue to producers. However, the
witness said, the order should not force handlers to share money
generated from manufactured milk products to offset a low Class I
price.
The AMPI, et al., witness was of the opinion that the practice of
de-pooling is a national issue that should be addressed in a national
hearing. The witness believed that a better solution to the practice of
de-pooling would be to eliminate the advanced pricing of Class I milk
and instead announce all Class prices after the end of the month.
The AMPI, et al., witness also testified that emergency marketing
conditions do not exist to warrant the omission of a recommended
decision by the Department. The witness stressed that price inversions
and the practice of de-pooling have occurred in the Federal order
system for decades and any major change in Department policy regarding
this practice should be addressed in a recommended decision where
interested parties can file comments and exceptions.
A post-hearing brief submitted on behalf of AMPI, et al.,
reiterated their opposition to all of the proposals that seek to deter
de-pooling. The brief argued that the AMAA intended for the government
to only require the sharing of the revenues generated from fluid sales.
According to the brief, requiring manufactured milk to remain pooled
oversteps the authority of the AMAA. The brief also expressed the
opinion that Proposals 3, 4, and 5 are designed to limit a producer's
access to the market and should therefore be denied. Furthermore, the
brief stressed that Proposals 3 through 5 would unfairly increase costs
of some UMW handlers because of the increased transportation and
capital investment that would be needed to comply with the proposed
amendments.
A witness appearing on behalf of WCA, testified in opposition to
all proposals intended to limit the practice of de-pooling as specified
in Proposals 2, 3, 4, and 5. The witness testified that WCA represents
dairy manufacturers and marketers with 32 of its members operating 42
pooled dairy facilities on the UMW order. According to the witness, 30
of the 42 pooled dairy facilities are small businesses and if the
proposals to limit the practice of de-pooling were adopted, these small
businesses would face new and significant costs to comply with the
proposed new standards without benefit to their dairy farmer suppliers.
The WCA witness expressed concern that Proposal 2 addressed the
practice of de-pooling without regard to the cause of negative PPD's,
specifically the inversion of classified prices. The witness also said
that Proposals 2, 3, 4 and 5 would put an additional administrative
burden on handlers by requiring them to designate which producers would
remain pooled or de-pooled. The witness asserted that access to
distributing plants in the UMW market is very limited and it would be
hard for a de-pooled producer to re-associate with a distributing plant
in order to be eligible to again pool their milk on the order.
The WCA witness was of the opinion that Proposals 3 and 4 also
would add additional transportation costs, administrative costs, and
the potential need for additional silo capacity to accommodate the
increased volume of milk that would be needed to meet the
[[Page 9011]]
10-day production delivery standard at a pool distributing plant. The
witness explained that many WCA members do not have the capacity to
accommodate meeting a 10-day production delivery standard for each
month. The witness was also of the opinion that existing supply
contracts provide ample milk supplies for the Class I market and
concluded that additional deliveries to pool plants are not needed to
assure an adequate supply to Class I facilities.
A witness appearing on behalf of the National Family Farm
Coalition, an organization representing family farms located in 32
states including those states comprising the UMW marketing area,
testified in opposition to all proposals at the hearing. The witness
was of the opinion that the entire Federal order system was in need of
a complete reform. The witness asserted that the proponents of the
proposals being heard were entities whose past actions have lowered
prices received by family farmers.
A post-hearing brief submitted on behalf of Alto Dairy (Alto), a
cooperative with 580 dairy farmer members in Wisconsin and Michigan,
reiterated their opposition to all proposals seeking to limit the
practice of de-pooling. The brief stressed that a decision to de-pool
is made separately from the decision to adequately supply the Class I
needs of the market.
An Extension Dairy Marketing Specialist at the University of
Wisconsin testified on the issues surrounding the practice of de-
pooling but did not support or oppose any specific proposal. The
witness referred to and explained a research paper which identified and
explained problems arising in the UMW marketing area by pooling distant
milk, the practice of de-pooling, and the resulting economic impacts to
producers. The witness said that if manufacturing prices for milk
rapidly increase during the month there will be a negative PPD but as
prices begin to decline, the PPD will again become positive over time.
The witness also explained that a negative PPD does not mean that
producers lost money. Rather, the witness clarified, the PPD is a
calculation of the difference between the Class III price and the blend
price that producers receive. However, concluded the witness, the
ability to engage in the practice of de-pooling does result in volatile
PPD's and gives rise to inequities among producers and handlers.
All Federal milk marketing orders require the pooling of milk
received at pool distributing plants--which is predominantly Class I
milk--and all pooled producers and handlers on an order share in the
additional revenue arising from higher valued Class I sales.
Manufacturing handlers and cooperatives of Class II, III and IV uses of
milk who meet the pooling and performance standards make all of their
milk receipts eligible to be pooled and usually find it advantageous.
Manufacturing handlers and cooperatives who supply a portion of their
total milk receipts to Class I distributing plants receive the
difference between their use-value of milk and the order's blend price.
Federal milk orders, including the UMW order, establish limits on the
volume of milk eligible to be pooled that is not used for fluid uses
primarily through diversion limit standards. However, manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives are not required, as are Class I handlers, to
pool all their eligible milk receipts.
According to the record, manufacturing handlers and cooperatives
have opted to not pool their milk receipts when the manufacturing class
prices of milk are higher than the order's blend price--commonly
referred to as being ``inverted.'' During such months, manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives have elected to not pool all of their
eligible milk receipts because doing so would require them to pay into
the PSF of the order, the mechanism through which handler and producer
prices are equalized. When prices are not inverted, handlers would pool
all of their eligible receipts and receive a payment or draw from the
PSF. In receiving a draw from the PSF, such handlers will have
sufficient money to pay at least the order's blend price to their
supplying dairy farmers.
When manufacturing handlers and cooperatives opt to not pool all of
their eligible milk receipts in a month, they are essentially avoiding
a payment to the PSF. This, in turn, enables them to avoid the
marketwide sharing of the additional value of milk that accrues in the
higher-valued uses of milk other than Class I. When the Class I price
again becomes the highest valued use of milk, or when other class-price
relationships become favorable, the record reveals that these same
handlers opt to again pool their eligible milk receipts and draw money
from the PSF. It is the ability of manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives opting to not pool milk and thereby avoid the marketwide
sharing of the revenue accruing from non-Class I milk sales that is
viewed by proponents as giving rise to disorderly marketing conditions.
According to proponents, producers and handlers who cannot escape being
pooled and priced under the order are not assured of equitable prices.
The record reveals that since the implementation of Federal milk
marketing order reform in January 2000, and especially in more recent
years, large and rapid increases in manufactured product prices during
certain months have provided the economic incentives for manufacturing
handlers to opt not to pool eligible milk on the UMW order. For
example, during the three-month period of February to April 2004, the
Class III price increased over 65 percent from $11.89 per cwt to $19.66
per cwt. During the same time period, total producer milk pooled on the
UMW order decreased by over 60 percent from 1.94 billion pounds to 608
million pounds. When milk volumes of this magnitude are not pooled the
impacts on producer blend prices are significant. Producers who incur
the additional costs of consistently servicing the Class I needs of the
market receive a lower return than would otherwise have been received
if they did not continue to service the Class I market. Prices received
by dairy farmers who supplied the other milk needs of the market are
not known. However, it is reasonable to conclude that prices received
by dairy farmers were not equitable or uniform.
The record reveals that ``inverted'' prices of milk are generally
the result of the timing of Class price announcements. Despite changes
made as part of Federal milk order reform to shorten the time period of
setting and announcing Class I milk prices and basing the Class I price
on the higher of the Class III or Class IV price to avoid price
inversions, large month-to-month price increases in Class III and Class
IV product prices sometimes trumped the intent of better assuring that
the Class I price for the month would be the highest-valued use of
milk. In all orders, the Class I price (and the Class II skim price) is
announced prior to or in advance of the month for which it will apply.
The Class I price is calculated by using the National Agricultural
Statistics Service (NASS) surveyed cheese, butter, nonfat dry milk and
dry whey prices for the two most current weeks prior to the 24th day of
the preceding month and then adding a differential value to the higher
of either the advanced Class III or Class IV price.
Historically, the advance pricing of Class I milk has been used in
all Federal orders because Class I handlers cannot avoid regulation and
are required to pool all of their Class I milk receipts, they should
know their product costs in advance of notifying their customers of
price changes. However, milk receipts
[[Page 9012]]
for Class III and IV uses are not required to be pooled thus, Class III
and IV product prices (and the Class II butterfat value) are not
announced in advance. These prices are announced on or before the 5th
of the following month. Of importance here is that manufacturing plant
operators and cooperatives have the benefit of knowing all the
classified prices of milk before making a decision to pool or not pool
eligible receipts.
The record reveals that the decision of manufacturing handlers or
cooperatives to pool or not pool milk is made on a month-to-month basis
and is generally independent of past pooling decisions. Manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives that elected to not pool their milk receipts
did so to avoid making payments to the PSF and they anticipated that
all other manufacturing handlers and cooperatives would do the same.
However, the record indicates that normally pooled manufacturing
handlers and cooperatives met the pooling standards of the order to
ensure that the Class I market was adequately supplied and that they
established eligibility to pool their physical receipts, including
diversions to nonpool plants. Opponents to proposals to deter de-
pooling are of the view that meeting the pooling standards of the order
and deciding how much milk to pool are unrelated events. Proponents
took the view that participation in the marketwide pool should be based
on a long-term commitment to supply the market because in the long-term
it is the sales of higher priced Class I milk that adds additional
revenue to the pool.
The producer price differential, or PPD, is the difference between
the Class III price and the weighted average value of all Class I, II
and IV milk pooled. In essence, the PPD is the residual revenue
remaining after all butterfat, protein and other solids values are paid
to producers. If the pooled value of Class I, II and IV milk is greater
than the Class III value, dairy farmers receive a positive PPD. While
the PPD is usually positive, a negative PPD can occur when class prices
rise rapidly during the six-week period between the time the Class I
price is announced and the time the Class II butterfat and III and IV
milk prices are announced. When manufacturing prices fall, this same
lag in the announcement of class prices yields a positive PPD.
As revealed by the record, when manufacturing plants and
cooperatives opted to not pool milk because of inverted price
relationships, PPD's were much more negative. When this milk is not
pooled, a larger percentage of the milk remaining pooled will be
``lower'' priced Class I milk. When manufacturing milk is not pooled
the weighted average value of milk decreases relative to the Class II,
III or IV value making the PPD more negative. For example, record
evidence demonstrated that in April 2004, a month when a sizeable
volume of milk was not pooled, the PPD was a negative $4.11 per cwt. If
all eligible milk had been pooled, the PPD would have been $2.97 per
cwt higher or a negative $1.14 per cwt.
The record reveals that when manufacturing handlers and
cooperatives opt to not pool milk, unequal pay prices may result to
similarly located dairy farmers. For example, Dean noted that when a
cooperative delivers a high percentage of their milk receipts to a
distributing plant, it lessens their ability to not pool milk, making
them less competitive in a marketplace relative to other producers and
handlers. Other evidence in the record supports conclusions identical
to Dean that when a dairy farmer or cooperative is able to receive
increased returns from shipping milk to a manufacturing handler during
times of price inversions, other dairy farmers or cooperatives who may
have shipped more milk to a pool distributing plant are competitively
disadvantaged.
The record of this proceeding reveals that the ability of
manufacturing handlers and cooperatives to not pool all of their
eligible milk receipts gives rise to disorderly marketing conditions
and warrants the establishment of additional pooling standards to
safeguard marketwide pooling. Current pooling provisions do not require
or prohibit handlers and cooperatives from pooling all eligible milk
receipts. However, the record reveals that when handlers and
cooperatives opt to not pool milk inequities arise among producers and
handlers that are contrary to the intent of the Federal milk marketing
order program--main