Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity Markets; Long-Term Transmission Rights in Markets Operated by Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent System Operators, 6693-6710 [06-1195]
Download as PDF
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
intended to prevent centrifugal compressor
intake wheel blade cracks, which can result
in engine in-flight power loss, engine
shutdown, or forced landing.
Compliance
(e) You are responsible for having the
actions required by this AD performed within
the compliance times specified unless the
actions have already been done.
Engine Modification Before Further Flight
(f) For engines modified to the TU 197
standard but not to the TU 191 or TU 224
standard, before further flight, remove the TU
197 standard and install the TU 224
standard.
Initial Inspections
(g) For all engines, borescope-inspect, and
either eddy current-inspect (ECI) or
6693
ultrasonic-inspect (UI) the centrifugal
compressor intake wheel blades using
paragraphs 2.B.(1)(a) through 2.B.(1)(g) of
Turbomeca Mandatory Service Bulletin A249
72 0100, Update No. 5, dated February 25,
2005, and the criteria in the following Table
1:
TABLE 1.—INSPECTION CRITERIA
Then borescope-inspect centrifugal compressor intake wheel
blades:
If engine modification level is:
(1) Pre TU 191 and Pre TU 224 ....
Were traces of corrosion found at
borescope-inspection?
Then confirm corrosion by performing ECI or UI within:
Within 200 flight hours-since-last
inspection.
(i) Yes ...........................................
Six months-or 50 flight hourssince-borescope
inspection,
whichever occurs first.
Two hundred flight hours-sinceborescope inspection.
Six months-or 50 flight hourssince-borescope
inspection,
whichever occurs first.
One thousand flight hours-sinceborescope inspection.
(ii) No ............................................
(2) Post TU 191 or Post TU 224 ...
Within 1,000 flight hours-since-last
inspection.
(i) Yes ...........................................
(ii) No ............................................
(h) Thereafter, perform repetitive
inspections using the criteria in Table 1 of
this AD.
(i) Remove centrifugal compressor intake
wheel blades confirmed cracked or pitted.
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Alternative Methods of Compliance
18 CFR Part 40
(j) The Manager, Engine Certification
Office, has the authority to approve
alternative methods of compliance for this
AD if requested using the procedures found
in 14 CFR 39.19.
[Docket Nos. RM06–8–000 and AD05–7–000]
Related Information
(k) Direction Generale de L’Aviation Civile
airworthiness directive F–2005–037, dated
March 2, 2005, also addresses the subject of
this AD.
Issued in Burlington, Massachusetts, on
February 3, 2006.
Peter A. White,
Acting Manager, Engine and Propeller
Directorate, Aircraft Certification Service.
[FR Doc. E6–1768 Filed 2–8–06; 8:45 am]
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
BILLING CODE 4910–13–P
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights
in Organized Electricity Markets; LongTerm Transmission Rights in Markets
Operated by Regional Transmission
Organizations and Independent
System Operators
February 2, 2006.
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission.
ACTION: Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission is proposing to
amend its regulations to require
transmission organizations that are
public utilities with organized
electricity markets to make available
long-term firm transmission rights that
satisfy certain guidelines established in
this proceeding. The Commission is
taking this action pursuant to section
1233(b) of the Energy Policy Act of
2005, Public Law No. 109–58, section
1233(b), 119 Stat. 594, 960 (2005).
DATES: Comments are due March 13,
2006. Reply comments are due March
27, 2006.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Udi E. Helman (Technical Information),
Office of Energy Markets and
Reliability, Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
PO 00000
Frm 00013
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502–
8080.
Roland Wentworth (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Markets
and Reliability, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
(202) 502–8262.
Wilbur C. Earley (Technical
Information), Office of Energy Markets
and Reliability, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
(202) 502–8087.
Harry Singh (Technical Information),
Office of Market Oversight and
Investigations, Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission, 888 First
Street, NE., Washington, DC 20426,
(202) 502–6341.
Jeffery S. Dennis (Legal Information),
Office of the General Counsel, Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street, NE., Washington, DC
20426, (202) 502–6027.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
I. Introduction
1. On August 8, 2005, the Energy
Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005) 1
became law. Pursuant to the
requirement in section 1233 of EPAct
2005,2 which added a new section 217
to the Federal Power Act (FPA), the
Commission is proposing to amend its
regulations to require each transmission
organization that is a public utility with
one or more organized electricity
markets to make available long-term
1 Pub.
2 Pub.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
L. 109–58, 119 Stat. 594 (2005).
L. 109–58, § 1233(b), 119 Stat. 594, 960.
09FEP1
6694
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
firm transmission rights that satisfy
guidelines established by the
Commission in this rulemaking. The
Commission proposes to require each
such transmission organization to file,
no later than [INSERT DATE 180 DAYS
AFTER PUBLICATION OF FINAL RULE
IN THE Federal Register], either: (1)
Tariff sheets and rate schedules that
make available long-term firm
transmission rights that are consistent
with the guidelines set forth in the Final
Rule; or (2) an explanation of how its
current tariff and rate schedules already
provide long-term firm transmission
rights that are consistent with the
guidelines set forth in the Final Rule.
Transmission organizations that are
approved by the Commission after
[INSERT DATE 180 DAYS AFTER
PUBLICATION OF FINAL RULE IN
THE Federal Register], must meet the
requirements of the proposed rule
before commencing operation.
2. New section 217(b)(4) of the FPA
provides:
The Commission shall exercise the
authority of the Commission under this Act
in a manner that facilitates the planning and
expansion of transmission facilities to meet
the reasonable needs of load-serving entities
to satisfy the service obligations of the loadserving entities, and enables load-serving
entities to secure firm transmission rights (or
equivalent tradable or financial rights) on a
long-term basis for long-term power supply
arrangements made, or planned, to meet such
needs.3
Section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005
requires:
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
Within 1 year after the date of enactment
of this section and after notice and an
opportunity for comment, the Commission
shall by rule or order, implement section
217(b)(4) of the Federal Power Act in
Transmission Organizations, as defined by
that Act with organized electricity markets.4
3. In this Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking (NOPR), we propose
guidelines for the design and
administration of long-term firm
transmission rights that transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets 5 would make available to all
transmission customers. As described in
more detail below, the Commission will
allow regional flexibility in setting the
terms of the rights, but long-term firm
transmission rights must be made
available with terms (and/or rights to
renewal) that are sufficient to meet the
needs of load-serving entities to hedge
long-term power supply arrangements
made or planned to satisfy a service
obligation. While we propose that long3 Pub.
L. 109–58, section 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 958.
at 960.
5 See ‘‘Definitions’’ below.
4 Id.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
term firm transmission rights be made
available to all transmission customers,
in the event that a transmission
organization cannot accommodate all
requests for long-term firm transmission
rights over existing transmission
capacity, we propose to require that a
preference be given to load-serving
entities with long-term power supply
arrangements used to meet service
obligations. The other properties we
believe long-term firm transmission
rights must have are discussed in the
proposed guidelines below. These
guidelines will give transmission
organizations, in consultation with
market participants, the flexibility to
propose alternative designs that reflect
regional preferences and accommodate
the regional market design, while also
ensuring that the objectives of Congress
expressed in new section 217(b)(4) of
the FPA are met.
4. In proposing this rule, the
Commission seeks to provide increased
certainty regarding the congestion cost
risks of long-term transmission service
in organized electricity markets that will
help load-serving entities and other
market participants make new
investments and other long-term power
supply arrangements. We understand
that specifying and allocating long-term
firm transmission rights supported by
existing transfer capability will raise
difficult issues that must be addressed
in this rulemaking and in its
implementation over time. We note,
however, that long-term rights are
available to market participants in a
direct manner, namely by supporting an
expansion or upgrade of grid transfer
capability. As described in more detail
below, the Commission’s policy is that
market participants that request and
support an expansion or upgrade in
accordance with their transmission
organization’s prevailing rules for cost
responsibility and allocation must be
awarded a long-term firm transmission
right for the incremental transfer
capability created by the expansion or
upgrade. Such a long-term transmission
right must be for a term equal to the life
of the new facilities, or for a lesser term
if requested by the funding entity. The
transmission organization tariffs must
clearly and specifically provide for this
arrangement, if they do not already.
II. Definitions
5. The Commission proposes several
definitions in this NOPR. We set forth
those proposed definitions in this
section, since these defined terms are
used extensively in the background
discussion and proposed guidelines that
follow. The Commission seeks comment
PO 00000
Frm 00014
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
on whether these definitions are
appropriate.
A. Transmission Organization
6. The Commission proposes a
definition for ‘‘transmission
organization’’ that is similar to the
definition provided in EPAct 2005.6
Specifically, we propose to include the
word ‘‘independent’’ in the last clause
of the EPAct 2005 definition, such that
transmission organization would mean
‘‘a Regional Transmission Organization,
Independent System Operator,
independent transmission provider, or
other independent transmission
organization finally approved by the
Commission for the operation of
transmission facilities.’’ 7 We make this
clarification to the definition in EPAct
2005 because we interpret section
1233(b) of the legislation to require that
long-term firm transmission rights be
made available in the currently existing
independent entities approved to
operate transmission facilities that have
organized electricity markets (as defined
below), and any such independent
entities that are created in the future.8
We seek comments on whether this
definition appropriately captures the
intent of section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005.
B. Load-Serving Entity and Service
Obligation
7. The Commission proposes to define
the terms ‘‘load-serving entity’’ and
‘‘service obligation,’’ for purposes of the
proposed rule, exactly as they are
defined in section 217 of the FPA.
Specifically, we propose to define loadserving entity to mean ‘‘a distribution
utility or electric utility that has a
service obligation.’’ 9 We propose to
define service obligation to mean ‘‘a
requirement applicable to, or the
exercise of authority granted to, an
electric utility under Federal, State or
local law or under long-term contracts
to provide electric service to end-users
or to a distribution utility.’’ 10 We seek
comment on whether it is necessary to
6 Pub. L. No. 109–58, section 1233, 119 Stat. 594,
985.
7 See id. at 942, 985.
8 The transmission organizations that currently
have an organized electricity market are ISO New
England, Inc. (ISO–NE), New York Independent
System Operator, Inc. (New York ISO), PJM
Interconnection, Inc. (PJM), California Independent
System Operator, Inc. (CAISO), and Midwest
Independent Transmission System Operator, Inc.
(Midwest ISO). Southwest Power Pool is currently
developing its market.
9 See id. at 957. In section 1291 of EPAct 2005,
‘‘electric utility’’ is defined as ‘‘a person or Federal
or State agency (including an entity described in
section 201(f) [of the FPA]) that sells electric
energy.’’ Id. at 984.
10 See id. at 958.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
expand or clarify these definitions in
the Final Rule.
C. Organized Electricity Market
8. EPAct 2005 and section 217 of the
FPA do not define ‘‘organized electricity
market.’’ The Commission proposes to
define organized electricity market as
‘‘an auction-based market where a single
entity receives offers to sell and bids to
buy electric energy and/or ancillary
services from multiple sellers and
buyers and determines which sales and
purchases are completed and at what
prices, based on formal rules contained
in Commission-approved tariffs, and
where the prices are used by a
transmission organization for
establishing transmission usage
charges.’’ We intend for the Final Rule
we develop in this proceeding to apply
to any transmission organization with a
day-ahead and/or real-time (or ‘‘spot’’)
bid-based energy market that is the
transmission provider in its region.11
These markets could either be
administered by the transmission
organization itself or by another entity.
The definition we propose here is
intended to ensure that the Final Rule
covers all such transmission
organizations, either existing or
developed in the future. We seek
comment on whether the scope of this
definition is appropriate or whether it
should be revised.
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
D. Long-Term Power Supply
Arrangement
9. Section 217(b)(4) of the FPA
requires the Commission to exercise its
authority to enable load-serving entities
to obtain firm transmission rights on a
long-term basis ‘‘for long-term power
supply arrangements made * * * or
planned’’ to meet service obligations.12
While ‘‘long-term power supply
arrangements’’ is not defined in the
legislation, section 217(b)(1)(A) of the
FPA suggests that a load-serving entity
has a long-term power supply
arrangement if it ‘‘owns generation
facilities, markets the output of Federal
generation facilities, or holds rights
under one or more wholesale contracts
to purchase electric energy, for the
purpose of meeting a service
obligation.’’ For purposes of this
proposed rule, we propose to use
similar language to define ‘‘long-term
power supply arrangements.’’
Specifically, we propose to define
11 As noted above, the transmission organizations
that currently have an organized electricity market
are ISO–NE, New York ISO, PJM, CAISO, and
Midwest ISO. Southwest Power Pool is currently
developing its market.
12 Pub. L. No. 109–58, section 1233, 119 Stat. 594,
958 (emphasis added).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
‘‘long-term power supply arrangements’’
to mean ‘‘the ownership of generation
facilities, rights to market the output of
Federal generation facilities with a term
of longer than one year, or rights under
one or more wholesale contracts to
purchase electric energy with a term of
longer than one year, for the purpose of
meeting a service obligation.’’ 13
III. Background
A. The Development of ISOs and RTOs
10. In Order No. 888, the Commission
found that undue discrimination and
anticompetitive practices existed in the
provision of electric transmission
service in interstate commerce, and
determined that non-discriminatory
open access transmission service was
one of the most critical components of
a successful transition to competitive
wholesale electricity markets.14
Accordingly, the Commission required
all public utilities that own, control or
operate facilities used for transmitting
electric energy in interstate commerce to
file open access transmission tariffs
(OATTs) containing certain non-price
terms and conditions and to
‘‘functionally unbundle’’ wholesale
power services from transmission
services.15
11. In addition, the Commission
found in Order No. 888 that
Independent System Operators (ISOs)
had the potential to aid in remedying
undue discrimination and
accomplishing comparable access.16 To
guide the voluntary development of
ISOs, Order No. 888 set forth 11
13 While we consider long-term as ‘‘more than one
year’’ in the context of defining a long-term power
supply arrangement, later in this NOPR we note
that we consider ‘‘long-term’’ in the context of the
appropriate terms for long-term firm transmission
rights to be terms and/or renewal rights that cover
the multiple years necessary to support a long-term
power supply arrangement. See infra at P 55.
14 Promoting Wholesale Competition Through
Open Access Non-discriminatory Transmission
Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded
Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities,
Order No. 888, 61 FR 21540 (May 10, 1996), FERC
Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,036 at 31,682 (1996), order on
reh’g, Order No. 888–A, 62 FR 12274 (March 14,
1997), FERC Stats & Regs. ¶ 31,048 (1997), order on
reh’g, Order No. 888–B, 81 FERC ¶ 61,248 (1997),
order on reh’g, Order No. 888–C, 82 FERC ¶ 61,046
(1998), aff’d in relevant part sub nom. Transmission
Access Policy Study Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667
(D.C. Cir. 2000), aff’d sub nom. New York v. FERC,
535 U.S. 1 (2002).
15 Under functional unbundling, the public utility
is required to: (1) Take wholesale transmission
services under the same tariff of general
applicability as it offers its customers; (2) state
separate rates for wholesale generation,
transmission and ancillary services; and (3) rely on
the same electronic information network that its
transmission customers rely on to obtain
information about the utility’s transmission system.
Id. at 31,654.
16 Order No. 888 at 31,655; Order No. 888–A at
30,184.
PO 00000
Frm 00015
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6695
principles for assessing ISO proposals
submitted to the Commission.17
Following Order No. 888, several
voluntary ISOs were established and
approved by the Commission.
12. In light of the creation of these
ISOs and other changes in the electric
industry, the Commission issued Order
No. 2000.18 In that order, the
Commission concluded that traditional
management of the transmission grid by
vertically integrated electric utilities
was inadequate to support the efficient
and reliable operation of transmission
facilities that is necessary for continued
development of competitive electricity
markets.19 The Commission also found
that even after functional unbundling of
electric utilities under Order No. 888,
opportunities for undue discrimination
continued to exist.20 As a result, the
Commission adopted rules intended to
facilitate the voluntary development of
Regional Transmission Organizations
(RTOs). The Commission concluded
that RTOs would provide several
benefits, including regional
transmission pricing, improved
congestion management, and more
effective management of parallel path
flows.21
13. In Order No. 2000, the
Commission established the minimum
characteristics and functions that an
RTO must satisfy to gain Commission
approval. Minimum characteristics of an
RTO include independence from market
participants and operational authority
over transmission facilities under its
control.22 Minimum functions of an
RTO include ensuring the development
and operation of market mechanisms to
manage transmission congestion,
development and implementation of
procedures to address parallel path flow
issues, and market monitoring.23 Under
Order No. 2000, the Commission has
approved the voluntary formation of a
number of RTOs.
14. Most of the RTOs and ISOs
operate organized markets for energy
and/or ancillary services in addition to
providing transmission service under a
single transmission tariff. As described
in more detail below, most of these
markets utilize a congestion
management system based on
17 Order
No. 888 at 31,730.
Transmission Organizations, Order
No. 2000, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,089 (1999), order
on reh’g, Order No. 2000–A, FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,092 (2000), aff’d sub nom. Public Utility
District No. 1 of Snohomish County, Washington v.
FERC, 272 F.3d 607 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
19 Order No. 2000 at 30,992–93 and 31,014–15.
20 Id. at 31,015–17.
21 Id. at 31,024.
22 Id. at 31,046 et seq.
23 Id. at 31,106 et seq.
18 Regional
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
6696
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
Locational Marginal Pricing (LMP).
Congestion is defined as the inability to
inject and withdraw additional energy
at particular locations in the network
due to the fact that the injections and
withdrawals would cause power flows
over a specific transmission facility to
violate the reliability limits for that
facility. The market operator manages
congestion by scheduling and
dispatching generators that can meet
load in the presence of congestion.
Financially, in LMP markets the price of
congestion is measured as the difference
in the cost of energy in the spot market
at two different locations in the
network.24 When such price differences
occur, a congestion charge is assessed to
transmission users based on their nodal
injections and withdrawals. These price
differences can be variable and difficult
to predict. In order to manage the risk
associated with the variability in prices
due to transmission congestion, these
markets use various forms of Financial
Transmission Rights (FTRs) (described
in more detail below) to allow market
participants who hold the rights to
protect against such price risks. In most
cases, these FTRs have terms of one year
or less. The use of FTRs and their terms
is also discussed in more detail below.25
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
B. Currently Available Transmission
Rights
15. In recent years, interest in longterm transmission rights in organized
electricity markets has increased,
stemming in large part from a desire of
some market participants to obtain
rights that replicate the transmission
service that was available to them prior
to the formation of the organized
electricity markets and remains
available today in regions without
organized electricity markets. The
principal concern of these market
participants is the inability to obtain a
fixed, long-term level of service under
pricing arrangements that hedge the
congestion cost risk that they face in the
organized electricity markets. This
section describes the transmission rights
that are available in regions with and
without organized electricity markets,
and concludes with a comparison of the
two types of rights.
1. Transmission Rights in Regions
Without Organized Electricity Markets
16. In general, in regions without
organized electricity markets,
transmission service is provided to
customers under the terms of the Order
No. 888 OATT, or under terms of
contracts that predate the OATT. The
24 See
25 See
infra at P 21–22.
infra at P 23–28.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
OATT offers two types of transmission
service: Network integration
transmission service (network service),
which is a long-term firm transmission
service, and point-to-point transmission
service, which is available on a firm or
non-firm basis and on a long-term (one
year or longer) or short-term basis. Longterm firm transmission customers taking
service under the OATT have the right
to continue to take transmission service
from the transmission provider when
their contract expires (rollover right).
Transmission providers are required to
expand facilities to satisfy network and
point-to-point customer needs.26
17. Firm point-to-point transmission
service provides for the transmission of
energy between designated points of
receipt and designated points of
delivery. A customer taking firm pointto-point transmission service generally
pays a monthly demand charge based on
its reserved capacity, and it may resell
the service to another customer.27
18. Network service provides the
customer with flexibility to utilize its
current and planned generation
resources to serve its network load in a
manner comparable to that in which the
transmission provider utilizes its
generation resources to serve its native
load customers. A network customer
must designate network resources,
including all generation owned,
purchased or leased by the network
customer to serve its designated load. A
network customer also must designate
the individual network loads on whose
behalf the transmission provider will
provide network service. The network
customer pays a monthly charge for
basic service based on its load ratio
share of the transmission provider’s
transmission revenue requirement.
19. As a condition of receiving
network service, a network customer
agrees to redispatch its network
resources as requested by the
transmission provider.28 The
transmission provider must plan,
26 See Order No. 888 pro forma OATT at sections
13.5, 15.4 and 28.2.
27 Under the Commission’s transmission pricing
policy, the demand charge may reflect the higher
of the transmission provider’s embedded costs or
incremental expansion costs. Also, if the
transmission system is constrained, the demand
charge may reflect the higher of embedded costs or
‘‘opportunity’’ costs, with the latter capped at
incremental expansion costs. See Inquiry
Concerning the Commission’s Pricing Policy for
Transmission Services Provided by Public Utilities
Under the Federal Power Act, Policy Statement, 69
FERC ¶ 61,086 (1994). In practice, the demand
charge is almost always determined on basis of the
transmission provider’s embedded costs.
28 Redispatch means that, due to congestion, the
utility changes the output of generators to maintain
the energy balance. The output of some generators
may be increased while the output of others may
decrease.
PO 00000
Frm 00016
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
construct, operate and maintain its
transmission system in order to provide
the network customer with network
service over the transmission provider’s
system, and must designate its own
resources and loads in the same manner
as a network customer. If the
transmission provider needs to
redispatch the system due to congestion
to accommodate a network customer’s
schedule, the costs of redispatch are
passed through to the transmission
provider’s network customers, including
its own native load, on a load-ratio
basis. If a curtailment on the
transmission provider’s system is
required to maintain reliable operation
of the system, curtailments are made on
a non-discriminatory basis to the extent
practicable and consistent with good
utility practice, with firm service having
the highest priority and non-firm
generally having the lowest priority.
20. The price that a transmission
customer pays for OATT transmission
service is usually predictable and
relatively stable over the long-term. For
example, a load-serving entity that has
a generating facility at one location that
it wishes to use to serve load at a second
location can contract for long-term
point-to-point transmission service from
the generator to the load. For this
service, the load-serving entity pays
only a demand charge that is known in
advance. Although the load-serving
entity must pay the demand charge
whether or not it uses its full
reservation, it does not have to pay
additional costs associated with
transmission congestion for point-topoint transmission service even when
the transmission provider must
redispatch its generators to honor the
firm service commitment. If the loadserving entity has generators and loads
at multiple locations, it can request
network service and dispatch of its
generators to serve its loads in a least
cost manner. The load-serving entity
must pay a load ratio share of the
transmission provider’s Commissionapproved transmission revenue
requirement but, again, is not directly
assigned any congestion costs. If either
the transmission provider’s or the loadserving entity’s generators have to be
redispatched to relieve congestion, then
the cost of redispatch is shared by the
transmission provider and all network
customers on a load ratio basis. Thus,
whether it takes firm point-to-point
transmission service or network service,
the load-serving entity faces
transmission costs that are relatively
stable and predictable over the term of
its service agreement.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
2. Transmission Rights in Organized
Electricity Markets
21. Each of the transmission
organizations that exist today has
implemented or is planning to
implement an organized electricity
market that uses locational pricing for
electric energy. In most cases, the
locational pricing system that is used is
LMP. Under LMP, the price at each
location in the grid at any given time
reflects the cost of making available an
additional unit of energy for purchase at
that location and time. In the absence of
transmission congestion, all locational
prices at a given time are the same.29
However, when congestion is present,
locational prices typically will not be
the same, and the difference between
any two locational prices represents the
cost of congestion between those
locations.
22. Because locational spot prices can
vary significantly over time, a market
participant potentially faces some
degree of price uncertainty. Consider a
load-serving entity that has a generator
at one location and load at another. If
there is no congestion, the generator and
the load will see the same locational
prices just as if they were at the same
location. However, when congestion
arises, locational prices will differ, and
the price that the load-serving entity’s
generator receives typically will not be
the same as the price that its load must
pay.30 This difference in prices is the
congestion cost, and the load-serving
entity must pay this cost to the
transmission organization whenever
power is injected and withdrawn at
different locations in the transmission
system under constrained conditions.
23. To reduce the uncertainty due to
congestion, transmission organizations
that use locational marginal pricing
make FTRs available to their market
participants.31 An FTR is a right to
receive the congestion costs paid by grid
users and collected by the transmission
organization for one megawatt of
electricity delivered from a specified
point of receipt to a specified point of
delivery. The holder of an FTR receives
in each hour a payment that is
29 The inclusion of marginal losses can cause
locational prices to differ across locations even in
the absence of congestion. For purposes of this
discussion, we will consider only the congestion
component of locational price differences.
30 It is important to note that, depending on the
relative magnitude of the prices at the generator’s
location and the load’s location, congestion costs
can be positive or negative.
31 We use the term FTR in this NOPR to refer
generally to the financial transmission instruments
used in the various organized electricity markets
that currently exist. In some markets, these
financial instruments are called transmission
congestion contracts or congestion revenue rights.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
calculated by subtracting the price at the
point of receipt from the price at the
point of delivery, and multiplying the
difference by the megawatt quantity.
24. In an LMP system, all spot power
is purchased and sold at locational
prices and all scheduled injections and
withdrawals are subject to congestion
charges. When there is no congestion,
the prices are the same and the
payments to FTR holders are zero.
However, when congestion is present,
prices will differ; prices for withdrawals
are generally higher than prices for
injections, creating a source of funds to
pay the FTR holders. To ensure that the
excess revenue is sufficient to meet its
FTR payment obligations under normal
operating conditions, the transmission
organization generally subjects any
award of FTRs to a simultaneous
feasibility test. The simultaneous
feasibility test requires that, before
specific FTRs can be awarded, the
transmission organization must
demonstrate that the transmission
system is capable of physically
delivering the power flows represented
by the FTRs simultaneously with the
power flows represented by all
concurrently or previously awarded
FTRs. Although FTRs do not convey a
physical right (or obligation) to use the
transmission system, the transmission
organization will be at risk of not
receiving sufficient revenues to meet all
of its FTR payment obligations under
normal operating conditions if any
awarded FTRs do not meet the
simultaneous feasibility test. Any time
that revenues are not sufficient, the
transmission organization is said to be
‘‘revenue inadequate.’’ 32
25. The most common type of FTR,
which is known as an FTR ‘‘obligation,’’
provides for a payment to the holder
when congestion cost is positive, but
also requires the holder to make a
payment to the transmission
organization whenever the cost is
negative. Because of this feature, some
transmission organizations also offer
FTR ‘‘options,’’ which do not place a
payment obligation on the rights holder.
However, because FTR options require
more transmission capacity than FTR
obligations to meet the simultaneous
feasibility test, their availability is
limited.33 Therefore, for purposes of the
32 It should be noted that, even when all awarded
FTRs meet the simultaneous feasibility test, the
Transmission Organization may at times be revenue
inadequate as a result of unexpected events, such
as a line outage or transmission system disruption
that reduces transfer capability.
33 The need for more capacity is due to the fact
that the Transmission Organization cannot assume
that the FTR options will provide any
‘‘counterflows’’ when it conducts the simultaneous
feasibility test.
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6697
discussion in this section, we will
assume that FTRs are limited to FTR
obligations.34
26. If a load-serving entity holds an
FTR that matches its injections and
withdrawals exactly, it pays no net
congestion cost.35 A load-serving entity
may also reduce its congestion cost risk
by holding an FTR that provides a
partial hedge. Typically, the FTRs that
load-serving entities hold do not exactly
match their use of the transmission
system in each hour, but the ‘‘over’’ and
‘‘under’’ financial coverage provided by
the FTRs evens out over time to provide
a sufficient hedge.
27. In general, transmission
organizations provide FTRs on an
annual basis to load-serving entities and
others that pay access charges or fixed
transmission rates. Load-serving entities
receive FTRs either through direct
allocation or through a two-step process
in which the load-serving entity first is
allocated auction revenue rights (ARRs)
and then purchases FTRs in an
auction.36 The revenues from the
auction flow back to the load-serving
entity and other ARR holders and thus
defray the cost of purchasing the FTRs
in the auction. Transmission
organizations currently offer ARRs and
FTRs with terms of one year or less.
Although details vary by transmission
organization, the allocation is based
largely on historical uses of the system
as measured by peak loads, but also
allows market participants some
flexibility to choose among transmission
paths. Most transmission organizations
also allocate long-term ARRs and FTRs
to any party that invests in transmission
upgrades that increase transmission
capability. FTRs can be traded in annual
and monthly transmission organization
auctions or bilaterally outside the
auction.
28. Since the state of the transmission
system and market prices change from
year to year, the annual allocation
allows market participants to re34 See infra at P 72–79 for a more complete
discussion of the properties of FTR obligations and
FTR options.
35 This net result is reached because congestion
charges billed to the load-serving entity (or any
other party that holds FTRs) are exactly offset by
FTR payments.
36 ARRs confer the right to collect revenues from
the subsequent FTR auction. For example, the
holder of an ARR between location A and location
B knows that it will collect revenues equal to the
market clearing price of an FTR between location
A and location B. An ARR can, but does not need
to, exactly match an FTR. In some Organized
Electricity Markets, a market participant must
submit a bid for FTRs in the auction to convert its
ARRs to FTRs, while in other Organized Electricity
Markets a market participant can convert its ARRs
to FTRs directly and is not required to bid in the
auction.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
6698
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
configure their transmission rights
requests each year to reflect such
changes. The annual reconfiguration
also helps the transmission organization
to manage exposure to situations where
payments to FTR holders can exceed
congestion revenues. Revenue shortfalls
can occur due to changes in the
transmission grid or in the availability
of generators that have a major impact
on power flows. If such changes are
expected to be long-lasting, the
transmission organization is able to
adjust the quantity and configuration of
rights made available in the next annual
cycle. However, a load-serving entity
may receive fewer FTRs or ARRs than
it requests due to factors outside of its
control, such as changes in the network,
the network flow assumptions or the
FTR nominations of other participants.
As a result, load-serving entities are
uncertain from year to year whether
they will obtain the FTRs needed to
support long-term power supply
arrangements, including investment in
generation resources.
3. Comparison of Transmission Rights
in Regions With and Without Organized
Electricity Markets
29. There are several important
differences between transmission
service under the OATT and
transmission rights in organized
electricity markets that use LMP and
FTRs. However, the differences that are
most relevant for purposes of this NOPR
concern the management of congestion,
the recovery of congestion costs and the
availability of long-term service
arrangements.
30. Under the OATT, the transmission
provider manages congestion by
redispatching its own or its customers’
network resources as needed to
accommodate a transmission constraint;
the OATT provides no mechanism by
which firm point-to-point transmission
customers can participate directly in
congestion management. However, in
organized electricity markets, the
transmission organization manages
congestion through the use of locational
prices. This means that all available
resources under an LMP system can
participate in redispatch for congestion
management because they all receive
the congestion price signal. As a result,
a transmission organization in a region
with an organized electricity market is
less likely to have to invoke
transmission loading relief (TLR)
procedures and service curtailments
than a transmission provider under the
OATT.
31. The recovery of congestion costs
also differs greatly between regions with
and without organized electricity
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
markets. In regions where transmission
service is provided under the OATT, a
transmission customer that takes
network service or firm point-to-point
transmission service is not charged
directly for the costs of the redispatch
that may be required to accommodate its
use of the transmission system. For
example, a firm point-to-point
transmission customer is allowed to
take service up to its contractual
entitlement while paying only a fixed
demand charge. Also, although a
network customer must pay a share of
any redispatch costs that the
transmission provider and other
network customers incur, its cost
responsibility is determined after the
fact as a load ratio share of the total
redispatch costs that are incurred on
behalf of all users of the system over a
given time period. While this type of
pricing may not present the customer
with a price signal that accurately
reflects all of the costs occasioned by
the customer’s use of the system, it
lowers the transmission customer’s
price uncertainty. In addition, both
network service and firm point-to-point
transmission service can be obtained
under long-term contracts. These
attributes of OATT transmission service
result in a less volatile price for
transmission service over a long-term,
which in turn can help facilitate the
planning and financing of large
generation facilities and other long-term
power supply arrangements.
32. In contrast, a transmission
organization in a region with an
organized electricity market recovers
congestion costs through the locational
pricing of energy. Because locational
prices include a congestion cost
component (which can be positive,
negative or zero), a participant in an
organized electricity market faces the
prospect of paying a congestion charge
for many of its transactions. For
example, as explained above, a loadserving entity that has generation at one
location and load at another, but does
not hold FTRs, is at risk of incurring
congestion costs, which may not be
predictable. Also, although that loadserving entity can avoid congestion
costs by holding FTRs, it still faces a
congestion price risk if its spot sales and
purchases or scheduled injections and
withdrawals do not correspond exactly
to its allocated (or purchased) FTRs.
Clearly, locational pricing and pricebased congestion management provide
the market participant with much of the
information it needs to make cost
effective decisions regarding energy
consumption and use of the
transmission system (as well as
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
investment in new generation and
transmission upgrades). However, the
FTRs that transmission organizations
currently provide to hedge congestion
charges for using existing transmission
capacity (as opposed to incremental
transmission expansions) are generally
available for terms of only one year or
less. This can create uncertainty for the
market participant because, in any given
year, its award of FTRs may not be
sufficient to meet its needs. Some
market participants have expressed
concern that this uncertainty makes it
more difficult to finance long-term
power supply arrangements.
33. The Commission believes that
some of the problems of uncertainty in
organized electricity markets can be
overcome and the objectives of section
217(b)(4) of the FPA can be met through
the introduction of long-term firm
transmission rights. However, for a
variety of reasons that are discussed
below, transmission rights in organized
electricity markets cannot always be
designed in a way that captures all of
the features of the transmission rights
that have long been available under the
OATT. Consequently, the Commission’s
objective in issuing this NOPR is to
present a framework within which
transmission organizations and their
market participants can design and
implement long-term firm transmission
rights in the organized electricity
markets that are compatible with the
design of those markets, in particular
retaining the advantages of price-based
congestion management, and meet the
reasonable needs of market participants.
C. Staff Paper on Long-Term
Transmission Rights
34. Prior to the enactment of EPAct
2005, the Commission released a Staff
Paper that provided background and
solicited comments on whether longterm transmission rights were needed in
the ISO and RTO markets, and if so,
how to implement them.37 This section
provides an overview of the comments
to the notice.
35. With respect to the need for and
design of long-term transmission rights,
the views of the respondents tended to
fall into three general groups. The first
group consisted of advocates of longterm transmission rights with terms in
37 Notice Inviting Comments on Establishing
Long-Term Transmission Rights in Markets With
Locational Pricing and Staff Paper, Long-Term
Transmission Rights Assessment, Docket No.
AD05–7–000 (May 11, 2005) (Staff Paper). While we
are issuing this NOPR in both Docket No. RM06–
8–000 and Docket No. AD05–7–000, we expect to
issue our Final Rule in only Docket No. RM06–8–
000. Comments in response to this NOPR should be
filed in Docket No. RM06–8–000.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
the range of 5–30 years.38 These parties
argue that the failure of transmission
organizations to offer transmission
rights with terms greater than one year
is a key deficiency in the markets that
produces increased financial risk due to
congestion price uncertainty, the failure
of forward energy markets to form, and
barriers to investment in new generation
capacity. The core problem expressed
by these parties is that annual
allocations of rights may not provide
sufficient rights year-to-year to
adequately cover potentially volatile
congestion cost exposure. In turn, the
inability to secure a known quantity of
transmission rights for multiple years
introduces an unacceptable degree of
uncertainty into resource planning,
investment and contracting.
36. Most of the parties in this first
group stressed that not all transmission
capacity should be given over to longterm rights, but that there should be an
amount sufficient to cover at least baseload generation resources and perhaps
renewable energy generators.39 These
commenters argue that long-term rights
should be FTR obligations only under
certain conditions that limit financial
exposure of the rights holder. Several
proposed that the long-term rights
should be FTR options. Otherwise, the
rights could be physical rights 40 or
modified FTRs (e.g. financial rights with
physical characteristics, such as ‘‘useor-lose’’ rights) designed to alter the
financial settlement properties of
traditional FTRs so as to reduce
congestion risk.41
38 See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of the
American Public Power Association (APPA) at 1, 8,
19; Comments on Staff Paper of the Transmission
Access Policy Study Group (TAPS) at 19–21;
Comments on Staff Paper of the National Rural
Electric Cooperative Association (NRECA) at 17–19;
Comments on Staff Paper of the Electricity
Consumers Resource Council (ELCON) at 9–10.
39 See Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at 31;
Comments on Staff Paper of TAPS at 17–19.
However, other parties supportive of long-term
transmission rights argued that their allocation
should not be tied to particular classes of generator.
See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of ELCON at 8–
9.
40 See Comments on Staff Paper of Sacramento
Municipal Utility District (SMUD) at 12–16;
Comments on Staff Paper of City of Santa Clara,
California, Silicon Valley Power (SVP) at 14–18.
41 For example, a right that only provides a
financial hedge when the holder submits a physical
schedule (a type of ‘‘use or lose’’ right). See, e.g.,
Comments on Staff Paper of the Transmission
Access Policy Study Group (TAPS) at 21–25;
Comments on Staff Paper of the Electricity
Consumers Resource Council (ELCON) at 12–13.
Note also that several commenters argued that ISOs
with LMP and financial rights should not revert to
physical rights to provide long-term transmission
service, nor should they allow such ISOs to offer
combinations of physical and financial rights (with
the exception of already awarded grandfathered
rights). See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of
ABATE at 10–11; Comments on Staff Paper of
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
37. A second group of commenters
largely agreed with the first that longterm rights should be introduced, but
argued that this should take place
within the framework of existing FTR
market designs and follow a cautious,
incremental approach. These parties,
which included most of the ISOs and
RTOs that submitted comments as well
as many stakeholders, argued that rights
of greater than one year duration would
indeed find a role in the markets, but
that care was needed in the design of
the rights.42 Most of these parties were
supportive of straightforward extensions
of the current FTR market design to
include FTR obligations of longer terms,
although perhaps with modified
creditworthiness requirements and
other rule changes to reflect the
different risks embodied in such rights.
In general, they proposed terms for such
FTRs of between 2 to 5 years. They also
supported limiting the quantity of
system capability given over to longterm FTRs for at least an initial period.
38. Finally, some respondents felt that
long-term rights should not be
introduced at this time.43 These parties
argued that the current procedures for
annual allocations of FTRs with terms of
one year or less were well-established
and that transmission rights markets
were efficient and maturing around this
design. They were concerned that the
introduction of multi-year rights could
introduce inequity and inefficiency into
the organized electricity markets,
because they believe such rights will
reduce the availability of FTRs with
terms of one year or less that can be
used to hedge shorter-term transactions.
They also assert that introducing longAmerican Electric Power (AEP) at 3; Comments on
Staff Paper of Cinergy at 13–14; Comments on Staff
Paper of Edison Electric Institute (EEI) at 3;
Comments on Staff Paper of Electric Power Supply
Association (EPSA) at 6–8; Comments on Staff
Paper of FirstEnergy Solutions at 8; Comments on
Staff Paper of ISO/RTO Council at 2–3.
42 See generally Comments on Staff Paper of
California ISO; Comments on Staff Paper of ISO
New England; Comments on Staff Paper of New
York ISO; Comments on Staff Paper of PJM;
Comments on Staff Paper of ISO/RTO Council. See
also generally Comments on Staff Paper of New
York Public Service Commission (NY PSC) and the
Organization of Midwest States (OMS). On
appropriate term lengths, see Comments on Staff
Paper of Cinergy at 10; Comments on Staff Paper of
Coral Power at 3, 6; Comments on Staff Paper of DC
Energy at 4–5; Comments on Staff Paper of Edison
Electric Institute (EEI) at 10; Comments on Staff
Paper of Electric Power Supply Association (EPSA)
at 11; Comments on Staff Paper of Midwest
Transmission Owners at 11; Comments on Staff
Paper of Morgan Stanley at 7; Comments on Staff
Paper of National Grid at 15; Comments on Staff
Paper of Pacific Gas & Electric (PG&E) at 5.
43 See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of Cinergy
at 3; Comments on Staff Paper of Coral Power at 7.
However, many of these respondents did articulate
views on how long-term rights should be specified
in the event that the Commission required them.
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6699
term rights could cause cost shifts if
holders of long-term rights are given
congestion risk coverage greater than
that accorded to other parties. Some
respondents that supported this position
were from retail choice states, reflecting
concerns that long-term rights could
adversely affect their ability to acquire
and trade transmission rights used to
hedge shorter-term contracts.
39. In general, those responding to the
Staff Paper did not favor a uniform,
‘‘one size fits all’’ approach to long-term
rights. Instead, they stressed that the
development of long-term transmission
rights should take place in a regional
context, which would allow
stakeholders to balance the different
needs of transmission users and reflect
the characteristics of the regional grid
and generation resources. Also, those
responding provided suggestions on
many other aspects of long-term
transmission right design and
implementation. We will refer to those
suggestions where relevant in some of
the discussion that follows.
IV. Proposed Guidelines for Design and
Administration of Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights in Organized
Electricity Markets
A. The Commission’s Proposed
Approach
40. To satisfy the requirements of
section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005, and to
address the concerns expressed by
market participants, the Commission
proposes to establish a set of guidelines
for the design and administration of
long-term firm transmission rights in
organized electricity markets. The
Commission proposes to require each
transmission organization that is a
public utility with one or more
organized electricity markets 44 to file
with the Commission, within 180 days,
either proposed tariff sheets that make
available long-term firm transmission
rights that are consistent with the
guidelines, or an explanation of how the
transmission organization already
makes such rights available. The
proposed compliance procedures are
discussed in more detail below.
41. The Commission recognizes that
there may be many possible approaches
to fulfilling this requirement of EPAct
2005. Parties commenting on the Staff
Paper suggested a number of possible
approaches to designing and
implementing long-term transmission
rights. The Commission believes that
44 As noted elsewhere, this proposed rule would
apply whether the Organized Electricity Markets are
administered by the Transmission Organization
itself, or whether the Organized Electricity Markets
are administered by another entity.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
6700
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
establishing guidelines for the design
and administration of long-term firm
transmission rights in this rulemaking,
followed by development of specific
long-term firm transmission right
designs within the stakeholder process
of each Transmission Organization with
an organized electricity market, is the
most appropriate course for complying
with the directive of section 1233(b) of
EPAct 2005. We agree with many of
those commenting on the Staff Paper
that a ‘‘one size fits all’’ long-term firm
transmission right design is not
appropriate, and that long-term
transmission rights should be developed
through regional stakeholder
discussion.45
42. This flexible regional
development of long-term firm
transmission rights must, however,
occur within certain guidelines.
Accordingly, the Commission proposes
guidelines for the design and
administration of long-term firm
transmission rights that ensure that
those rights have certain properties that
we believe are fundamental to meeting
the objectives of section 217(b)(4) of the
FPA. For example, we propose below
that long-term firm transmission rights
be made available with terms (and/or
rights to renewal) that are sufficient to
meet the needs of load-serving entities
to hedge long-term power supply
arrangements made or planned to satisfy
a service obligation. Additionally, as
described in more detail in the
guidelines that follow, we propose that
transmission organizations be required
to award long-term firm transmission
rights to market participants that request
and support an expansion or upgrade to
the transmission system in accordance
with the transmission organization’s
prevailing rules for cost allocation. Such
long-term firm transmission rights must
be for a term equal to the life of the new
facilities, or for a lesser term if
requested by the funding entity. Also, as
described in more detail below, while
long-term firm transmission rights
should be made available to all
transmission customers, in the event
that a transmission organization cannot
accommodate all requests for long-term
firm transmission rights over existing
transmission capacity, we propose that
the approach most consistent with
section 217(b)(4) of the FPA is to require
that a preference be given to loadserving entities with long-term power
45 See,
e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at
23–24; Comments on Staff Paper of Association of
Businesses Advocating Tariff Equity (ABATE) and
Coalition of Midwest Transmission Customers at
11–12; Comments on Staff Paper of New York ISO
at 3–4; Comments on Staff Paper of New York
Transmission Organizations at 3–4.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
supply arrangements used to meet
service obligations.
43. While we believe these and the
other properties outlined in the
guidelines below are critical to the
successful implementation of long-term
rights, we intend for the guidelines to
form only a framework for further, more
specific development of long-term firm
transmission rights by each
transmission organization. Accordingly,
the guidelines should provide enough
flexibility to allow each region to
develop, through its usual stakeholder
process, a specific long-term firm
transmission right design that fits the
prevailing market design and best meets
the needs of market participants in that
region.
44. Although we propose to allow
regional flexibility in the development
of long-term firm transmission rights,
we recognize that allowing transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets to implement different rules for
these rights could lead to regional seams
issues. We seek comments on our
proposal to provide regional flexibility.
In particular, we ask commenters to
identify features of long-term firm
transmission rights that, if not
consistent across transmission
organizations, may interfere with the
effective operation of regional markets.
B. Proposed Guidelines
Guideline (1): The long-term firm
transmission right should be a point-to-point
right that specifies a source (injection node
or nodes) and sink (withdrawal node or
nodes), and a quantity (MW).
45. Section 217(b)(4) of the FPA
requires that long-term firm
transmission rights be available to
support long-term power supply
arrangements. Hence, we propose that
the transmission rights must be
specified such that they can hedge the
congestion costs that may be incurred in
delivering the output of particular
generation resources to particular
loads.46 The source nodes can
correspond to a single generator or a set
of generators (e.g., a zone). Similarly,
the sink nodes can specify a single node
or set of nodes.47 This guideline is not
46 APPA states that, because ISO–NE offers only
general system-wide ARRs, there is no direct
relationship between the ARRs that a market
participant receives and the FTRs that the market
participant may desire, given the location of its
resources. See Comments on Staff Paper of APPA,
attached Concept Paper—Long-Term Transmission
Rights, at 16, n. 22.
47 It is thus possible to define a form of network
service that consists of a set of point-to-point rights,
each of which specifies a source, a sink and a
megawatt quantity. This, however, would differ
from network service under the OATT, which does
not require the customer to reserve a specific
PO 00000
Frm 00020
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
intended to preclude flowgate rights so
long as they are designed with the same
hedging properties as an equivalent
long-term point-to-point right.
46. Section 217(b)(4) recognizes that
there may be alternative designs for
long-term firm transmission rights.48
For many transmission organizations
and their market participants, the most
straightforward method to develop longterm firm transmission rights would be
to extend the term of the auction
revenue rights or FTRs that they
currently allocate. These may require
additional market rules, such as
modified creditworthiness standards.
However, we do not preclude
alternative designs for long-term rights.
Some possible designs are compared in
Section IV.C of this NOPR.
Guideline (2): The long-term firm
transmission right must provide a hedge
against locational marginal pricing
congestion charges (or other direct
assignment of congestion costs) for the period
covered and quantity specified. Once
allocated, the financial coverage provided by
the right should not be modified during its
term except in the case of extraordinary
circumstances or through voluntary
agreement of both the holder of the right and
the transmission organization.
47. In most existing organized
electricity markets, LMP is used to
manage congestion. The FTRs currently
offered in the organized electricity
markets provide a hedge against these
charges, but are only offered in terms of
one year or less. Because of this short
term, market participants with longterm power supply arrangements are at
risk of having the ARRs or FTRs that
they are eligible for to hedge congestion
charges associated with delivery of that
power prorated during the course of the
power supply arrangement. As noted
above, one criticism of the current FTR
market rules is that the annual FTR
allocation may produce different results
from year to year in the quantity of FTRs
allocated to eligible load-serving
entities. APPA, for example, argues that
there is a need for a mechanism to keep
long-term firm transmission rights
feasible in the ‘‘out’’ years.49
48. To address this concern, we
propose that the transmission
organization ensure that the long-term
firm transmission rights it offers provide
a hedge against congestion costs for the
entire term of the right, and for the
amount of capacity between its network resources
and network loads.
48 In particular, that provision states that the
Commission shall exercise its authority ‘‘to enable
load-serving entities to secure firm transmission (or
equivalent tradable or financial rights) on a longterm basis’’ (emphasis added).
49 Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at 21.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
entire quantity of the right. In proposing
that the financial coverage offered by
the long-term rights, once awarded, not
be modified, we seek to establish rights
that provide a high degree of stability in
terms of payments from year to year,
rather than subject to uncertainty over
the possibility of significant prorationing in the event of revenue
inadequacy. We interpret the intent of
section 217(b)(4) of the FPA to be that
the Commission ensure the availability
in organized electricity markets of longterm firm transmission rights that
provide price stability to load-serving
entities with long-term power supply
arrangements used to satisfy their
service obligations.
49. When conditions arise that cause
the transmission organization to receive
congestion revenues that are not
sufficient to meet payment obligations
to FTR holders, the transmission
organization must have in place a
mechanism to fully fund the rights by
collecting the needed revenues from a
set of market participants. We will not
specify here how that funding should be
allocated among market participants,
which is a subject for stakeholder
discussion, but note that ideally the
rules for funding of the rights should be
designed to create and improve
incentives for the maintenance and
expansion of the transmission system
that is needed to ensure the feasibility
of the long-term rights that are allocated.
This might be accomplished, for
example, by placing the entities that are
ultimately responsible for system
maintenance and expansion at risk
(wholly or partially) for funding revenue
shortfalls that are due to inadequate
maintenance or expansion practices.
The transmission organization might
also define rules for transmission
upgrades and expansion to support the
feasibility of long-term rights.50 The
Commission seeks comments on
funding revenue shortfalls related to the
provision of long-term firm transmission
rights, particularly with regard to how
any necessary charges should be
allocated. Should such charges be
allocated to a transmission owner that is
responsible for maintaining and
expanding the capacity supporting the
long-term firm transmission rights
where the revenue shortfalls are due to
inadequate maintenance or expansion?
Are there appropriate methods for
allocating such charges that also provide
appropriate short-term and long-term
incentives for transmission usage,
maintenance and expansion?
50. Also, there may be extraordinary
circumstances under which the
50 We
discuss this issue in Section V, infra.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
requirement for full funding should be
relaxed. For example, one such
extraordinary circumstance may be a
sustained, unplanned outage of a large
transmission line. Such circumstances
may require alternative rules for sharing
of congestion cost risk than would
otherwise apply.
Guideline (3): Long-term firm transmission
rights made feasible by transmission
upgrades or expansions must be available
upon request to any party that pays for such
upgrades or expansions in accordance with
the transmission organization’s prevailing
cost allocation methods for upgrades or
expansions. The term of the rights should be
equal to the life of the facility (or facilities)
or a lesser term requested by the party paying
for the upgrade or expansion.
51. Most transmission organizations
today allow entities that pay for network
upgrades or expansions to receive the
long-term firm transmission rights that
would not be feasible but for those
expansions. The Commission believes
that this policy is fair to both new and
existing users of the transmission
system, promotes efficient capacity
expansions by allowing users that fund
the expansions to compare directly any
congestion cost savings with the cost of
the necessary upgrades, and provides
the long-term hedge against congestion
costs desired by transmission customers
wishing to enter into long-term power
supply arrangements. We note that the
pro forma OATT adopted by the
Commission in Order No. 888 requires
public utility transmission providers to
expand capacity, if necessary, to satisfy
the needs of transmission customers.51
Accordingly, the tariffs of transmission
organizations must clearly and
specifically provide for the award of
long-term firm transmission rights (as
described in this proposed rule) to
entities that support an expansion or
upgrade in accordance with the
transmission organization’s prevailing
cost responsibility or allocation rules.
The long-term firm transmission rights
would be equal to the amount of transfer
capability created by the expansion or
upgrade. We propose that such rights be
for a term equal to the life of the facility
(or facilities), or for a lesser term if
requested by the funding party.
52. An issue that arises in this context
concerns the possibility that granting a
long-term firm transmission right that
uses expanded capacity may encumber
some existing transmission capacity as
well. Given the integrated nature of the
grid, any point-to-point transmission
right made possible by a capacity
expansion is likely to require use of at
51 See pro forma OATT at sections 13.5, 15.4 and
28.2.
PO 00000
Frm 00021
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6701
least some existing transfer capability in
order for the right to be feasible. If the
entity that has funded a capacity
expansion does not have a priority to
obtain long-term rights to existing
capacity as proposed in guideline (5) in
this NOPR,52 the transmission
organization must propose a procedure
by which such an entity can obtain
rights to existing capacity when such
rights are needed to make the
incremental expansion rights feasible.
We ask for comment on the appropriate
rules in such cases.
Guideline (4): Long-term firm transmission
rights must be made available with term
lengths (and/or rights to renewal) that are
sufficient to meet the needs of load-serving
entities to hedge long-term power supply
arrangements made or planned to satisfy a
service obligation. The length of term of
renewals may be different from the original
term.
53. The Commission proposes to
require each transmission organization
to make long-term firm transmission
rights available to market participants.
Doing so is consistent with section
217(b)(4) of the FPA, which requires
that load-serving entities be able to
secure firm transmission rights on a
long-term basis to support long-term
power supply arrangements made or
planned to meet a service obligation.
This requirement raises a number of
issues. First, we note that the FPA (and
EPAct 2005) do not define ‘‘long-term.’’
Commenters on the Staff Paper
expressed a wide range of views on the
appropriate term for long-term
transmission rights. Some commenters
prefer to proceed cautiously, suggesting
that a two year FTR obligation would be
a reasonable, conservative starting point
for implementation of long-term
rights.53 A number of commenters also
support initial experimentation with
shorter term FTRs, but are willing to
consider longer terms, typically up to
three to five years.54
54. Other commenters argued that the
initial assignment of long-term rights
should consider much longer timeframes, on the order of decades. For
example, NRECA argues that the term of
the rights should be matched to the RTO
planning process, which is typically 5
or 10 years.55 TAPS argues that longterm rights consistent with its
specifications should be made available
for 10 year terms with the unconditional
52 See
infra at P 58–61.
e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of California
ISO at 5; Comments on Staff Paper of New York
Public Service Commission at 3.
54 See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of Cinergy
at 10; Comments on Staff Paper of Edison Electric
Institute at 10.
55 See Comments on Staff Paper of NRECA at 18.
53 See,
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
6702
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
right to renew.56 APPA states that a
party making an investment in a
generation asset should be able to obtain
a long-term right for the duration of the
financing terms, which could be 20 to
30 years, or even for the duration of the
asset’s operating life. APPA notes that
there should be flexibility in the term of
the long-term right, but that perhaps
there should be a minimum term that
matches the transmission organization’s
planning and construction horizon.57
55. The Commission believes that it is
reasonable to allow transmission
organizations to individually develop
and propose the terms of the long-term
firm transmission rights they offer.58
However, we consider long-term, for
purposes of this rulemaking, to mean
terms on the order of multiple years,
sufficient to meet the needs of loadserving entities with service
obligations.59 The Commission’s
primary concern here is to be responsive
to the needs of load-serving entities,
other market participants, and the
requirements of section 217(b)(4) of the
FPA. In particular, our goal is to ensure
that long-term firm transmission rights
are available for those who wish to
obtain a more stable, long-term firm
transmission right to meet their service
obligations, and for those who need
longer-term transmission rights to
finance investments in new generation
or long-term power purchase contracts.
To achieve this goal, we propose this
guideline, which would require that the
specific rights proposed by each
transmission organization in
compliance with this rulemaking have
term lengths (and/or rights to renewal)
that are sufficient to meet the needs of
transmission customers to hedge longterm power supply arrangements made
or planned to satisfy a service
obligation. Because market participants
in different transmission organizations
may have different needs, we decline to
propose a specific term length or set of
term lengths. New section 217(b)(4) of
the FPA makes clear, however, that
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets must meet
the needs for long-term firm
transmission service of load-serving
entities with long-term power supply
56 See
Comments on Staff Paper of TAPS at 19–
21.
57 See
Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at 33.
expect that transmission organizations will
develop their proposals in consultation with
stakeholders.
59 Defining long-term in this manner, for purposes
of this proposed rule, differs from our previous
practice of defining long-term as ‘‘one year or
more.’’ We propose defining long-term differently
in this context because the transmission
organizations subject to this rulemaking already
provide transmission rights with a term of one year.
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
58 We
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
arrangements made, or planned, to meet
their service obligations. Hence, this
guideline would require that
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets offer longterm firm transmission rights with terms
that meet such needs. The Commission
expects that multiple-year terms will be
necessary to ensure that the rights will
support the financing of new generation
investments or power purchase
contracts.60 Our view of long-term as
terms of multiple years is intended to
provide a range to allow transmission
organizations the flexibility to
individually develop and propose term
lengths, subject to review by the
Commission to ensure that the terms
each transmission organization proposes
meet the goals described above and
expressed by Congress in section
217(b)(4) of the FPA.
56. We seek comments regarding the
length of terms of long-term firm
transmission rights. For example, we
seek comments on whether regional
flexibility is needed on the length of
term, or whether a more specific set of
terms should be included in the Final
Rule. Further, we note that the issue of
term length is linked to the length of the
transmission organization’s
transmission planning and expansion
cycle. As a result, we seek comments on
how longer-term long-term firm
transmission rights (i.e. 20 to 30 years)
relate to the transmission organization’s
planning cycle, how such longer-term
rights can be guaranteed beyond the
length of the planning cycle, and
whether the planning cycles of
transmission organization’s must be
modified or extended to accommodate
terms that are sufficient to meet the
needs of load-serving entities to hedge
long-term power supply arrangements
made or planned to satisfy a service
obligation.61
57. With regard to rights to renew
long-term firm transmission rights, the
transmission organization may propose
reasonable criteria regarding the
availability of renewal rights, and the
price at which rights may be renewed.
For example, the right to renew longterm firm transmission rights may be
limited to a load-serving entity that can
demonstrate that the renewal right is
needed to allow the load-serving entity
to match the term of its transmission
rights to the term of a particular longterm power supply arrangement. In
addition, the transmission organization
60 The ability to renew the long-term firm
transmission rights will also help ensure that term
lengths will be appropriate.
61 This NOPR also explores transmission
planning and expansion in Section V, infra.
PO 00000
Frm 00022
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
may require minimum notice periods
for initiation, renewal, cancellation or
conversion that accommodate the
transmission organization’s planning
cycle or other administrative
considerations. We seek comments on
the relationship between the right to
renew a long-term firm transmission
right and transmission system planning.
Guideline (5): Load-serving entities with
long-term power supply arrangements to
meet a service obligation must have priority
to existing transmission capacity that
supports long-term firm transmission rights
requested to hedge such arrangements.
58. When finalized, this rulemaking
will require that transmission
organizations with organized electricity
markets make long-term firm
transmission rights available to
transmission customers. As noted
above, section 217(b)(4) of the FPA
requires the Commission to exercise its
authority to enable ‘‘load-serving
entities to secure firm transmission
rights (or equivalent tradable or
financial rights) on a long-term basis for
long-term power supply arrangements
made, or planned, to meet such needs.’’
As we discuss elsewhere in this NOPR,
in regions where existing transmission
capacity is limited, transmission
organizations may not be able to
accommodate all requests for long-term
firm transmission rights. While section
217 does not require that long-term firm
transmission rights be made available
only to load-serving entities with
service obligations, we interpret that
section to require the Commission to
give load-serving entities with long-term
power supply arrangements to satisfy a
service obligation a preference in
securing long-term firm transmission
rights. In accordance with this
interpretation, if there is a conflict
(infeasibility) in awarding long-term
rights from existing capacity (or
capacity created by incremental
reliability upgrades) to all parties
eligible to receive them, we propose to
require the transmission organizations
to address this infeasibility by first
giving load-serving entities with longterm power supply arrangements used
to meet service obligations priority in
the allocation of the rights.
59. When rights requested by eligible
parties with priority (or parties without
priority that are being accommodated)
are not simultaneously feasible given
existing transmission capacity, the
transmission organization may adopt
methods to allocate the requested rights
to the parties prior to granting such
rights. We seek comments on such
methods and whether and to what
extent it may be appropriate to allow
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
transmission organizations to adopt
limits on the amount of capacity they
will allocate to long-term rights before
such rights are allocated. In particular,
we seek comments on whether section
1233 of EPAct 2005 and new section
217(b)(4) of the FPA, read in their
entirety, support such reasonable limits.
Section 217(b)(4) states that the
Commission must exercise its authority
to meet the ‘‘reasonable needs’’ of loadserving entities to satisfy their service
obligations. Additionally, that section
requires that the Commission enable
load-serving entities to secure long-term
firm transmission rights for ‘‘power
supply arrangements made, or
planned,’’ to meet their service
obligations.
60. In making available long term firm
transmission rights for power supply
arrangements ‘‘made or planned’’ to
meet service obligations, transmission
organizations may have to incorporate
estimates of load growth into the award
of such rights. This raises the concern
that to the extent that the load growth
assumptions made by load-serving
entities as a basis for nominating
transmission rights are overstated, some
load serving entities could be awarded
more long-term firm transmission rights
than needed to meet service obligations,
and the associated transmission
capacity would not be available for
allocation of transmission rights to
others. The Commission seeks comment
on this issue and any rules or other
safeguards that address it.
61. We also seek comments on the
other issues raised by this guideline.
Particularly, we seek comment on how
the transmission organization should
allocate long-term firm transmission
rights from existing capacity in light of
the priority we propose in this
guideline.
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
Guideline (6): A long-term transmission
right held by a load-serving entity to support
a service obligation should be re-assignable
to another entity that acquires that service
obligation.
62. The Commission believes that in
general, it is appropriate to require that
long-term firm transmission rights, once
allocated to or obtained by a loadserving entity, be reassignable to a
successor load-serving entity which, in
turn, would assume any cost
responsibility that holding the rights
entails. This proposal is consistent with
section 217(b)(3)(A) of the FPA, which
requires that transmission rights held by
a load-serving entity as of the date of
enactment of EPAct 2005 for the
purpose of delivering energy it has
purchased or generated to meet a service
obligation be transferred to a successor
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
6703
load-serving entity.62 Specifically,
section 217(b)(3)(A) provides:
require recipients to participate in an
auction.
To the extent that all or a portion of the
service obligation covered by the firm
transmission rights or equivalent tradable or
financial transmission rights is transferred to
another load-serving entity, the successor
load-serving entity shall be entitled to use the
firm transmission rights or equivalent
tradable or financial transmission rights
associated with the transferred service
obligation.
64. As is currently done in most
transmission organization markets, the
first stage in awarding transmission
rights is to allocate the rights directly to
eligible parties or to allocate auction
revenue rights directly and
subsequently conduct an auction for
transmission rights (in which parties
with and without allocated rights can
participate). If an auction model is
adopted or continued by the
transmission organization, we will
require that any long-term rights
allocated as auction revenue rights can
be directly converted to transmission
rights without participation in the
auction.63 This allows any party that
feels uncertain about valuing its rights
commercially to de facto have them
allocated directly. This guideline does
not preclude interested parties with
long-term rights from participating in
the auction if they choose.
This guideline would apply when a
service obligation is transferred to a new
load-serving entity. Such a transfer of a
service obligation might occur pursuant
to a state commission order, or might
occur in a state with retail competition
if load chooses a new supplier. The
Commission seeks comments regarding
whether the reassignability we propose
to require in this guideline, consistent
with section 217, should apply to all
long-term firm transmission rights,
regardless of how those rights were
obtained. For example, what, if any,
compensation should a holder of longterm rights receive when its rights are
reassigned to a successor load-serving
entity?
63. Section 217(b)(4) of the FPA does
not discuss whether long-term firm
transmission rights should be fully
tradable among market participants.
Allowing such rights to be fully tradable
could raise issues of equity, since a
load-serving entity who acquired the
rights through the preference we
propose in this rulemaking could then
possibly sell or trade the rights at a
profit. This might give load-serving
entities the incentive to acquire excess
long-term firm transmission rights in
order to take advantage of profit
opportunities through arbitrage.
However, full tradability may bring
benefits to the market, and allow those
who could not obtain long-term rights in
the initial allocation to obtain such
rights later. We seek comment on these
issues. Particularly, we seek comment
on whether the equity issues we note
above could be addressed by only
permitting holders of long-term firm
transmission rights to return their rights
to the transmission organization at the
price paid, or whether these issues
could be addressed in some other
manner.
Guideline (7): The initial allocation of the
long-term firm transmission rights shall not
62 We
note that the short-term transmission rights
currently offered by transmission organizations are
generally reassignable to successor load-serving
entities, consistent with this statutory language.
See, e.g., PJM Manual 06, Financial Transmission
Rights (Revision 7, effective April 15, 2005), at
https://www.pjm.com/contributions/pjm-manuals/
pdf/m06v071.pdf.
PO 00000
Frm 00023
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
Guideline (8): Allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights should balance any
adverse economic impact between
participants receiving and not receiving the
right.
65. The provision of long-term firm
transmission rights may have adverse
impacts on markets participants not
receiving such rights. For example, to
the extent that the capacity of the
transmission system is encumbered by
entities holding long-term firm
transmission rights, entities that prefer
to hold short-term transmission rights,
such as load-serving entities operating
in retail states,64 will have fewer rights
available to them than they have under
annual allocation schemes that are now
used. In addition, to the extent awarded
long-term rights become infeasible due
to major unforeseen changes in the
physical properties of the transmission
system, the payment obligations to
holders of long-term firm transmission
rights would have to be funded by
others.
66. Although some of these impacts
may be unavoidable, the Commission
believes, in general, that it is possible
for a transmission organization to
introduce long-term firm transmission
rights in a way that balances their
economic impact between those
receiving and not receiving the rights.
For example, the transmission
63 For example, under the rules for allocation of
transmission rights on file for PJM, awarded ARRs
can be directly converted to FTRs in the subsequent
annual auction without submission of price offers.
64 Because load-serving entities in retail access
states may prefer a business model that is based
upon having only short-term supply arrangements,
they may prefer to hold only short-term
transmission rights.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
6704
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
organization could place a limit on the
amount of system capacity that is
available to support long-term rights.
This would reduce the likelihood that
the rights may become infeasible due to
major unforeseen changes in physical
properties of the transmission system,
which in turn would reduce the
possibility that the burden of funding
the allocated rights would eventually
fall onto other market participants. The
Commission seeks comment on this
issue.
67. Second, to the extent that the
long-term right relieves the holder of the
obligation to pay congestion costs, the
value of that congestion hedge should
be reflected in the price of the long-term
right, insofar as possible. For example,
where FTR options are offered to
provide a better congestion hedge, and
the FTR option encumbers more system
capacity than an FTR obligation, the
load-serving entity that requests such a
right could be required to assume
greater cost responsibility than it would
if it received an FTR obligation. The
additional payment may, for example,
be in the form of a requirement to pay
a larger share of the transmission
revenue requirement.
68. Third, the transmission
organization might provide for a
secondary market or auction by which
long-term rights holders can offer their
rights for sale or reconfigure their rights,
subject to any restrictions on trading
that may be deemed necessary. This
would provide an opportunity for
transmission customers to obtain longterm rights on either a long-term or
short term basis from those holding
long-term rights. However, as we noted
above in our discussion of guideline (6),
allowing this kind of tradability could
raise equity issues and could give loadserving entities with a preference the
incentive to acquire excess long-term
rights and later sell them at a profit.65
We seek comment on these issues.
69. Finally, with regard to the pricing
of long-term rights in general, the
Commission proposes not to prescribe a
specific methodology, whether the
rights are available from existing
capacity or require capacity expansion.
In particular, the Commission does not
propose to require a rolled-in pricing
policy for long-term firm transmission
rights. Rather, consistent with current
policy, the Commission proposes to
allow the transmission organization
flexibility to propose methods for
pricing transmission rights and related
services that are appropriate for its
region and are the product of a
stakeholder process.
65 See
supra at P 63.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
70. We seek comment on ways that
transmission organizations may balance
any adverse economic impacts of
allocating long-term firm transmission
rights between participants receiving
and not receiving such rights. We also
seek comment on any measures that
should be adopted to protect against
actions by long-term firm transmission
rights holders. For example, a holder of
a long-term firm transmission obligation
type of right may leave the transmission
organization. The allocation of other
transmission rights may have depended
on that holder’s counterflows on the
grid or its payments to fulfill its
obligation to the transmission
organization. Are measures needed to
address this situation?
C. Alternative Designs
71. The guidelines above are
sufficiently general to allow for a range
of proposals for the design of long-term
firm transmission rights. To assist
parties in formulating those proposals,
we discuss three alternative designs that
are possible under the guidelines: longterm ARR or FTR obligations, FTR
options, and rights with modifications
of FTR settlement or physical
scheduling requirements, such as ‘‘use
or lose’’ rights. Consistent with
proposed Guideline (7), we expect that
the first step under any proposed design
will be a direct allocation, rather than
an auction (followed possibly by
voluntary participation in an auction).
The prevailing design for initial
allocation of ARRs or FTRs has been to
assign obligation rights. At the
Commission’s urging and in response to
market interest, in at least one current
market (PJM), ARRs can subsequently be
used to purchase FTR options as well as
obligations through an FTR auction.
1. Long-Term ARR or FTR Obligations
72. We begin with the advantages and
disadvantages of the prevailing designs
for transmission rights in current
organized electricity markets. As noted
above, allocated transmission rights,
whether as ARRs or FTRs, are modeled
as obligation rights. The major
advantage of obligations is that they
allow the transmission organization to
maximize the coverage of the allocated
point-to-point transmission rights made
available to eligible parties. As
explained above, in the modeling of the
transmission system power flows that
supports the initial allocation,
obligation rights are represented under
the assumption that the counterflows
associated with injections and
withdrawals will be present. This limits
the need to ‘‘pro-ration’’ eligible
transmission rights, although most
PO 00000
Frm 00024
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
transmission organizations have rules
for how such pro-rationing will occur if
necessary (e.g., by having stages of the
allocation with higher priority given to
rights nominated in early stages).
73. In existing systems that directly
allocate FTR obligations, allocating
multi-year FTRs could be a fairly
straightforward extension of the existing
market design, with the need for
additional rules to cover the additional
risks of a multi-year financial
instrument that could entail payment
obligations, such as creditworthiness
requirements.
74. In systems that directly allocate
ARRs, the rules would be slightly
different. A long-term ARR obligation
would mean that for the term defined in
the right, the load-serving entity would
receive the right to auction revenues
associated with a fixed quantity of
injections and withdrawals in the FTR
auction. The load-serving entity could
then either directly convert the ARRs to
FTR obligations on an annual basis or it
can use the expected revenues to
purchase FTRs of greater than one year
based on the assumption that its ARR
revenue eligibility will be fixed for
multiple years (or it could choose not to
purchase long-term FTRs but simply
collect auction revenues each year). In
contrast, under a direct allocation of
long-term FTR obligations, the party
with the rights will hold the rights for
the term specified. Hence, a design that
provides ARR obligations on a long-term
basis will be somewhat more flexible
than the allocation directly of FTRs,
because it gives the parties the choice of
purchasing a fixed quantity of FTRs
annually or holding a longer-term FTR
obligation. Thus, the directly allocated
long-term ARR obligation gives a similar
degree of financial certainty as the
directly allocated long-term FTR
obligation, but more flexibility to
change actual holdings of FTRs from
year to year.
75. On the other hand, under some
conditions, obligations of either type—
ARR or FTR—may not provide the price
certainty desired in a long-term firm
transmission right. Transmission system
conditions change over time—including
resource ownership and perhaps load—
such that the long-term FTR obligation
may be difficult to manage financially
through physical scheduling. At times,
FTR obligations may become a financial
liability, as noted above. ARR
obligations can also become negative
sources of income—a negative ARR
would require the holder to pay the
auction rather than collect revenues
from it. It is these properties that have
stimulated interest in other types of
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
rights without the likelihood of negative
payment obligations.
76. Before turning to alternative
rights, we note that there could be
market rules that, while not turning
obligations into options, reduce the
extent of the exposure to potential longterm payment obligations. As an
example, long-term FTR obligations are
currently awarded for incremental
transmission expansions, and such
rights also have potential negative
payment obligations. Because parties
that build transmission may not own
generation with which to manage such
FTR payment risk (e.g., merchant
transmission operators), some organized
electricity market rules (e.g., PJM)
currently allow for such long-term
incremental rights to be ‘‘turned back’’
to the transmission organization without
penalty at the end of each annual
allocation cycle, thus creating an
option-like feature. To the extent that
long-term incremental transmission
rights support only a limited reliance on
counterflow used by other parties in
subsequent allocations of rights, such a
rule may have no or limited financial
impact on other parties, but if the
transmission organization applied such
a rule to long-term obligation rights to
existing capacity, such a ‘‘turn back’’
rule could have more substantial
financial implications—that is, require
uplift charges—in some circumstances.
This is a ‘‘socialization’’ of risk decision
that is best made by stakeholders in
tandem with other such decisions, such
as how many long-term rights to
allocate. Such socialization may assist
in developing rules for long-term ARR
or FTR obligations that have more
desirable properties for market
participants.
2. Long-Term FTR Options
77. For many parties seeking longterm rights (including long-term rights
obtained for transmission upgrades and
expansions), FTR option rights have
attractive financial properties. As noted
above, in contrast to the obligation right,
the FTR option payment is made only
when the congestion charge between the
points is positive. When the congestion
charge is negative, the FTR option
neither pays revenues nor requires
payment equal to the negative charge.
As such, the holder will never face
negative payment obligations.
78. The primary difficulty in
allocating long-term (or short-term) FTR
options is that because the counterflows
are not included when modeling for
revenue adequacy, the transmission
organization will be able to directly
allocate fewer FTR options to eligible
parties than it would be able to allocate
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
FTR obligations that assume
counterflows (see discussion next). This
increases the likelihood that the
transmission organization would not be
able to fulfill all requests for FTRs. The
potential shortfall in available FTRs
could be significant in some locations
and rules for equitable pro-rationing
could be difficult to develop.66 As a
result some parties would be exposed to
congestion charges for transmission
usage in excess of their FTR allocation.
79. The allocation issues posed by
long-term FTR options may be mitigated
in a number of ways. If parties
sufficiently desire the financial risk
characteristics and revenues associated
with FTR options, they may be willing
to accept pro-rationing with the
attendant possibility of congestion
charge exposure. Depending on grid
capability, it is possible that the
resulting exposure may be minimal.
Another possibility is that, if eligibility
requirements are restrictive, sufficiently
few long-term FTR options will be
allocated such that there is enough
transmission system capability to satisfy
the remaining needs for congestion
hedges through FTR obligations.
Another approach, similar to that
currently followed in PJM for annual
rights, is to assign long-term auction
revenue rights modeled as obligations,
and then let holders of such rights
decide whether to purchase long-term
FTR options or obligations in a
subsequent auction. This method
requires the party eligible for the longterm right to make financial decisions
up-front that it may prefer not to make,
however. Yet another policy option is to
make sufficient investments in
transmission expansion to make the
desired long-term FTR options feasible.
This course could be taken if the market
participants determine that such
investments are less expensive than any
congestion cost exposure or insurance
through uplift charges associated with
other transmission rights schemes, some
of which are discussed below.
3. Other Approaches to Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights
80. The features of long-term FTR
options and FTR obligations have
driven some parties to propose
alternative types of long-term
transmission rights, some having
financial settlement properties that are
different from current FTRs and others
combining physical and financial
66 The pro-rationing of FTR obligations has also
created conflict over the appropriate rules in some
organized markets, but the scale of the equity
problem in the case of FTR options could be much
greater.
PO 00000
Frm 00025
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6705
features.67 We review these alternative
approaches simply for illustrative
purposes.
81. Some transmission organizations
have implemented types of multi-year
transmission rights with combined
financial and physical properties to
solve certain transmission rights
allocation problems. For example, in the
Midwest ISO, parties with pre-Order
888 OATT rights were eligible for
Grandfathered Agreements (GFAs) that
exempted the holders from congestion
charges based on locational marginal
prices. Typically, such rights would be
accommodated in transmission rights
markets through physical set-asides or
‘‘carve-outs’’ that basically reserved
enough transmission capacity on an
‘‘option’’ basis (i.e., not considering
counterflows) to accommodate them.
However, in the Midwest ISO footprint,
there were enough of these eligible
GFAs so that treating them all in this
fashion would have greatly reduced the
allocation of FTRs to other parties and
possibly threatened the integrity of the
LMP energy markets and the FTR
allocation to other parties. One of the
interim solutions devised by the
Midwest ISO was to create the GFA
‘‘Option B’’ right.68 The Midwest ISO
models this right as an FTR obligation
in the FTR allocation process, thus
allowing it to capture the counterflows
associated with the rights. However,
instead of assigning the FTR obligation
to the eligible party, the Midwest ISO
holds the right for settlement purposes.
The GFA Option B holder is required to
schedule transmission in the day-ahead
market, upon which the congestion
revenues accumulated by the right are
used to ‘‘pay’’ its congestion charges;
the holder is not assessed negative
congestion charges (in most cases, the
holder of such a right would not
schedule power if LMPs were to create
negative congestion charges, but this
might not be foreseeable at all times).69
If there is a revenue inadequacy, the
Midwest ISO charges uplift to all market
participants on a pro-rata basis, based
on their load ratio share in the Midwest
ISO market. This is thus a type of useor-lose right that does not allow the
holder to accumulate revenues in excess
of congestion charges from transmission
rights but does not expose the holder to
negative congestion charges. However,
the allocation of such rights is based on
system-wide insurance, in the form of
67 See generally Comments on Staff Paper of
APPA; Comments on Staff Paper of TAPS.
68 See section 38.8.3(b), Midwest ISO Open
Access Transmission and Energy Markets Tariff
(TEMT), Second Revised Sheet No. 447.
69 Holders of GFA Option B rights are also
exempted from marginal loss charges.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
6706
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
uplift, to cover any resulting revenue
inadequacies.
82. Also in the Midwest ISO, the
Commission created a related type of
interim long-term congestion cost hedge
for parties in persistent load pockets
(called ‘‘Narrow Constrained Areas’’ or
NCAs) that previously had firm
transmission service that covered
generation resources or contracts
outside the load pocket.70 This is called
the ‘‘Expanded Congestion Cost Hedge.’’
The concern was that the FTR allocation
would not be sufficient to always cover
the quantities of transmission imports
covered by these parties’ prior
transmission rights, thus leaving them
potentially exposed to high congestion
charges (reflecting the expectation that
LMPs in a load pocket could be
substantially higher than LMPs outside
the load pocket). In this case, the
purpose of the right was to provide such
parties with a fixed quantity of
transmission service covered by a
congestion hedge, even if such rights
were not awarded through the FTR
allocation process (that is, were not
simultaneously feasible with all other
nominated FTRs).71 This right also
requires that the holder schedule
through the day-ahead market. Unlike
the Midwest ISO’s ‘‘Option B’’ GFA, this
arrangement does not protect the holder
from negative congestion charges
associated with its allocated FTRs, but
it does guarantee that the holder will
receive revenues from the Midwest ISO
sufficient to cover any positive
congestion charges not covered through
its allocated FTRs. If the Midwest ISO
experiences revenue inadequacy due to
these payments, it again charges uplift
to all market participants on a pro-rata
basis, based on their load ratio share in
the Midwest ISO market.
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
4. Combining Different Types of LongTerm Firm Transmission Rights
83. Most existing transmission
organizations do retain some quantity of
non-FTR transmission rights on their
transmission systems, typically
grandfathered pre-Order 888 OATT
rights that are treated as physical
scheduling rights. In most of these
markets, these physical transmission
rights do not require that a large amount
of transmission capability is reserved,
hence they do not greatly affect the
70 See section 43.2.6, Midwest ISO TEMT,
Substitute Second Revised Sheet No. 630.
71 This expanded hedge was made available as a
market start safeguard for five years from the start
of the market. Since only one region of the Midwest
ISO was designated as an NCA at the start of the
market, the hedge was also made available during
the safeguard period for parties in any area
subsequently designated as an NCA.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
allocation and trading of FTRs.
However, as noted above, the Midwest
ISO has had to accommodate a greater
number of such rights than other
transmission organizations and has
done so on an interim basis through
creation of alternative types of financial
rights or other arrangements. It has
sought to minimize the impact of such
rights on the FTR allocation and on the
exposure of market participants to
uplift.
84. In the event that stakeholders’
interests in different types of
transmission rights are difficult to
reconcile, transmission organizations
may need to consider the development
of different types of long-term rights
simultaneously. We believe that
regional stakeholder discussions are the
appropriate forum for such decisionmaking.
85. If the transmission organization
and stakeholders are considering more
than one type of transmission right, we
further encourage them to establish
mechanisms by which holders of one
kind of long-term firm transmission
right can convert their rights into other
rights with other characteristics offered
by the transmission organization that
rely on the same amount of transmission
capacity. For example, a long-term right
initially awarded as an obligation could
be subsequently converted to an option.
However, since more transmission
capacity may be necessary to support an
option than to support an obligation, the
holder may receive fewer options than
obligations.
V. Planning and Expansion of
Transmission Facilities
86. As noted above, section 217(b)(4)
of the FPA requires the Commission to
exercise its authority ‘‘in a manner that
facilitates the planning and expansion
of transmission facilities to meet the
reasonable needs of load-serving entities
to satisfy the service obligations of the
load-serving entities.’’ 72
87. Additionally, many of those
commenting on the Staff Paper argued
that implementation of long-term firm
transmission rights will not be possible
unless the transmission organization has
adequate transmission planning and
expansion procedures in place.73
According to some commenters, the
inadequacy of the physical transmission
system and the lack of a reliable
mechanism for transmission
organizations to plan and require the
72 Pub.
L. 109–58, § 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 958.
e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of NRECA
at 9–10; Comments on Staff Paper of Midwest TDUs
at 5; Comments on Staff Paper of ELCON at 3;
Comments on Staff Paper of National Grid at 1–2
and 9.
73 See,
PO 00000
Frm 00026
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
construction of transmission facilities
are the prime impediments to both
introducing long-term firm transmission
rights in the organized electricity
markets and ensuring that they remain
simultaneously feasible over their entire
term.74 Several of those providing
comments on the Staff Paper
recommended specific attributes that
should be included in transmission
organization planning and expansion
procedures.75 For example, TAPS
argues that transmission organizations
should have clear authority to mandate
the construction of transmission
facilities by transmission owners or
others.76 Also, commenters asserted that
transmission planning and expansion
procedures adopted by transmission
organizations should plan for
‘‘economic’’ upgrades as well as
upgrades needed for reliability.77
88. We propose in this NOPR to
require that transmission organizations
ensure that the long-term firm
transmission rights they offer remain
viable and are not modified or curtailed
over their entire term. In particular, the
proposed guidelines would require that
transmission organizations guarantee
the financial coverage of the long-term
firm transmission rights over their entire
term.78 Accordingly, transmission
organizations will need to have effective
planning and expansion regimes in
place, and may need to expand the
system where necessary to ensure that
the long-term firm transmission rights
can be accommodated over their entire
term without modification or
curtailment. Without appropriate
planning and expansion of the system
where necessary, it may be difficult to
ensure that long-term firm transmission
rights remain financially viable without
significant charges to some set of
participants.
89. While we agree in general with
those comments on the Staff Paper that
stress the necessity of tying the
availability of long-term firm
transmission rights to adequate
planning and expansion procedures, we
will not propose specific procedures in
this NOPR. The Commission believes
that each transmission organization and
its stakeholders should develop
appropriate methods for ensuring that
74 See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of NRECA
at 9; Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at 21–22.
75 See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of NRECA
at 11–13; Comments on Staff Paper of City of Santa
Clara, California at 18–19; Comments on Staff Paper
of APPA, attached Concept Paper; Comments on
Staff Paper of National Grid at 8–10.
76 Comments on Staff Paper of TAPS at 32.
77 See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of TAPS at
32; Comments on Staff Paper of NRECA at 12;
Comments on Staff Paper of National Grid at 10.
78 See discussion of guideline (2), supra.
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
long-term firm transmission rights are
supported by adequate planning and
expansion procedures. While we do not
propose specific requirements in this
regard, we expect that such planning
and expansion procedures will be a
necessary complement to long-term firm
transmission rights. The Commission
encourages transmission organizations
to propose such procedures as part of
their filings in compliance with the
Final Rule in this docket, and the
Commission will consider them in light
of the charge in section 217(b)(4) of the
FPA that we ‘‘facilitate * * * the
planning and expansion of transmission
facilities to meet the reasonable needs of
load-serving entities to satisfy the
service obligations of the load-serving
entities.’’ We seek additional comments
regarding the relationship between longterm firm transmission rights and
planning and expansion procedures in
the organized electricity markets
operated by transmission organizations.
In particular, we seek comment on
whether the Commission should require
that transmission organizations file their
transmission planning and expansion
procedures and specific plans. We also
seek comment on whether, alternatively,
the Commission should require that
transmission organizations file such
procedures for informational purposes,
as a means for the Commission to
monitor the adequacy of such plans and
procedures for ensuring the adequacy of
long-term firm transmission rights.
90. Additionally, we note that the pro
forma OATT adopted by the
Commission in Order No. 888 requires
public utility transmission providers to
expand capacity, if necessary, to satisfy
the needs of network transmission
customers and point-to-point
transmission service customers.79 In
comments submitted in response to the
Staff Paper, several entities suggested
that this obligation does not exist, or is
not carried out, in the organized
electricity markets operated by ISOs and
RTOs.80 The Commission’s recent
Notice of Inquiry concerning the pro
forma OATT sought responses from
interested parties on several specific
questions relating to this requirement in
the pro forma OATT, including: (1)
Whether this provision has met
transmission customers’ needs, and (2)
whether public utility transmission
providers have fulfilled these
79 See
pro forma OATT at sections 13.5, 15.4 and
28.2.
80 See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at
10; Comments on Staff Paper of ABATE and
Midwest Transmission Customers at 4–6;
Comments on Staff Paper of Peabody Energy
Corporation at 6.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
obligations.81 In this proceeding, the
Commission seeks comments addressing
these questions in the specific context of
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets that are
the subject of this rulemaking. Where
appropriate, responses should address
the arguments made in response to the
Staff Paper, and noted above,
concerning the obligation of
transmission providers to expand
capacity to meet the needs of network
and point-to-point transmission service
customers.
91. The Commission also emphasized
in the NOI that it is not proposing to
change the native load preference
established in Order No. 888.82 The
Commission sought comments,
however, on whether the definition of
native load service obligation in section
1233 of EPAct 2005 is the same as the
approach the Commission took in Order
No. 888.83 In this docket, the
Commission seeks comments on this
question with particular emphasis on
how the native load preference has been
applied in the organized electricity
markets that are the subject of this
rulemaking.
92. Finally, many of the comments
received on the Staff Paper stressed a
need for appropriate incentives for
transmission organizations,
transmission owners and market
participants to construct needed
upgrades and expansions to the
transmission system. As we discuss
above, the potential for additional
charges in ensuring that the financial
coverage of the long-term firm
transmission rights remains intact for
their entire term should provide an
incentive for planning and expanding
the transmission system. Additionally,
we note that in Docket No. RM06–4–
000, the Commission issued a NOPR
proposing amendments to the
Commission’s existing regulations to
promote reliable and economically
efficient transmission and generation of
electricity by providing incentives for
increased capital investment in
transmission facilities.84 The
Commission will consider the issues
surrounding appropriate incentives for
expansion of transmission facilities in
that rulemaking.
81 Preventing Undue Discrimination and
Preference in Transmission Services, Notice of
Inquiry, 112 FERC ¶ 61,299 at P 21 (2005) (NOI).
82 Id. at P 9.
83 Id.
84 See Promoting Transmission Investment
Through Pricing Reform, Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, 113 FERC ¶ 61,182 (2005).
PO 00000
Frm 00027
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6707
VI. Proposed Compliance Procedures
93. The Commission proposes to
direct each public utility that is a
transmission organization with an
organized electricity market, within 180
days of the publication of a Final Rule
in the Federal Register, to either: (1)
File with the Commission tariff sheets
and rate schedules that make available
long-term firm transmission rights that
are consistent with the guidelines set
forth in section (d) of the Final Rule; or
(2) file with the Commission an
explanation of how its current tariff and
rate schedules already provide for longterm firm transmission rights that are
consistent with the guidelines set forth
in paragraph (d) of the Final Rule. The
Commission intends that during this
180-day time period, such transmission
organizations will work with their
stakeholders to develop a long-term firm
transmission right that will harmonize
the prevailing market design with the
guidelines set forth in this Final Rule.
We do not propose any specific
stakeholder process, and intend that the
transmission organization will use its
usual process for receiving stakeholder
input and filing tariff changes with the
Commission. For any transmission
organization that is approved by the
Commission after the 180-day time
period, the Commission proposes that
the transmission organization satisfy the
requirements set forth in this rule before
commencing operation.
VII. Information Collection Statement
94. The Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) regulations require
approval of certain information
collection requirements imposed by
agency rules.85 Upon approval of a
collection(s) of information, OMB will
assign an OMB control number and an
expiration date. Respondents subject to
the filing requirements of this rule will
not be penalized for failing to respond
to these collections of information
unless the collections of information
display a valid OMB control number.
This NOPR amends the Commission’s
regulations to implement some of the
statutory provisions of section 1233 of
EPAct 2005. Particularly, section 1233
of EPAct 2005 enacts a new section 217
of the FPA. New section 217(b)(4)
requires the Commission to exercise its
authority in a manner that facilitates the
planning and expansion of transmission
facilities to meet the reasonable needs of
load-serving entities to satisfy their
service obligations, and enables loadserving entities to secure long-term firm
transmission rights to meet their service
85 5
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
CFR 1320.13 (2005).
09FEP1
6708
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
obligations. Section 1233(b) of EPAct
2005 directs that Commission to, by rule
or order, implement this new provision
in the FPA. This proposed rule would
require transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets to either
file tariff sheets making long-term firm
transmission rights available that are
consistent with guidelines established
by the Commission, or to make a filing
explaining how their existing tariffs
already provide long-term firm
transmission rights that are consistent
with the guidelines. Such filings would
be made under Part 35 of the
Commission’s regulations. The
information provided for under Part 35
is identified as FERC–516.
95. The Commission is submitting
these reporting requirements to OMB for
its review and approval under section
3507(d) of the Paperwork Reduction
Act.86 Comments are solicited on the
Commission’s need for this information,
whether the information will have
practical utility, the accuracy of
provided burden estimates, ways to
enhance the quality, utility, and clarity
of the information to be collected, and
any suggested methods for minimizing
the respondent’s burden, including the
use of automated information
techniques.
Burden Estimate: The Public
Reporting burden for the requirements
contained in the NOPR is as follows:
Number of
respondents
Number of
responses
Hours per
response
Total annual
hours
FERC–516—Transmission Organizations with Organized Electricity Markets
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
Data collection
6
1
1180
7,080
Total Annual Hours for Collection:
(Reporting + recordkeeping, (if
appropriate) = 7,080 hours.
Information Collection Costs: The
Commission seeks comments on the
costs to comply with these
requirements. It has projected the
average annualized cost to be the total
annual hours of 7,080 times $150 =
$1,062,000.
Title: FERC–516 ‘‘Electric Rate
Schedule Filings.’’
Action: Proposed Collections.
OMB Control No.: 1902–0096.
Respondents: Business or other for
profit, and/or not for profit institutions.
Frequency of Responses: One time to
initially comply with the rule, and then
on occasion as needed to revise or
modify.
Necessity of the Information: This
proposed rule, if adopted, would
implement the Congressional mandate
of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 to make
long-term transmission rights available
in transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets. This
mandate addresses an identified need
for transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets to provide
longer-term transmission rights that can
aid load-serving entities in financing
long-term power supply arrangements to
meet their service obligations. Making
long-term firm transmission rights
available will also provide increased
certainty regarding the long-term costs
of transmission service in organized
electricity markets. As a result, longterm firm transmission rights will allow
load-serving entities to more effectively
plan their power supply portfolios, and
encourage load-serving entities and
other participants in organized
electricity markets to make long-term
investments in power supply
arrangements.
86 44
U.S.C. 3507(d) (2000).
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
Internal review: The Commission has
reviewed the requirements pertaining to
transmission organizations with
organized electricity markets and
determined the proposed requirements
are necessary to meet the statutory
provisions of the Energy Policy Act of
2005.
96. These requirements conform to
the Commission’s plan for efficient
information collection, communication
and management within the energy
industry. The Commission has assured
itself, by means of internal review, that
there is specific, objective support for
the burden estimates associated with the
information requirements.
97. Interested persons may obtain
information on the reporting
requirements by contacting: Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission, 888
First Street, NE. Washington, DC 20426
[Attention: Michael Miller, Office of the
Executive Director, Phone: (202) 502–
8415, fax: (202) 273–0873, e-mail:
michael.miller@ferc.gov]. Comments on
the requirements of the proposed rule
may also be sent to the Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs,
Office of Management and Budget,
Washington, DC 20503 [Attention: Desk
Officer for the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission], e-mail:
oira_submission@omb.eop.gov.
VIII. Environmental Analysis
98. The Commission is required to
prepare an Environmental Assessment
or an Environmental Impact Statement
for any action that may have a
significant adverse effect on the human
environment.87 The Commission has
categorically excluded certain actions
from this requirement as not having a
significant effect on the human
environment. Included in the exclusion
87 Regulations Implementing the National
Environmental Policy Act, Order No. 486, 52 FR
47897 (Dec. 17, 1987), FERC Stats. & Regs.
Preambles 1986–1990 ¶ 30,783 (1987).
PO 00000
Frm 00028
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
are rules that do not substantially
change the effect of legislation.88 The
rule proposed in this NOPR falls within
this categorical exemption because it
implements the requirements of EPAct
2005 relating to long-term firm
transmission rights in organized
electricity markets. Accordingly, neither
an environmental impact statement nor
environmental assessment is required.
IX. Regulatory Flexibility Act
Certification
99. The Regulatory Flexibility Act of
1980 89 generally requires a description
and analysis of rules that will have
significant economic impact on a
substantial number of small entities.
Most, if not all, of the transmission
organizations to which the requirements
of this rule would apply do not fall
within the definition of small entities.90
Therefore, the Commission certifies that
this rule will not have a significant
economic impact on a substantial
number of small entities. Accordingly,
no regulatory flexibility analysis is
required.
X. Comment Procedures
100. The Commission invites
interested persons to submit comments
on the matters and issues proposed in
this notice to be adopted, including any
related matters or alternative proposals
that commenters may wish to discuss.
Comments are due March 13, 2006.
Reply comments are due March 27,
2006. Comments and reply comments
must refer to Docket No. RM06–8–000,91
88 18
CFR 380.4(2)(ii) (2005).
U.S.C. 601–12 (2000).
90 The RFA definition of ‘‘small entity’’ refers to
the definition provided in the Small Business Act,
which defines a ‘‘small business concern’’ as a
business that is independently owned and operated
and that is not dominant in its field of operation.
See 15 U.S.C. 632 (2000).
91 While we are issuing this NOPR in both Docket
No. RM06–8–000 and Docket No. AD05–7–000, we
expect to issue our Final Rule in only Docket No.
89 5
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
and must include the commenter’s
name, the organization they represent, if
applicable, and their address in their
comments. Comments and reply
comments may be filed either in
electronic or paper format.
101. Comments and reply comments
may be filed electronically via the
eFiling link on the Commission’s Web
site at https://www.ferc.gov. The
Commission accepts most standard
word processing formats and
commenters may attach additional files
with supporting information in certain
other file formats. Commenters filing
electronically do not need to make a
paper filing. Commenters that are not
able to file comments and reply
comments electronically must send an
original and 14 copies of their
comments to: Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, Office of the Secretary,
888 First Street, NE., Washington, DC,
20426.
102. All comments and reply
comments will be placed in the
Commission’s public files and may be
viewed, printed, or downloaded
remotely as described in the Document
Availability section below. Commenters
on this proposal are not required to
serve copies of their comments and
reply comments on other commenters.
8371, TTY (202) 502–8659 (e-mail at
public.referenceroom@ferc.gov).
XI. Document Availability
103. In addition to publishing the full
text of this document in the Federal
Register, the Commission provides all
interested persons an opportunity to
view and/or print the contents of this
document via the Internet through the
Commission’s Home Page (https://
www.ferc.gov) and in the Commission’s
Public Reference Room during normal
business hours (8:30 a.m. to 5 p.m.
eastern time) at 888 First Street, NE.,
Room 2A, Washington, DC 20426.
104. From the Commission’s Home
Page on the Internet, this information is
available in the Commission’s document
management system, eLibrary. The full
text of this document is available on
eLibrary in PDF and Microsoft Word
format for viewing, printing, and/or
downloading. To access this document
in eLibrary, type the docket number
excluding the last three digits of this
document in the docket number field.
105. User assistance is available for
eLibrary and the Commission’s Web site
during normal business hours. For
assistance, please contact FERC Online
Support at 1–866–208–3676 (toll free) or
(202) 502–8222 (e-mail at
FERCOnlineSupport@FERC.gov), or the
Public Reference Room at (202) 502–
(a) Purpose. This section requires a
transmission organization with one or
more organized electricity markets
(administered either by it or by another
entity) to make available long-term firm
transmission rights, pursuant to section
217(b)(4) of the Federal Power Act, that
satisfy the guidelines set forth in
paragraph (d) of this section. This
section does not require that a specific
type of long-term firm transmission
right be made available, and is intended
to permit transmission organizations
flexibility in satisfying the guidelines
set forth in paragraph (d) of this section.
(b) Definitions. As used in this
section:
(1) Transmission Organization means
a Regional Transmission Organization,
Independent System Operator,
independent transmission provider, or
other independent transmission
organization finally approved by the
Commission for the operation of
transmission facilities.
(2) Load-serving entity means a
distribution utility or an electric utility
that has a service obligation.
(3) Service obligation means a
requirement applicable to, or the
exercise of authority granted to, an
electric utility under Federal, State, or
local law or under long-term contracts
to provide electric service to end-users
or to a distribution utility.
RM06–8–000. Comments in response to this NOPR
should be filed in Docket No. RM06–8–000 only.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
List of Subjects in 18 CFR Part 40
Electric power rates; Electric utilities.
By direction of the Commission.
Magalie R. Salas,
Secretary.
In consideration of the foregoing, the
Commission proposes to amend
Subchapter B, Chapter I, Title 18, Code
of Federal Regulations, by adding a new
Part 40 as follows:
*
*
*
*
*
Subchapter B—Regulations Under the
Federal Power Act
*
*
*
*
*
PART 40—LONG–TERM FIRM
TRANSMISSION RIGHTS IN
ORGANIZED ELECTRICITY MARKETS
Sec.
40.1
Requirement that Transmission
Organizations with Organized Electricity
Markets offer Long-Term Transmission
Rights
Authority: 16 U.S.C. 791a–825r and section
217 of the Federal Power Act.
§ 40.1 Requirement that Transmission
Organizations with Organized Electricity
Markets Offer Long-Term Transmission
Rights.
PO 00000
Frm 00029
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
6709
(4) Organized Electricity Market
means an auction-based market where a
single entity receives offers to sell and
bids to buy electric energy and/or
ancillary services from multiple sellers
and buyers and determines which sales
and purchases are completed and at
what prices, based on formal rules
contained in Commission-approved
tariffs, and where the prices are used by
a transmission organization for
establishing transmission usage charges.
(5) Long-term power supply
arrangements means the ownership of
generation facilities, rights to market the
output of Federal generation facilities
with a term of longer than one year, or
rights under one or more wholesale
contracts to purchase electric energy
with a term of longer than one year, for
the purpose of meeting a service
obligation.
(c) General rule.
(1) Every public utility that is a
transmission organization and that
owns, operates or controls facilities
used for the transmission of electric
energy in interstate commerce and has
one or more organized electricity
markets (administered either by it or by
another entity) must file with the
Commission, no later than [INSERT
DATE 180 DAYS AFTER
PUBLICATION OF FINAL RULE IN
THE FEDERAL REGISTER], one of the
following:
(i) Tariff sheets and rate schedules
that make available long-term firm
transmission rights that are consistent
with the guidelines set forth in
paragraph (d) of this section; or
(ii) An explanation of how its current
tariff and rate schedules already provide
for long-term firm transmission rights
that are consistent with the guidelines
set forth in paragraph (d) of this section.
(2) Any transmission organization that
is approved by the Commission for
operation after [INSERT DATE 180
DAYS AFTER PUBLICATION OF
FINAL RULE IN THE FEDERAL
REGISTER] and has one or more
organized electricity markets
(administered either by it or by another
entity) must satisfy this general rule
before commencing operation.
(d) Guidelines for Design and
Administration of Long-term Firm
Transmission Rights. Transmission
organizations subject to paragraph (c) of
this section must make available longterm firm transmission rights that satisfy
the following guidelines:
(1) The long-term firm transmission
right should specify a source (injection
node or nodes) and sink (withdrawal
node or nodes), and a quantity (MW).
(2) The long-term firm transmission
right must provide a hedge against day-
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
6710
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 27 / Thursday, February 9, 2006 / Proposed Rules
ahead locational marginal pricing
congestion charges (or other direct
assignment of congestion costs) for the
period covered and quantity specified.
Once allocated, the financial coverage
provided by the right should not be
modified during its term except in the
case of extraordinary circumstances or
through voluntary agreement of both the
holder of the right and the transmission
organization.
(3) Long-term firm transmission rights
made feasible by transmission upgrades
or expansions must be available upon
request to any party that pays for such
upgrades or expansions in accordance
with the transmission organization’s
prevailing cost allocation methods for
upgrades or expansions. The term of the
rights should be equal to the life of the
facility (or facilities) or a lesser term
requested by the party paying for the
upgrade or expansion.
(4) Long-term firm transmission rights
must be made available with terms
(and/or rights to renewal) that are
sufficient to meet the needs of loadserving entities to hedge long-term
power supply arrangements made or
planned to satisfy a service obligation.
The length of term of renewals may be
different from the original term.
(5) Load-serving entities with longterm power supply arrangements to
meet a service obligation must have
priority to existing transmission
capacity that supports long-term firm
transmission rights requested to hedge
such arrangements.
(6) A long-term transmission right
held by a load-serving entity to support
a service obligation should be reassignable to another entity that
acquires that service obligation.
(7) The initial allocation of the longterm firm transmission rights shall not
require recipients to participate in an
auction.
(8) Allocation of long-term firm
transmission rights should balance any
adverse economic impact between
participants receiving and not receiving
the right.
[FR Doc. 06–1195 Filed 2–8–06; 8:45 am]
wwhite on PROD1PC61 with PROPOSALS
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
VerDate Aug<31>2005
20:19 Feb 08, 2006
Jkt 208001
DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND
HUMAN SERVICES
Food and Drug Administration
21 CFR Part 888
[Docket No. 2006N–0019]
Orthopedic Devices; Reclassification
of the Intervertebral Body Fusion
Device
AGENCY:
Food and Drug Administration,
HHS.
ACTION:
Proposed rule.
SUMMARY: The Food and Drug
Administration (FDA) is proposing to
reclassify intervertebral body fusion
devices that contain bone grafting
material, from class III (premarket
approval) into class II (special controls),
and retain those that contain any
therapeutic biologic (e.g., bone
morphogenic protein) in class III.
Elsewhere in this issue of the Federal
Register, FDA is announcing the
availability of a draft guidance
document that would serve as the
special control if FDA reclassifies this
device. The agency is proposing this
reclassification based on the
recommendation of the Orthopaedic and
Rehabilitation Devices Panel (the Panel).
DATES: Submit written or electronic
comments by May 10, 2006. See section
X of this document for the proposed
effective date of a final rule based on
this proposed rule.
ADDRESSES: You may submit comments,
identified by Docket No. 2006N–0019,
by any of the following methods:
Electronic Submissions
Submit electronic comments in the
following ways:
• Federal eRulemaking Portal: https://
www.regulations.gov. Follow the
instructions for submitting comments.
• Agency Web site: https://
www.fda.gov/dockets/ecomments.
Follow the instructions for submitting
comments on the agency Web site.
Written Submissions
Submit written submissions in the
followings ways:
• FAX: 301–827–6870.
• Mail/Hand delivery/courier (for
paper, disk, or CD–ROM submissions):
Division of Dockets Management (HFA–
305), Food and Drug Administration,
5630 Fishers Lane, rm. 1061, Rockville,
MD 20852.
To ensure more timely processing of
comments, FDA is no longer accepting
comments submitted to the agency by email. FDA encourages you to continue
to submit electronic comments by using
PO 00000
Frm 00030
Fmt 4702
Sfmt 4702
the Federal eRulemaking Portal or the
agency Web site, as described in the
Electronic Submissions portion of this
paragraph.
Instructions: All submissions received
must include the agency name and
docket number for this rulemaking. All
comments received may be posted
without change to https://www.fda.gov/
ohrms/dockets/default.htm, including
any personal information provided. For
additional information on submitting
comments, see the ‘‘Comments’’ heading
of the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION
section of this document.
Docket: For access to the docket to
read background documents or
comments received, go to https://
www.fda.gov/ohrms/dockets/
default.htm and insert the docket
number, found in brackets in the
heading of this document, into the
‘‘Search’’ box and follow the prompts
and/or go to the Division of Dockets
Management, 5630 Fishers Lane, rm.
1061, Rockville, MD 20852.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Jodi
N. Anderson, Center for Devices and
Radiological Health (HFZ–410), Food
and Drug Administration, 9200
Corporate Blvd., Rockville, MD 20850,
301–594–2036, ext. 186.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
I. Background (Regulatory Authorities)
The Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic
Act (the act) (21 U.S.C. 301 et seq.), as
amended by the Medical Device
Amendments of 1976 (the 1976
amendments) (Public Law 94–295), the
Safe Medical Devices Act of 1990
(Public Law 101–629), the Food and
Drug Administration Modernization Act
of 1997 (Public Law 105–115), and the
Medical Device User Fee and
Modernization Act of 2002 (Public Law
107–250), established a comprehensive
system for the regulation of medical
devices intended for human use.
Section 513 of the act (21 U.S.C. 360c)
established three categories (classes) of
devices, depending on the regulatory
controls needed to provide reasonable
assurance of their safety and
effectiveness. The three categories of
devices are class I (general controls),
class II (special controls), and class III
(premarket approval).
Under section 513 of the act, devices
that were in commercial distribution
before May 28, 1976 (the date of
enactment of the 1976 amendments),
generally referred to as preamendments
devices, are classified after FDA has
done the following: (1) Received a
recommendation from a device
classification panel (an FDA advisory
committee); (2) published the panel’s
E:\FR\FM\09FEP1.SGM
09FEP1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 71, Number 27 (Thursday, February 9, 2006)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 6693-6710]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 06-1195]
=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
18 CFR Part 40
[Docket Nos. RM06-8-000 and AD05-7-000]
Long-Term Firm Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity
Markets; Long-Term Transmission Rights in Markets Operated by Regional
Transmission Organizations and Independent System Operators
February 2, 2006.
AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
ACTION: Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission is proposing to amend
its regulations to require transmission organizations that are public
utilities with organized electricity markets to make available long-
term firm transmission rights that satisfy certain guidelines
established in this proceeding. The Commission is taking this action
pursuant to section 1233(b) of the Energy Policy Act of 2005, Public
Law No. 109-58, section 1233(b), 119 Stat. 594, 960 (2005).
DATES: Comments are due March 13, 2006. Reply comments are due March
27, 2006.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
Udi E. Helman (Technical Information), Office of Energy Markets and
Reliability, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street,
NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8080.
Roland Wentworth (Technical Information), Office of Energy Markets and
Reliability, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street,
NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8262.
Wilbur C. Earley (Technical Information), Office of Energy Markets and
Reliability, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street,
NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8087.
Harry Singh (Technical Information), Office of Market Oversight and
Investigations, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street,
NE., Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-6341.
Jeffery S. Dennis (Legal Information), Office of the General Counsel,
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street, NE.,
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-6027.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
I. Introduction
1. On August 8, 2005, the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005)
\1\ became law. Pursuant to the requirement in section 1233 of EPAct
2005,\2\ which added a new section 217 to the Federal Power Act (FPA),
the Commission is proposing to amend its regulations to require each
transmission organization that is a public utility with one or more
organized electricity markets to make available long-term
[[Page 6694]]
firm transmission rights that satisfy guidelines established by the
Commission in this rulemaking. The Commission proposes to require each
such transmission organization to file, no later than [INSERT DATE 180
DAYS AFTER PUBLICATION OF FINAL RULE IN THE Federal Register], either:
(1) Tariff sheets and rate schedules that make available long-term firm
transmission rights that are consistent with the guidelines set forth
in the Final Rule; or (2) an explanation of how its current tariff and
rate schedules already provide long-term firm transmission rights that
are consistent with the guidelines set forth in the Final Rule.
Transmission organizations that are approved by the Commission after
[INSERT DATE 180 DAYS AFTER PUBLICATION OF FINAL RULE IN THE Federal
Register], must meet the requirements of the proposed rule before
commencing operation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Pub. L. 109-58, 119 Stat. 594 (2005).
\2\ Pub. L. 109-58, Sec. 1233(b), 119 Stat. 594, 960.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. New section 217(b)(4) of the FPA provides:
The Commission shall exercise the authority of the Commission
under this Act in a manner that facilitates the planning and
expansion of transmission facilities to meet the reasonable needs of
load-serving entities to satisfy the service obligations of the
load-serving entities, and enables load-serving entities to secure
firm transmission rights (or equivalent tradable or financial
rights) on a long-term basis for long-term power supply arrangements
made, or planned, to meet such needs.\3\
Section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005 requires:
Within 1 year after the date of enactment of this section and
after notice and an opportunity for comment, the Commission shall by
rule or order, implement section 217(b)(4) of the Federal Power Act
in Transmission Organizations, as defined by that Act with organized
electricity markets.\4\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Pub. L. 109-58, section 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 958.
\4\ Id. at 960.
3. In this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR), we propose
guidelines for the design and administration of long-term firm
transmission rights that transmission organizations with organized
electricity markets \5\ would make available to all transmission
customers. As described in more detail below, the Commission will allow
regional flexibility in setting the terms of the rights, but long-term
firm transmission rights must be made available with terms (and/or
rights to renewal) that are sufficient to meet the needs of load-
serving entities to hedge long-term power supply arrangements made or
planned to satisfy a service obligation. While we propose that long-
term firm transmission rights be made available to all transmission
customers, in the event that a transmission organization cannot
accommodate all requests for long-term firm transmission rights over
existing transmission capacity, we propose to require that a preference
be given to load-serving entities with long-term power supply
arrangements used to meet service obligations. The other properties we
believe long-term firm transmission rights must have are discussed in
the proposed guidelines below. These guidelines will give transmission
organizations, in consultation with market participants, the
flexibility to propose alternative designs that reflect regional
preferences and accommodate the regional market design, while also
ensuring that the objectives of Congress expressed in new section
217(b)(4) of the FPA are met.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ See ``Definitions'' below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. In proposing this rule, the Commission seeks to provide
increased certainty regarding the congestion cost risks of long-term
transmission service in organized electricity markets that will help
load-serving entities and other market participants make new
investments and other long-term power supply arrangements. We
understand that specifying and allocating long-term firm transmission
rights supported by existing transfer capability will raise difficult
issues that must be addressed in this rulemaking and in its
implementation over time. We note, however, that long-term rights are
available to market participants in a direct manner, namely by
supporting an expansion or upgrade of grid transfer capability. As
described in more detail below, the Commission's policy is that market
participants that request and support an expansion or upgrade in
accordance with their transmission organization's prevailing rules for
cost responsibility and allocation must be awarded a long-term firm
transmission right for the incremental transfer capability created by
the expansion or upgrade. Such a long-term transmission right must be
for a term equal to the life of the new facilities, or for a lesser
term if requested by the funding entity. The transmission organization
tariffs must clearly and specifically provide for this arrangement, if
they do not already.
II. Definitions
5. The Commission proposes several definitions in this NOPR. We set
forth those proposed definitions in this section, since these defined
terms are used extensively in the background discussion and proposed
guidelines that follow. The Commission seeks comment on whether these
definitions are appropriate.
A. Transmission Organization
6. The Commission proposes a definition for ``transmission
organization'' that is similar to the definition provided in EPAct
2005.\6\ Specifically, we propose to include the word ``independent''
in the last clause of the EPAct 2005 definition, such that transmission
organization would mean ``a Regional Transmission Organization,
Independent System Operator, independent transmission provider, or
other independent transmission organization finally approved by the
Commission for the operation of transmission facilities.'' \7\ We make
this clarification to the definition in EPAct 2005 because we interpret
section 1233(b) of the legislation to require that long-term firm
transmission rights be made available in the currently existing
independent entities approved to operate transmission facilities that
have organized electricity markets (as defined below), and any such
independent entities that are created in the future.\8\ We seek
comments on whether this definition appropriately captures the intent
of section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ Pub. L. No. 109-58, section 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 985.
\7\ See id. at 942, 985.
\8\ The transmission organizations that currently have an
organized electricity market are ISO New England, Inc. (ISO-NE), New
York Independent System Operator, Inc. (New York ISO), PJM
Interconnection, Inc. (PJM), California Independent System Operator,
Inc. (CAISO), and Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator,
Inc. (Midwest ISO). Southwest Power Pool is currently developing its
market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Load-Serving Entity and Service Obligation
7. The Commission proposes to define the terms ``load-serving
entity'' and ``service obligation,'' for purposes of the proposed rule,
exactly as they are defined in section 217 of the FPA. Specifically, we
propose to define load-serving entity to mean ``a distribution utility
or electric utility that has a service obligation.'' \9\ We propose to
define service obligation to mean ``a requirement applicable to, or the
exercise of authority granted to, an electric utility under Federal,
State or local law or under long-term contracts to provide electric
service to end-users or to a distribution utility.'' \10\ We seek
comment on whether it is necessary to
[[Page 6695]]
expand or clarify these definitions in the Final Rule.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ See id. at 957. In section 1291 of EPAct 2005, ``electric
utility'' is defined as ``a person or Federal or State agency
(including an entity described in section 201(f) [of the FPA]) that
sells electric energy.'' Id. at 984.
\10\ See id. at 958.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
C. Organized Electricity Market
8. EPAct 2005 and section 217 of the FPA do not define ``organized
electricity market.'' The Commission proposes to define organized
electricity market as ``an auction-based market where a single entity
receives offers to sell and bids to buy electric energy and/or
ancillary services from multiple sellers and buyers and determines
which sales and purchases are completed and at what prices, based on
formal rules contained in Commission-approved tariffs, and where the
prices are used by a transmission organization for establishing
transmission usage charges.'' We intend for the Final Rule we develop
in this proceeding to apply to any transmission organization with a
day-ahead and/or real-time (or ``spot'') bid-based energy market that
is the transmission provider in its region.\11\ These markets could
either be administered by the transmission organization itself or by
another entity. The definition we propose here is intended to ensure
that the Final Rule covers all such transmission organizations, either
existing or developed in the future. We seek comment on whether the
scope of this definition is appropriate or whether it should be
revised.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ As noted above, the transmission organizations that
currently have an organized electricity market are ISO-NE, New York
ISO, PJM, CAISO, and Midwest ISO. Southwest Power Pool is currently
developing its market.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
D. Long-Term Power Supply Arrangement
9. Section 217(b)(4) of the FPA requires the Commission to exercise
its authority to enable load-serving entities to obtain firm
transmission rights on a long-term basis ``for long-term power supply
arrangements made * * * or planned'' to meet service obligations.\12\
While ``long-term power supply arrangements'' is not defined in the
legislation, section 217(b)(1)(A) of the FPA suggests that a load-
serving entity has a long-term power supply arrangement if it ``owns
generation facilities, markets the output of Federal generation
facilities, or holds rights under one or more wholesale contracts to
purchase electric energy, for the purpose of meeting a service
obligation.'' For purposes of this proposed rule, we propose to use
similar language to define ``long-term power supply arrangements.''
Specifically, we propose to define ``long-term power supply
arrangements'' to mean ``the ownership of generation facilities, rights
to market the output of Federal generation facilities with a term of
longer than one year, or rights under one or more wholesale contracts
to purchase electric energy with a term of longer than one year, for
the purpose of meeting a service obligation.'' \13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ Pub. L. No. 109-58, section 1233, 119 Stat. 594, 958
(emphasis added).
\13\ While we consider long-term as ``more than one year'' in
the context of defining a long-term power supply arrangement, later
in this NOPR we note that we consider ``long-term'' in the context
of the appropriate terms for long-term firm transmission rights to
be terms and/or renewal rights that cover the multiple years
necessary to support a long-term power supply arrangement. See infra
at P 55.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
III. Background
A. The Development of ISOs and RTOs
10. In Order No. 888, the Commission found that undue
discrimination and anticompetitive practices existed in the provision
of electric transmission service in interstate commerce, and determined
that non-discriminatory open access transmission service was one of the
most critical components of a successful transition to competitive
wholesale electricity markets.\14\ Accordingly, the Commission required
all public utilities that own, control or operate facilities used for
transmitting electric energy in interstate commerce to file open access
transmission tariffs (OATTs) containing certain non-price terms and
conditions and to ``functionally unbundle'' wholesale power services
from transmission services.\15\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-
discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery
of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities,
Order No. 888, 61 FR 21540 (May 10, 1996), FERC Stats. & Regs. ]
31,036 at 31,682 (1996), order on reh'g, Order No. 888-A, 62 FR
12274 (March 14, 1997), FERC Stats & Regs. ] 31,048 (1997), order on
reh'g, Order No. 888-B, 81 FERC ] 61,248 (1997), order on reh'g,
Order No. 888-C, 82 FERC ] 61,046 (1998), aff'd in relevant part sub
nom. Transmission Access Policy Study Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667
(D.C. Cir. 2000), aff'd sub nom. New York v. FERC, 535 U.S. 1
(2002).
\15\ Under functional unbundling, the public utility is required
to: (1) Take wholesale transmission services under the same tariff
of general applicability as it offers its customers; (2) state
separate rates for wholesale generation, transmission and ancillary
services; and (3) rely on the same electronic information network
that its transmission customers rely on to obtain information about
the utility's transmission system. Id. at 31,654.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
11. In addition, the Commission found in Order No. 888 that
Independent System Operators (ISOs) had the potential to aid in
remedying undue discrimination and accomplishing comparable access.\16\
To guide the voluntary development of ISOs, Order No. 888 set forth 11
principles for assessing ISO proposals submitted to the Commission.\17\
Following Order No. 888, several voluntary ISOs were established and
approved by the Commission.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ Order No. 888 at 31,655; Order No. 888-A at 30,184.
\17\ Order No. 888 at 31,730.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
12. In light of the creation of these ISOs and other changes in the
electric industry, the Commission issued Order No. 2000.\18\ In that
order, the Commission concluded that traditional management of the
transmission grid by vertically integrated electric utilities was
inadequate to support the efficient and reliable operation of
transmission facilities that is necessary for continued development of
competitive electricity markets.\19\ The Commission also found that
even after functional unbundling of electric utilities under Order No.
888, opportunities for undue discrimination continued to exist.\20\ As
a result, the Commission adopted rules intended to facilitate the
voluntary development of Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs).
The Commission concluded that RTOs would provide several benefits,
including regional transmission pricing, improved congestion
management, and more effective management of parallel path flows.\21\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Regional Transmission Organizations, Order No. 2000, FERC
Stats. & Regs. ] 31,089 (1999), order on reh'g, Order No. 2000-A,
FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,092 (2000), aff'd sub nom. Public Utility
District No. 1 of Snohomish County, Washington v. FERC, 272 F.3d 607
(D.C. Cir. 2001).
\19\ Order No. 2000 at 30,992-93 and 31,014-15.
\20\ Id. at 31,015-17.
\21\ Id. at 31,024.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
13. In Order No. 2000, the Commission established the minimum
characteristics and functions that an RTO must satisfy to gain
Commission approval. Minimum characteristics of an RTO include
independence from market participants and operational authority over
transmission facilities under its control.\22\ Minimum functions of an
RTO include ensuring the development and operation of market mechanisms
to manage transmission congestion, development and implementation of
procedures to address parallel path flow issues, and market
monitoring.\23\ Under Order No. 2000, the Commission has approved the
voluntary formation of a number of RTOs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\22\ Id. at 31,046 et seq.
\23\ Id. at 31,106 et seq.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
14. Most of the RTOs and ISOs operate organized markets for energy
and/or ancillary services in addition to providing transmission service
under a single transmission tariff. As described in more detail below,
most of these markets utilize a congestion management system based on
[[Page 6696]]
Locational Marginal Pricing (LMP). Congestion is defined as the
inability to inject and withdraw additional energy at particular
locations in the network due to the fact that the injections and
withdrawals would cause power flows over a specific transmission
facility to violate the reliability limits for that facility. The
market operator manages congestion by scheduling and dispatching
generators that can meet load in the presence of congestion.
Financially, in LMP markets the price of congestion is measured as the
difference in the cost of energy in the spot market at two different
locations in the network.\24\ When such price differences occur, a
congestion charge is assessed to transmission users based on their
nodal injections and withdrawals. These price differences can be
variable and difficult to predict. In order to manage the risk
associated with the variability in prices due to transmission
congestion, these markets use various forms of Financial Transmission
Rights (FTRs) (described in more detail below) to allow market
participants who hold the rights to protect against such price risks.
In most cases, these FTRs have terms of one year or less. The use of
FTRs and their terms is also discussed in more detail below.\25\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\24\ See infra at P 21-22.
\25\ See infra at P 23-28.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
B. Currently Available Transmission Rights
15. In recent years, interest in long-term transmission rights in
organized electricity markets has increased, stemming in large part
from a desire of some market participants to obtain rights that
replicate the transmission service that was available to them prior to
the formation of the organized electricity markets and remains
available today in regions without organized electricity markets. The
principal concern of these market participants is the inability to
obtain a fixed, long-term level of service under pricing arrangements
that hedge the congestion cost risk that they face in the organized
electricity markets. This section describes the transmission rights
that are available in regions with and without organized electricity
markets, and concludes with a comparison of the two types of rights.
1. Transmission Rights in Regions Without Organized Electricity Markets
16. In general, in regions without organized electricity markets,
transmission service is provided to customers under the terms of the
Order No. 888 OATT, or under terms of contracts that predate the OATT.
The OATT offers two types of transmission service: Network integration
transmission service (network service), which is a long-term firm
transmission service, and point-to-point transmission service, which is
available on a firm or non-firm basis and on a long-term (one year or
longer) or short-term basis. Long-term firm transmission customers
taking service under the OATT have the right to continue to take
transmission service from the transmission provider when their contract
expires (rollover right). Transmission providers are required to expand
facilities to satisfy network and point-to-point customer needs.\26\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\26\ See Order No. 888 pro forma OATT at sections 13.5, 15.4 and
28.2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
17. Firm point-to-point transmission service provides for the
transmission of energy between designated points of receipt and
designated points of delivery. A customer taking firm point-to-point
transmission service generally pays a monthly demand charge based on
its reserved capacity, and it may resell the service to another
customer.\27\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\27\ Under the Commission's transmission pricing policy, the
demand charge may reflect the higher of the transmission provider's
embedded costs or incremental expansion costs. Also, if the
transmission system is constrained, the demand charge may reflect
the higher of embedded costs or ``opportunity'' costs, with the
latter capped at incremental expansion costs. See Inquiry Concerning
the Commission's Pricing Policy for Transmission Services Provided
by Public Utilities Under the Federal Power Act, Policy Statement,
69 FERC ] 61,086 (1994). In practice, the demand charge is almost
always determined on basis of the transmission provider's embedded
costs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
18. Network service provides the customer with flexibility to
utilize its current and planned generation resources to serve its
network load in a manner comparable to that in which the transmission
provider utilizes its generation resources to serve its native load
customers. A network customer must designate network resources,
including all generation owned, purchased or leased by the network
customer to serve its designated load. A network customer also must
designate the individual network loads on whose behalf the transmission
provider will provide network service. The network customer pays a
monthly charge for basic service based on its load ratio share of the
transmission provider's transmission revenue requirement.
19. As a condition of receiving network service, a network customer
agrees to redispatch its network resources as requested by the
transmission provider.\28\ The transmission provider must plan,
construct, operate and maintain its transmission system in order to
provide the network customer with network service over the transmission
provider's system, and must designate its own resources and loads in
the same manner as a network customer. If the transmission provider
needs to redispatch the system due to congestion to accommodate a
network customer's schedule, the costs of redispatch are passed through
to the transmission provider's network customers, including its own
native load, on a load-ratio basis. If a curtailment on the
transmission provider's system is required to maintain reliable
operation of the system, curtailments are made on a non-discriminatory
basis to the extent practicable and consistent with good utility
practice, with firm service having the highest priority and non-firm
generally having the lowest priority.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\28\ Redispatch means that, due to congestion, the utility
changes the output of generators to maintain the energy balance. The
output of some generators may be increased while the output of
others may decrease.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
20. The price that a transmission customer pays for OATT
transmission service is usually predictable and relatively stable over
the long-term. For example, a load-serving entity that has a generating
facility at one location that it wishes to use to serve load at a
second location can contract for long-term point-to-point transmission
service from the generator to the load. For this service, the load-
serving entity pays only a demand charge that is known in advance.
Although the load-serving entity must pay the demand charge whether or
not it uses its full reservation, it does not have to pay additional
costs associated with transmission congestion for point-to-point
transmission service even when the transmission provider must
redispatch its generators to honor the firm service commitment. If the
load-serving entity has generators and loads at multiple locations, it
can request network service and dispatch of its generators to serve its
loads in a least cost manner. The load-serving entity must pay a load
ratio share of the transmission provider's Commission-approved
transmission revenue requirement but, again, is not directly assigned
any congestion costs. If either the transmission provider's or the
load-serving entity's generators have to be redispatched to relieve
congestion, then the cost of redispatch is shared by the transmission
provider and all network customers on a load ratio basis. Thus, whether
it takes firm point-to-point transmission service or network service,
the load-serving entity faces transmission costs that are relatively
stable and predictable over the term of its service agreement.
[[Page 6697]]
2. Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity Markets
21. Each of the transmission organizations that exist today has
implemented or is planning to implement an organized electricity market
that uses locational pricing for electric energy. In most cases, the
locational pricing system that is used is LMP. Under LMP, the price at
each location in the grid at any given time reflects the cost of making
available an additional unit of energy for purchase at that location
and time. In the absence of transmission congestion, all locational
prices at a given time are the same.\29\ However, when congestion is
present, locational prices typically will not be the same, and the
difference between any two locational prices represents the cost of
congestion between those locations.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\29\ The inclusion of marginal losses can cause locational
prices to differ across locations even in the absence of congestion.
For purposes of this discussion, we will consider only the
congestion component of locational price differences.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
22. Because locational spot prices can vary significantly over
time, a market participant potentially faces some degree of price
uncertainty. Consider a load-serving entity that has a generator at one
location and load at another. If there is no congestion, the generator
and the load will see the same locational prices just as if they were
at the same location. However, when congestion arises, locational
prices will differ, and the price that the load-serving entity's
generator receives typically will not be the same as the price that its
load must pay.\30\ This difference in prices is the congestion cost,
and the load-serving entity must pay this cost to the transmission
organization whenever power is injected and withdrawn at different
locations in the transmission system under constrained conditions.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\30\ It is important to note that, depending on the relative
magnitude of the prices at the generator's location and the load's
location, congestion costs can be positive or negative.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
23. To reduce the uncertainty due to congestion, transmission
organizations that use locational marginal pricing make FTRs available
to their market participants.\31\ An FTR is a right to receive the
congestion costs paid by grid users and collected by the transmission
organization for one megawatt of electricity delivered from a specified
point of receipt to a specified point of delivery. The holder of an FTR
receives in each hour a payment that is calculated by subtracting the
price at the point of receipt from the price at the point of delivery,
and multiplying the difference by the megawatt quantity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\31\ We use the term FTR in this NOPR to refer generally to the
financial transmission instruments used in the various organized
electricity markets that currently exist. In some markets, these
financial instruments are called transmission congestion contracts
or congestion revenue rights.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
24. In an LMP system, all spot power is purchased and sold at
locational prices and all scheduled injections and withdrawals are
subject to congestion charges. When there is no congestion, the prices
are the same and the payments to FTR holders are zero. However, when
congestion is present, prices will differ; prices for withdrawals are
generally higher than prices for injections, creating a source of funds
to pay the FTR holders. To ensure that the excess revenue is sufficient
to meet its FTR payment obligations under normal operating conditions,
the transmission organization generally subjects any award of FTRs to a
simultaneous feasibility test. The simultaneous feasibility test
requires that, before specific FTRs can be awarded, the transmission
organization must demonstrate that the transmission system is capable
of physically delivering the power flows represented by the FTRs
simultaneously with the power flows represented by all concurrently or
previously awarded FTRs. Although FTRs do not convey a physical right
(or obligation) to use the transmission system, the transmission
organization will be at risk of not receiving sufficient revenues to
meet all of its FTR payment obligations under normal operating
conditions if any awarded FTRs do not meet the simultaneous feasibility
test. Any time that revenues are not sufficient, the transmission
organization is said to be ``revenue inadequate.'' \32\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\32\ It should be noted that, even when all awarded FTRs meet
the simultaneous feasibility test, the Transmission Organization may
at times be revenue inadequate as a result of unexpected events,
such as a line outage or transmission system disruption that reduces
transfer capability.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
25. The most common type of FTR, which is known as an FTR
``obligation,'' provides for a payment to the holder when congestion
cost is positive, but also requires the holder to make a payment to the
transmission organization whenever the cost is negative. Because of
this feature, some transmission organizations also offer FTR
``options,'' which do not place a payment obligation on the rights
holder. However, because FTR options require more transmission capacity
than FTR obligations to meet the simultaneous feasibility test, their
availability is limited.\33\ Therefore, for purposes of the discussion
in this section, we will assume that FTRs are limited to FTR
obligations.\34\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\33\ The need for more capacity is due to the fact that the
Transmission Organization cannot assume that the FTR options will
provide any ``counterflows'' when it conducts the simultaneous
feasibility test.
\34\ See infra at P 72-79 for a more complete discussion of the
properties of FTR obligations and FTR options.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
26. If a load-serving entity holds an FTR that matches its
injections and withdrawals exactly, it pays no net congestion cost.\35\
A load-serving entity may also reduce its congestion cost risk by
holding an FTR that provides a partial hedge. Typically, the FTRs that
load-serving entities hold do not exactly match their use of the
transmission system in each hour, but the ``over'' and ``under''
financial coverage provided by the FTRs evens out over time to provide
a sufficient hedge.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\35\ This net result is reached because congestion charges
billed to the load-serving entity (or any other party that holds
FTRs) are exactly offset by FTR payments.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
27. In general, transmission organizations provide FTRs on an
annual basis to load-serving entities and others that pay access
charges or fixed transmission rates. Load-serving entities receive FTRs
either through direct allocation or through a two-step process in which
the load-serving entity first is allocated auction revenue rights
(ARRs) and then purchases FTRs in an auction.\36\ The revenues from the
auction flow back to the load-serving entity and other ARR holders and
thus defray the cost of purchasing the FTRs in the auction.
Transmission organizations currently offer ARRs and FTRs with terms of
one year or less. Although details vary by transmission organization,
the allocation is based largely on historical uses of the system as
measured by peak loads, but also allows market participants some
flexibility to choose among transmission paths. Most transmission
organizations also allocate long-term ARRs and FTRs to any party that
invests in transmission upgrades that increase transmission capability.
FTRs can be traded in annual and monthly transmission organization
auctions or bilaterally outside the auction.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\36\ ARRs confer the right to collect revenues from the
subsequent FTR auction. For example, the holder of an ARR between
location A and location B knows that it will collect revenues equal
to the market clearing price of an FTR between location A and
location B. An ARR can, but does not need to, exactly match an FTR.
In some Organized Electricity Markets, a market participant must
submit a bid for FTRs in the auction to convert its ARRs to FTRs,
while in other Organized Electricity Markets a market participant
can convert its ARRs to FTRs directly and is not required to bid in
the auction.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
28. Since the state of the transmission system and market prices
change from year to year, the annual allocation allows market
participants to re-
[[Page 6698]]
configure their transmission rights requests each year to reflect such
changes. The annual reconfiguration also helps the transmission
organization to manage exposure to situations where payments to FTR
holders can exceed congestion revenues. Revenue shortfalls can occur
due to changes in the transmission grid or in the availability of
generators that have a major impact on power flows. If such changes are
expected to be long-lasting, the transmission organization is able to
adjust the quantity and configuration of rights made available in the
next annual cycle. However, a load-serving entity may receive fewer
FTRs or ARRs than it requests due to factors outside of its control,
such as changes in the network, the network flow assumptions or the FTR
nominations of other participants. As a result, load-serving entities
are uncertain from year to year whether they will obtain the FTRs
needed to support long-term power supply arrangements, including
investment in generation resources.
3. Comparison of Transmission Rights in Regions With and Without
Organized Electricity Markets
29. There are several important differences between transmission
service under the OATT and transmission rights in organized electricity
markets that use LMP and FTRs. However, the differences that are most
relevant for purposes of this NOPR concern the management of
congestion, the recovery of congestion costs and the availability of
long-term service arrangements.
30. Under the OATT, the transmission provider manages congestion by
redispatching its own or its customers' network resources as needed to
accommodate a transmission constraint; the OATT provides no mechanism
by which firm point-to-point transmission customers can participate
directly in congestion management. However, in organized electricity
markets, the transmission organization manages congestion through the
use of locational prices. This means that all available resources under
an LMP system can participate in redispatch for congestion management
because they all receive the congestion price signal. As a result, a
transmission organization in a region with an organized electricity
market is less likely to have to invoke transmission loading relief
(TLR) procedures and service curtailments than a transmission provider
under the OATT.
31. The recovery of congestion costs also differs greatly between
regions with and without organized electricity markets. In regions
where transmission service is provided under the OATT, a transmission
customer that takes network service or firm point-to-point transmission
service is not charged directly for the costs of the redispatch that
may be required to accommodate its use of the transmission system. For
example, a firm point-to-point transmission customer is allowed to take
service up to its contractual entitlement while paying only a fixed
demand charge. Also, although a network customer must pay a share of
any redispatch costs that the transmission provider and other network
customers incur, its cost responsibility is determined after the fact
as a load ratio share of the total redispatch costs that are incurred
on behalf of all users of the system over a given time period. While
this type of pricing may not present the customer with a price signal
that accurately reflects all of the costs occasioned by the customer's
use of the system, it lowers the transmission customer's price
uncertainty. In addition, both network service and firm point-to-point
transmission service can be obtained under long-term contracts. These
attributes of OATT transmission service result in a less volatile price
for transmission service over a long-term, which in turn can help
facilitate the planning and financing of large generation facilities
and other long-term power supply arrangements.
32. In contrast, a transmission organization in a region with an
organized electricity market recovers congestion costs through the
locational pricing of energy. Because locational prices include a
congestion cost component (which can be positive, negative or zero), a
participant in an organized electricity market faces the prospect of
paying a congestion charge for many of its transactions. For example,
as explained above, a load-serving entity that has generation at one
location and load at another, but does not hold FTRs, is at risk of
incurring congestion costs, which may not be predictable. Also,
although that load-serving entity can avoid congestion costs by holding
FTRs, it still faces a congestion price risk if its spot sales and
purchases or scheduled injections and withdrawals do not correspond
exactly to its allocated (or purchased) FTRs. Clearly, locational
pricing and price-based congestion management provide the market
participant with much of the information it needs to make cost
effective decisions regarding energy consumption and use of the
transmission system (as well as investment in new generation and
transmission upgrades). However, the FTRs that transmission
organizations currently provide to hedge congestion charges for using
existing transmission capacity (as opposed to incremental transmission
expansions) are generally available for terms of only one year or less.
This can create uncertainty for the market participant because, in any
given year, its award of FTRs may not be sufficient to meet its needs.
Some market participants have expressed concern that this uncertainty
makes it more difficult to finance long-term power supply arrangements.
33. The Commission believes that some of the problems of
uncertainty in organized electricity markets can be overcome and the
objectives of section 217(b)(4) of the FPA can be met through the
introduction of long-term firm transmission rights. However, for a
variety of reasons that are discussed below, transmission rights in
organized electricity markets cannot always be designed in a way that
captures all of the features of the transmission rights that have long
been available under the OATT. Consequently, the Commission's objective
in issuing this NOPR is to present a framework within which
transmission organizations and their market participants can design and
implement long-term firm transmission rights in the organized
electricity markets that are compatible with the design of those
markets, in particular retaining the advantages of price-based
congestion management, and meet the reasonable needs of market
participants.
C. Staff Paper on Long-Term Transmission Rights
34. Prior to the enactment of EPAct 2005, the Commission released a
Staff Paper that provided background and solicited comments on whether
long-term transmission rights were needed in the ISO and RTO markets,
and if so, how to implement them.\37\ This section provides an overview
of the comments to the notice.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\37\ Notice Inviting Comments on Establishing Long-Term
Transmission Rights in Markets With Locational Pricing and Staff
Paper, Long-Term Transmission Rights Assessment, Docket No. AD05-7-
000 (May 11, 2005) (Staff Paper). While we are issuing this NOPR in
both Docket No. RM06-8-000 and Docket No. AD05-7-000, we expect to
issue our Final Rule in only Docket No. RM06-8-000. Comments in
response to this NOPR should be filed in Docket No. RM06-8-000.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
35. With respect to the need for and design of long-term
transmission rights, the views of the respondents tended to fall into
three general groups. The first group consisted of advocates of long-
term transmission rights with terms in
[[Page 6699]]
the range of 5-30 years.\38\ These parties argue that the failure of
transmission organizations to offer transmission rights with terms
greater than one year is a key deficiency in the markets that produces
increased financial risk due to congestion price uncertainty, the
failure of forward energy markets to form, and barriers to investment
in new generation capacity. The core problem expressed by these parties
is that annual allocations of rights may not provide sufficient rights
year-to-year to adequately cover potentially volatile congestion cost
exposure. In turn, the inability to secure a known quantity of
transmission rights for multiple years introduces an unacceptable
degree of uncertainty into resource planning, investment and
contracting.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\38\ See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of the American Public
Power Association (APPA) at 1, 8, 19; Comments on Staff Paper of the
Transmission Access Policy Study Group (TAPS) at 19-21; Comments on
Staff Paper of the National Rural Electric Cooperative Association
(NRECA) at 17-19; Comments on Staff Paper of the Electricity
Consumers Resource Council (ELCON) at 9-10.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
36. Most of the parties in this first group stressed that not all
transmission capacity should be given over to long-term rights, but
that there should be an amount sufficient to cover at least base-load
generation resources and perhaps renewable energy generators.\39\ These
commenters argue that long-term rights should be FTR obligations only
under certain conditions that limit financial exposure of the rights
holder. Several proposed that the long-term rights should be FTR
options. Otherwise, the rights could be physical rights \40\ or
modified FTRs (e.g. financial rights with physical characteristics,
such as ``use-or-lose'' rights) designed to alter the financial
settlement properties of traditional FTRs so as to reduce congestion
risk.\41\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\39\ See Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at 31; Comments on
Staff Paper of TAPS at 17-19. However, other parties supportive of
long-term transmission rights argued that their allocation should
not be tied to particular classes of generator. See, e.g., Comments
on Staff Paper of ELCON at 8-9.
\40\ See Comments on Staff Paper of Sacramento Municipal Utility
District (SMUD) at 12-16; Comments on Staff Paper of City of Santa
Clara, California, Silicon Valley Power (SVP) at 14-18.
\41\ For example, a right that only provides a financial hedge
when the holder submits a physical schedule (a type of ``use or
lose'' right). See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of the
Transmission Access Policy Study Group (TAPS) at 21-25; Comments on
Staff Paper of the Electricity Consumers Resource Council (ELCON) at
12-13. Note also that several commenters argued that ISOs with LMP
and financial rights should not revert to physical rights to provide
long-term transmission service, nor should they allow such ISOs to
offer combinations of physical and financial rights (with the
exception of already awarded grandfathered rights). See, e.g.,
Comments on Staff Paper of ABATE at 10-11; Comments on Staff Paper
of American Electric Power (AEP) at 3; Comments on Staff Paper of
Cinergy at 13-14; Comments on Staff Paper of Edison Electric
Institute (EEI) at 3; Comments on Staff Paper of Electric Power
Supply Association (EPSA) at 6-8; Comments on Staff Paper of
FirstEnergy Solutions at 8; Comments on Staff Paper of ISO/RTO
Council at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
37. A second group of commenters largely agreed with the first that
long-term rights should be introduced, but argued that this should take
place within the framework of existing FTR market designs and follow a
cautious, incremental approach. These parties, which included most of
the ISOs and RTOs that submitted comments as well as many stakeholders,
argued that rights of greater than one year duration would indeed find
a role in the markets, but that care was needed in the design of the
rights.\42\ Most of these parties were supportive of straightforward
extensions of the current FTR market design to include FTR obligations
of longer terms, although perhaps with modified creditworthiness
requirements and other rule changes to reflect the different risks
embodied in such rights. In general, they proposed terms for such FTRs
of between 2 to 5 years. They also supported limiting the quantity of
system capability given over to long-term FTRs for at least an initial
period.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\42\ See generally Comments on Staff Paper of California ISO;
Comments on Staff Paper of ISO New England; Comments on Staff Paper
of New York ISO; Comments on Staff Paper of PJM; Comments on Staff
Paper of ISO/RTO Council. See also generally Comments on Staff Paper
of New York Public Service Commission (NY PSC) and the Organization
of Midwest States (OMS). On appropriate term lengths, see Comments
on Staff Paper of Cinergy at 10; Comments on Staff Paper of Coral
Power at 3, 6; Comments on Staff Paper of DC Energy at 4-5; Comments
on Staff Paper of Edison Electric Institute (EEI) at 10; Comments on
Staff Paper of Electric Power Supply Association (EPSA) at 11;
Comments on Staff Paper of Midwest Transmission Owners at 11;
Comments on Staff Paper of Morgan Stanley at 7; Comments on Staff
Paper of National Grid at 15; Comments on Staff Paper of Pacific Gas
& Electric (PG&E) at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
38. Finally, some respondents felt that long-term rights should not
be introduced at this time.\43\ These parties argued that the current
procedures for annual allocations of FTRs with terms of one year or
less were well-established and that transmission rights markets were
efficient and maturing around this design. They were concerned that the
introduction of multi-year rights could introduce inequity and
inefficiency into the organized electricity markets, because they
believe such rights will reduce the availability of FTRs with terms of
one year or less that can be used to hedge shorter-term transactions.
They also assert that introducing long-term rights could cause cost
shifts if holders of long-term rights are given congestion risk
coverage greater than that accorded to other parties. Some respondents
that supported this position were from retail choice states, reflecting
concerns that long-term rights could adversely affect their ability to
acquire and trade transmission rights used to hedge shorter-term
contracts.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\43\ See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of Cinergy at 3;
Comments on Staff Paper of Coral Power at 7. However, many of these
respondents did articulate views on how long-term rights should be
specified in the event that the Commission required them.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
39. In general, those responding to the Staff Paper did not favor a
uniform, ``one size fits all'' approach to long-term rights. Instead,
they stressed that the development of long-term transmission rights
should take place in a regional context, which would allow stakeholders
to balance the different needs of transmission users and reflect the
characteristics of the regional grid and generation resources. Also,
those responding provided suggestions on many other aspects of long-
term transmission right design and implementation. We will refer to
those suggestions where relevant in some of the discussion that
follows.
IV. Proposed Guidelines for Design and Administration of Long-Term Firm
Transmission Rights in Organized Electricity Markets
A. The Commission's Proposed Approach
40. To satisfy the requirements of section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005,
and to address the concerns expressed by market participants, the
Commission proposes to establish a set of guidelines for the design and
administration of long-term firm transmission rights in organized
electricity markets. The Commission proposes to require each
transmission organization that is a public utility with one or more
organized electricity markets \44\ to file with the Commission, within
180 days, either proposed tariff sheets that make available long-term
firm transmission rights that are consistent with the guidelines, or an
explanation of how the transmission organization already makes such
rights available. The proposed compliance procedures are discussed in
more detail below.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\44\ As noted elsewhere, this proposed rule would apply whether
the Organized Electricity Markets are administered by the
Transmission Organization itself, or whether the Organized
Electricity Markets are administered by another entity.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
41. The Commission recognizes that there may be many possible
approaches to fulfilling this requirement of EPAct 2005. Parties
commenting on the Staff Paper suggested a number of possible approaches
to designing and implementing long-term transmission rights. The
Commission believes that
[[Page 6700]]
establishing guidelines for the design and administration of long-term
firm transmission rights in this rulemaking, followed by development of
specific long-term firm transmission right designs within the
stakeholder process of each Transmission Organization with an organized
electricity market, is the most appropriate course for complying with
the directive of section 1233(b) of EPAct 2005. We agree with many of
those commenting on the Staff Paper that a ``one size fits all'' long-
term firm transmission right design is not appropriate, and that long-
term transmission rights should be developed through regional
stakeholder discussion.\45\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\45\ See, e.g., Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at 23-24;
Comments on Staff Paper of Association of Businesses Advocating
Tariff Equity (ABATE) and Coalition of Midwest Transmission
Customers at 11-12; Comments on Staff Paper of New York ISO at 3-4;
Comments on Staff Paper of New York Transmission Organizations at 3-
4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
42. This flexible regional development of long-term firm
transmission rights must, however, occur within certain guidelines.
Accordingly, the Commission proposes guidelines for the design and
administration of long-term firm transmission rights that ensure that
those rights have certain properties that we believe are fundamental to
meeting the objectives of section 217(b)(4) of the FPA. For example, we
propose below that long-term firm transmission rights be made available
with terms (and/or rights to renewal) that are sufficient to meet the
needs of load-serving entities to hedge long-term power supply
arrangements made or planned to satisfy a service obligation.
Additionally, as described in more detail in the guidelines that
follow, we propose that transmission organizations be required to award
long-term firm transmission rights to market participants that request
and support an expansion or upgrade to the transmission system in
accordance with the transmission organization's prevailing rules for
cost allocation. Such long-term firm transmission rights must be for a
term equal to the life of the new facilities, or for a lesser term if
requested by the funding entity. Also, as described in more detail
below, while long-term firm transmission rights should be made
available to all transmission customers, in the event that a
transmission organization cannot accommodate all requests for long-term
firm transmission rights over existing transmission capacity, we
propose that the approach most consistent with section 217(b)(4) of the
FPA is to require that a preference be given to load-serving entities
with long-term power supply arrangements used to meet service
obligations.
43. While we believe these and the other properties outlined in the
guidelines below are critical to the successful implementation of long-
term rights, we intend for the guidelines to form only a framework for
further, more specific development of long-term firm transmission
rights by each transmission organization. Accordingly, the guidelines
should provide enough flexibility to allow each region to develop,
through its usual stakeholder process, a specific long-term firm
transmission right design that fits the prevailing market design and
best meets the needs of market participants in that region.
44. Although we propose to allow regional flexibility in the
development of long-term firm transmission rights, we recognize that
allowing transmission organizations with organized electricity markets
to implement different rules for these rights could lead to regional
seams issues. We seek comments on our proposal to provide regional
flexibility. In particular, we ask commenters to identify features of
long-term firm transmission rights that, if not consistent across
transmission organizations, may interfere with the effective operation
of regional markets.
B. Proposed Guidelines
Guideline (1): The long-term firm transmission right should be a
point-to-point right that specifies a source (injection node or
nodes) and sink (withdrawal node or nodes), and a quantity (MW).
45. Section 217(b)(4) of the FPA requires that long-term firm
transmission rights be available to support long-term power supply
arrangements. Hence, we propose that the transmission rights must be
specified such that they can hedge the congestion costs that may be
incurred in delivering the output of particular generation resources to
particular loads.\46\ The source nodes can correspond to a single
generator or a set of generators (e.g., a zone). Similarly, the sink
nodes can specify a single node or set of nodes.\47\ This guideline is
not intended to preclude flowgate rights so long as they are designed
with the same hedging properties as an equivalent long-term point-to-
point right.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\46\ APPA states that, because ISO-NE offers only general
system-wide ARRs, there is no direct relationship between the ARRs
that a market participant receives and the FTRs that the market
participant may desire, given the location of its resources. See
Comments on Staff Paper of APPA, attached Concept Paper--Long-Term
Transmission Rights, at 16, n. 22.
\47\ It is thus possible to define a form of network service
that consists of a set of point-to-point rights, each of which
specifies a source, a sink and a megawatt quantity. This, however,
would differ from network service under the OATT, which does not
require the customer to reserve a specific amount of capacity
between its network resources and network loads.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
46. Section 217(b)(4) recognizes that there may be alternative
designs for long-term firm transmission rights.\48\ For many
transmission organizations and their market participants, the most
straightforward method to develop long-term firm transmission rights
would be to extend the term of the auction revenue rights or FTRs that
they currently allocate. These may require additional market rules,
such as modified creditworthiness standards. However, we do not
preclude alternative designs for long-term rights. Some possible
designs are compared in Section IV.C of this NOPR.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\48\ In particular, that provision states that the Commission
shall exercise its authority ``to enable load-serving entities to
secure firm transmission (or equivalent tradable or financial
rights) on a long-term basis'' (emphasis added).
Guideline (2): The long-term firm transmission right must
provide a hedge against locational marginal pricing congestion
charges (or other direct assignment of congestion costs) for the
period covered and quantity specified. Once allocated, the financial
coverage provided by the right should not be modified during its
term except in the case of extraordinary circumstances or through
voluntary agreement of both the holder of the right and the
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
transmission organization.
47. In most existing organized electricity markets, LMP is used to
manage congestion. The FTRs currently offered in the organized
electricity markets provide a hedge against these charges, but are only
offered in terms of one year or less. Because of this short term,
market participants with long-term power supply arrangements are at
risk of having the ARRs or FTRs that they are eligible for to hedge
congestion charges associated with delivery of that power prorated
during the course of the power supply arrangement. As noted above, one
criticism of the current FTR market rules is that the annual FTR
allocation may produce different results from year to year in the
quantity of FTRs allocated to eligible load-serving entities. APPA, for
example, argues that there is a need for a mechanism to keep long-term
firm transmission rights feasible in the ``out'' years.\49\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\49\ Comments on Staff Paper of APPA at 21.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
48. To address this concern, we propose that the transmission
organization ensure that the long-term firm transmission rights it
offers provide a hedge against congestion costs for the entire term of
the right, and for the
[[Page 6701]]
entire quantity of the right. In proposing that the financial coverage
offered by the long-term rights, once awarded, not be modified, we seek
to establish rights that provide a high degree of stability in terms of
payments from year to year, rather than subject to uncertainty over the
possibility of significant pro-rationing in the event of revenue
inadequacy. We interpret the intent of section 217(b)(4) of the FPA to
be that the Commission ensure the availability in organized electricity
markets of long-term firm transmission rights that provide price
stability to load-serving entities with long-term power supply
arrangements used to satisfy their service obligations.
49. When conditions arise that cause the transmission organization
to receive congestion revenues that are not sufficient to meet payment
obligations to FTR holders, the transmission organization must have in
place a