Before Commissioners: Joseph T. Kelliher, Chairman; Nora Mead Brownell, and Suedeen G. Kelly; Natural Gas Pipeline Negotiated Rate Policies and Practices; Order on Rehearing and Clarification, 4362-4364 [E6-941]
Download as PDF
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with NOTICES
4362
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 17 / Thursday, January 26, 2006 / Notices
generation, transmission constraints,
proposed new transmission
construction, demand response and new
generation projects as they relate to
PJM’s current and forecasted reliability
needs. The Commission further requests
that PJM summarize the main
components of RPM. (A representative
of PJM will be present during each
subsequent panel to answer questions,
but PJM will not make any further
independent presentation.)
PJM Interconnection, LLC: Audrey A.
Zibelman, Executive Vice President &
Chief Operating Officer, and Andrew
L. Ott, Vice President—Markets.
Panel 1:
10:45 a.m.–1 p.m.
Whether the current capacity
obligation construct within PJM’s
market design provides for just and
reasonable wholesale power prices in
the PJM footprint, at levels that provide
adequate assurance that necessary
resources will be provided to assure
reliability, or whether changes must be
made to that capacity obligation
construct.
Dayton Power and Light Company: Gary
Stephenson, Vice President,
Commercial Operations.
Edison Mission Companies: Reem
Fahey, Vice President, Market Policy.
Exelon Corporation: John F. Young,
Executive Vice President, Finance and
Markets and Chief Financial Officer.
FirstEnergy Service Company: Michael
R. Beiting, Associate General Counsel.
Public Utilities Commission of Ohio:
Hon. Alan R. Schriber, Chair.
Pennsylvania Public Utility
Commission: Andrew S. Tubbs,
Counsel.
Maryland Office of People’s Counsel:
William Fields, Senior Assistant
People’s Counsel.
Lunch
1 p.m.–2 p.m.
Panel 2:
2 p.m.–3:30 p.m.
Whether PJM’s RPM proposal would
provide for just and reasonable
wholesale power prices in the PJM
footprint, at levels that provide adequate
reliability, or whether changes must be
made to the proposal to meet those
goals.
PSEG Companies: Gary R. Sorenson,
Managing Director, Energy
Operations, PSEG Power LLC.
Reliant Energy, Inc.: Neal A. Fitch,
Senior Regulatory Specialist.
Mirant Parties/NRG Companies/
Williams: Robert B. Stoddard, Vice
President, Charles River Associates,
International.
Constellation Energy Group: Marjorie R.
Philips, Vice President, Regulatory
Affairs.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:10 Jan 25, 2006
Jkt 205001
National Grid USA: Mary Ellen
Paravalos, Director of Regulatory
Policy.
PJM Industrial Customer Coalition:
Robert A. Weishaar, McNees, Wallace
and Nurick, LLC.
New Jersey Board of Public Utilities:
Hon. Frederick T. Butler,
Commissioner.
Virginia Office of the Attorney General:
Seth W. Brown, Manager of
Transmission Services, GDS
Associates, Inc.
Panel 3:
3:30 p.m.–4:45 p.m.
Whether an alternative approach to
RPM is necessary to ensure just and
reasonable wholesale power prices in
the PJM footprint.
American Electric Power Service Co.: J.
Craig Baker, Senior Vice President,
Regulatory Services.
Morgan Stanley Capital Group Inc.:
James Sheffield, Vice President.
Coalition of Consumers for Reliability:
Edward D. Tatum, Jr., Assistant Vice
President, Rates and Regulation, Old
Dominion Electric Cooperative
(ODEC).
PPL Parties: Thomas Hyzinski, Manager,
ISO Markets Development and
Regulatory Policy.
Delaware Public Service Commission:
Hon. Arnetta McRae, Chair.
Closing remarks by Chairman Joseph T.
Kelliher:
4:45 p.m.–5 p.m.
Each panelist should provide a
presentation of no more than five
minutes, and the Commissioners may
ask questions at the conclusion of each
presentation. If time permits, the
audience may also ask questions of the
panelists at the conclusion of the
Commissioners’ questions. Panelists
wishing to distribute copies of their
presentation should bring 100 or more
hard copies to the conference for
distribution. Any such presentation will
be placed into the record for these
dockets. Any panelist requiring
particular software or other technical
facilities for a presentation should
contact FERC staff no later than January
27, 2006. All parties to this proceeding
may file comments on the technical
conference by close of business on
February 23, 2006.
[FR Doc. E6–953 Filed 1–25–06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
PO 00000
Frm 00017
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission
[Docket No. PL02–6–001]
Before Commissioners: Joseph T.
Kelliher, Chairman; Nora Mead
Brownell, and Suedeen G. Kelly;
Natural Gas Pipeline Negotiated Rate
Policies and Practices; Order on
Rehearing and Clarification
Issued January 19, 2006.
1. Several parties 1 request rehearing
and or clarification of the Commission’s
July 9, 2003 Order in the captioned
docket.2 In that order, the Commission
modified its negotiated rate policies so
that pipelines would no longer be
permitted to enter into negotiated rate
agreements that utilize basis
differentials as a transportation pricing
mechanism.
Background
2. In 1996, the Commission permitted
pipelines the opportunity to use
negotiated rates as an alternative to costof-service ratemaking.3 Under the
negotiated rate program, the pipeline
and a shipper may negotiate rates that
vary from a pipeline’s otherwise
applicable cost-of-service tariff rate.
However, a cost-based recourse rate
must be maintained by the pipeline for
customers that prefer traditional cost-ofservice rates and to mitigate market
power if the pipeline unilaterally
demands excess prices or withholds
service. The Commission determined
that the availability of the recourse rate
would prevent pipelines from exercising
market power by assuring that the
customer always has the option of
purchasing capacity at the just and
reasonable tariff rate if the pipeline
unilaterally demands excessive prices.4
1 Parties requesting rehearing or clarification are:
Illinois Municipal Gas Agency; Natural Gas
Pipeline Company of America and Kinder Morgan
Interstate Gas Transmission, LLC; CenterPoint
Energy Gas Transmission Company; Northern
Natural Gas Company; MidAmerican Energy
Company; BP America Production Company and BP
Energy Company; American Public Gas Association;
Williston Basin Interstate Pipeline Company; ANR
Pipeline Company and Tennessee Gas Pipeline
Company; American Gas Association; and Interstate
Natural Gas Association of America.
2 Natural Gas Pipeline Negotiated Rates Policies
and Practices, 104 FERC ¶ 61,134 (2003)(July 2003
Order).
3 The Commission’s negotiated rate policies were
originally established in Alternatives to Traditional
Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for Natural Gas
Pipelines, Regulation of Negotiated Transportation
Services, 74 FERC ¶ 61,076, order on clarification,
74 FERC ¶ 61,194, order on reh’g, 75 FERC ¶ 61,024
(1996).
4 Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ¶
E:\FR\FM\26JAN1.SGM
26JAN1
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 17 / Thursday, January 26, 2006 / Notices
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with NOTICES
In order to implement a negotiated rate
transaction, a pipeline must file either
the negotiated rate agreement itself or a
tariff sheet describing the agreement,
since, unlike a discount, a negotiated
rate is a material deviation from the
pipeline’s tariff.5 Until the issuance of
the modification of the policy statement,
the Commission permitted pipelines to
use price indices in pricing their
negotiated rate transactions.6 However,
on July 9, 2003, the Commission issued
a policy statement, revising its
negotiated rate policies so that the use
of gas basis differentials would no
longer be permitted.7
3. In its modification of the original
negotiated rate policy statement, the
Commission stated that it was
concerned that the use of basis
differentials could provide pipelines
with an incentive to withhold capacity
in an attempt to manipulate the gas
commodity market to widen the
differences between the relevant price
indices. The Commission explained that
the manner in which it regulated
transportation rates would ordinarily
minimize any incentive for a pipeline to
withhold capacity. That was because
even if a pipeline created scarcity, it
could not charge rates above the
maximum just and reasonable rate based
upon the pipeline’s cost of service.
Therefore, if a pipeline withheld
capacity, its revenues would not
increase.8 However, because the
negotiated rate policy permits a pipeline
to charge a rate above the maximum cost
of service rate, a pipeline charging
negotiated rates tied to basis
differentials could increase its revenues
by withholding capacity in order to
61,076 at 61,238–242, order on clarification, 74
FERC ¶ 61,194, order on reh’g, 75 FERC ¶ 61,024
(1996).
5 NorAm Gas Transmission Co., 75 FERC ¶ 61,091
at 61,309, order on reh’g, 77 FERC ¶ 61,011 at
61,037 (1996).
6 Before the modification of the Commission’s
negotiated rate policies, pipelines were permitted to
negotiate pricing mechanisms for transportation
based upon the difference between gas commodity
price indices at different points (referred to here as
the ‘‘basis differential’’). These gas commodity price
indices, when used as a negotiated pricing
mechanism, usually reflect gas prices at different
points such as at gas basins or certain receipt and
delivery points and citygates. The pricing
mechanism is based upon the difference between
the gas price indices at the two points. The
foundation for this pricing mechanism is that the
difference in price between two points, as shown
by the respective price indices, reflects the value of
transportation between the two points.
7 In its July 9, 2003 Order, the Commission also
clarified its filing requirements for negotiated rates,
particularly where the negotiated agreement
contained material deviations from the form of
service agreement. July 2003 Order, 104 FERC at P
31–34.
8 Id. at P 17–18.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:10 Jan 25, 2006
Jkt 205001
increase the relevant basis differentials.9
The Commission concluded that pricing
mechanisms that invest pipelines with
an incentive to use market power to
manipulate the commodity price of gas
would hinder the Commission’s attempt
to maintain and improve the
competitive natural gas market.
Therefore, the Commission prohibited
the use of natural gas indices in pricing
negotiated rate transactions.10
4. In reaching this determination, the
Commission recognized that these basis
differential pricing mechanisms are
useful in permitting parties to the
negotiated agreement to engage in
various hedging programs and gas
supply cost-management programs, but
the Commission found that such
flexibility could not justify the
increased risk of market manipulation
faced by market participants. The
Commission determined that this
limitation of flexibility was offset by the
fact that negotiated rates may still be
based upon a virtually unlimited
number of indices or other mechanisms
that have no relationship with the
commodity price of gas, and are,
therefore, not as subject to manipulation
through the withholding of pipeline
capacity.
5. Subsequent to its modification of
the negotiated rate policy statement, the
Commission modified its selective
discounting policies which had
prohibited the use of formulas in
discounted rates. On remand from the
court in Northern Natural Gas
Company, the Commission determined
that it would permit the use of formulas,
including those tied to basis
differentials in discounted rate
transactions.11 In reaching this
determination, the Commission stated
that its concerns about the use of basis
differentials in negotiated rates were not
present to the same degree in the
context of discounted rates. The
Commission reasoned that because
discounted rates, unlike negotiated
rates, were capped by the pipeline’s
maximum cost-of-service rate, use of
pricing differentials in discounted rates
did not present the pipeline with an
incentive to withhold capacity in order
to achieve higher revenues. Given this
fact, the Commission found that the
benefits of allowing the use of basis
differentials to price transportation
service in discounted rate agreements
outweighed any potential harm.
9 Id.
at P 19–20.
at P 23–24.
11 Northern Natural Gas Co., 105 FERC ¶ 61,299
(2003).
10 Id.
PO 00000
Frm 00018
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
4363
Discussion
6. A number of parties have filed
requests for rehearing of the revised
policy statement, objecting not only to
the revised policy concerning the use of
pricing differentials in negotiated rates
but also to other aspects of the revised
policy statement. The revised policy
statement is not a final action of the
Commission but an expression of policy
intent. As the U.S. Court of Appeals for
the District of Columbia Circuit has
held, a statement of policy ‘‘is not
finally determinative of the issues or
rights to which it is addressed’’; rather,
it only ‘‘announces the agency’s
tentative intentions for the future.’’ 12
Therefore, the parties are not aggrieved
by the revised policy statement, and
rehearing does not lie.13 The
Commission accordingly dismisses the
requests for rehearing.
7. Nevertheless, the Commission has
further considered the basis differential
issue, and has determined to modify its
negotiated rate policy to again permit
the use of gas commodity basis
differentials in negotiated rate
transactions without regard to the
existence of a revenue cap. The
Commission finds that a generic policy
against the use of gas basis differentials
in negotiated rate transactions is overly
restrictive, given the benefits such
pricing mechanisms yield and the fact
that there are other less restrictive
means to ensure that the pipelines do
not utilize market power to influence
the gas commodity market.
8. The Commission has long
recognized that the ‘‘commodity and
transportation markets are closely
interdependent in the natural gas
business with changes in one market
affecting the other.’’ 14 Further, the
Commission itself has stated that the
market conditions it has fostered create
a ‘‘market-driven value for
transportation * * * the implicit value
of transportation between two such
points is the spot price of gas at the
delivery point minus the spot price of
gas at the receipt point.’’ 15 Thus, the
12 Pacific Gas & Electric Co. v. FPC, 506 F.2d 33,
38 (D.C. Cir. 1974).
13 See Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines, 75 FERC ¶
61,024 at 61,076, citing, American Gas Association
v. FERC, 888 F.2d 136 (1989); Interstate Natural Gas
Pipeline Rate Design, 47 FERC ¶ 61,295 (1985),
order on reh’g, 48 FERC ¶ 61,122 at 61,442 (1989).
14 Order No. 637 at 31,258.
15 Id. at 33,436. In this vein, the Commission also
added that, ‘‘The implicit price for transportation
represents the most any shipper purchasing
delivered gas at a downstream market would pay
to move gas from the lower priced market to the
higher priced market. For instance, the implicit
value of transportation between the Henry Hub and
E:\FR\FM\26JAN1.SGM
Continued
26JAN1
4364
Federal Register / Vol. 71, No. 17 / Thursday, January 26, 2006 / Notices
rwilkins on PROD1PC63 with NOTICES
use of basis differentials to price
transportation services enables the
pipeline to negotiate market sensitive
transportation rates, consistent with the
Commission’s goal of encouraging
competition in the transportation
capacity market. Such market sensitive
rates provide greater efficiency in the
production and distribution of gas
across the pipeline grid. For example,
such rates minimize the distorting effect
of transportation costs on producer
decisions concerning exploration and
production. They also help the pipeline
to more accurately assess when new
construction is needed, because a high
basis differential indicates a need for
more capacity between the points.16
9. In implementing its policy against
the use of gas basis differentials, the
Commission recognized that the use of
basis differential pricing mechanisms
yielded significant benefits, but stated
that such increased flexibility could not
justify the increased risk that the
pipelines may utilize their market
power over transportation service to
manipulate the commodity market to
increase basis differentials.17
10. However, in the Commission’s
view, the ability of pipelines to
manipulate the gas commodity market is
tempered by several factors. First, part
284 of the Commission’s regulations and
its policies provide that pipelines must
sell capacity to maximum rate bidders.18
Therefore, pipelines may not hoard
desired capacity in an attempt to widen
basis differential without violating the
Commission’s existing regulations.
the Chicago city gate was $.07 in September 1999
(the difference between the $2.67 price for gas in
Chicago and the $2.60 price at Henry Hub).’’ Id. at
31,271. The difference between the downstream
delivered gas price and the market price at
upstream market centers in the production area
shows the market value of transportation service
between those two points. As the Commission
observed in Order No. 637, ‘‘gas commodity
markets now determine the economic value of
pipeline transportation services in many parts of
the country. Thus, even as FERC has sought to
isolate pipeline services from commodity sales, it
is within the commodity markets that one can see
revealed the true price for gas transportation.’’
Order No. 637 at 31,274 (quoting M. Barcella, How
Commodity Markets Drive Gas Pipeline Values,
Public Utilities Fortnightly, February 1, 1998 at 24–
25).
16 See Policy for Selective Discounting by Natural
Gas Pipelines, 111 FERC ¶ 61,309 at P 32–37 (2005).
17 July 2003 Order, 104 FERC at P 23.
18 See Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 91 FERC
¶ 61,053 (2000), order on reh’g, 94 FERC ¶ 61,097
(2001), aff’d, Process Gas Consumers Group v.
FERC, 292 F.3d 831 (D.C. Cir. 2002). Moreover, in
Order No. 637–A, the Commission reaffirmed its
position that the recourse rate effectively mitigates
pipeline market power by stating that ‘‘[T]he
requirement that a pipeline sell its capacity at the
regulated maximum rate prevents tacit collusion
between the pipeline and the shipper to withhold
capacity to raise price above the ceiling * * *’’ Id.
at 31,564.
VerDate Aug<31>2005
16:10 Jan 25, 2006
Jkt 205001
Second, pipelines must file all
negotiated rate agreements with the
Commission for approval. Those filing
negotiated rate contracts are noticed for
comments giving all interested parties
an opportunity to raise whatever
concerns they have with the agreement.
Moreover, the Commission has access to
information regarding available pipeline
capacity and daily gas basis
differentials. This allows it to monitor
the transactions to determine if the
pipeline is withholding capacity in
order to increase the gas commodity
basis differential. Moreover, subsequent
to the modification of the negotiated
rate policy statement, Congress enacted
new legislation designed to prohibit
manipulation of the gas transportation
markets. Concurrently with the issuance
of this order, the Commission is
approving a final rule in Docket No.
RM06–3–000 implementing new section
4A of the Natural Gas Act.19
11. Given these facts and the benefits
of the use of basis differential pricing
mechanisms, the Commission finds that
it is not necessary to ban the use of such
mechanisms in order to mitigate the
potential for manipulation of the market
for either transportation or gas sales.
Rather, the Commission will permit the
use of gas commodity basis differentials
and will continue to investigate, on a
case by case basis, allegations of market
manipulation or attempted market
manipulation by pipelines. In this
manner, the flexibility benefits of this
pricing mechanism may be retained
while the Commission maintains the
integrity of the marketplace.
The Commission orders:
(A) The requests for rehearing of the
Commission’s July 9, 2003 Order are
dismissed as discussed in the body of
this order.
(B) The Commission’s July 9, 2003
Order is clarified as discussed in the
body of this order.
19 Section 315 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005
added the following provision to the Natural Gas
Act:
Prohibition on Market Manipulation
SEC. 4A. It shall be unlawful for any entity,
directly or indirectly, to use or employ, in
connection with the purchase or sale of natural gas
or the purchase or sale of transportation services
subject to the jurisdiction of the Commission, any
manipulative or deceptive device or contrivance (as
those terms are used in section 10(b) of the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (15 U.S.C. 78j(b)))
in contravention of such rules and regulations as
the Commission may prescribe as necessary in the
public interest or for the protection of natural gas
ratepayers. Nothing in this section shall be
construed to create a private right of action.
Energy Policy Act of 2005, Pub. L. No. 109–58,
§ 315, 119 Stat. 594, (2005).
PO 00000
Frm 00019
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
By the Commission.
Magalie R. Salas,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. E6–941 Filed 1–25–06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717–01–P
ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION
AGENCY
[FRL–8025–3]
Proposed CERCLA Administrative
Settlement Agreement for the
Bountiful/Woods Cross/5th South Pce
Plume NPL Site, in Woods Cross,
Davis County, UT
Environmental Protection
Agency (EPA).
ACTION: Notice and request for public
comment.
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: In accordance with the
requirements of section 122(h)(1) of the
Comprehensive Environmental
Response, Compensation, and Liability
Act, as amended (‘‘CERCLA’’), 42 U.S.C.
9622(h)(1), notice is hereby given of the
proposed administrative settlement
under section 122(h) of CERCLA, 42
U.S.C. 9622(h), between EPA and W.S.
Hatch Company and Jack B. Kelley, Inc.
(‘‘Settling Parties’’) regarding the W.S.
Hatch facility (the ‘‘Facility’’). The
property which is the subject of this
proposed Settlement Agreement is a
parcel of land approximately three acres
in size and is located at approximately
643 South and 800 West in Woods
Cross, Davis County, Utah. The terms of
the proposed Administrative Settlement
Agreement, (the ‘‘Settlement’’), are
intended to resolve the Settling Parties’
liability at the Site for all response costs
incurred and paid, or to be incurred and
paid, by EPA in connection with the
work performed at the Site as provided
for in the Settlement.
W.S. Hatch Company, a subsidiary of
Jack B. Kelley, Inc., is the owner of a
parcel of land which has been impacted
by business operations at the Facility
and is included within the defined
boundaries of the Site. The proposed
Settlement will resolve the Settling
Parties’ liability under section 107(a)(1)
of CERCLA, 42 U.S.C. 9607(a)(1). EPA
has performed an ability to pay analysis
of Settling Parties’ financial capacity.
Under the terms of the proposed
Settlement, W.S. Hatch Company agrees
to pay $450,000, plus interest, to EPA
over five installment payments, and Jack
B. Kelley, Inc. agrees to pay the
principal sum of $40,000 to EPA. In
exchange, the Settling Parties will settle
their liability for all response costs
incurred and paid, or to be incurred and
E:\FR\FM\26JAN1.SGM
26JAN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 71, Number 17 (Thursday, January 26, 2006)]
[Notices]
[Pages 4362-4364]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: E6-941]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
[Docket No. PL02-6-001]
Before Commissioners: Joseph T. Kelliher, Chairman; Nora Mead
Brownell, and Suedeen G. Kelly; Natural Gas Pipeline Negotiated Rate
Policies and Practices; Order on Rehearing and Clarification
Issued January 19, 2006.
1. Several parties \1\ request rehearing and or clarification of
the Commission's July 9, 2003 Order in the captioned docket.\2\ In that
order, the Commission modified its negotiated rate policies so that
pipelines would no longer be permitted to enter into negotiated rate
agreements that utilize basis differentials as a transportation pricing
mechanism.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ Parties requesting rehearing or clarification are: Illinois
Municipal Gas Agency; Natural Gas Pipeline Company of America and
Kinder Morgan Interstate Gas Transmission, LLC; CenterPoint Energy
Gas Transmission Company; Northern Natural Gas Company; MidAmerican
Energy Company; BP America Production Company and BP Energy Company;
American Public Gas Association; Williston Basin Interstate Pipeline
Company; ANR Pipeline Company and Tennessee Gas Pipeline Company;
American Gas Association; and Interstate Natural Gas Association of
America.
\2\ Natural Gas Pipeline Negotiated Rates Policies and
Practices, 104 FERC ] 61,134 (2003)(July 2003 Order).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Background
2. In 1996, the Commission permitted pipelines the opportunity to
use negotiated rates as an alternative to cost-of-service
ratemaking.\3\ Under the negotiated rate program, the pipeline and a
shipper may negotiate rates that vary from a pipeline's otherwise
applicable cost-of-service tariff rate. However, a cost-based recourse
rate must be maintained by the pipeline for customers that prefer
traditional cost-of-service rates and to mitigate market power if the
pipeline unilaterally demands excess prices or withholds service. The
Commission determined that the availability of the recourse rate would
prevent pipelines from exercising market power by assuring that the
customer always has the option of purchasing capacity at the just and
reasonable tariff rate if the pipeline unilaterally demands excessive
prices.\4\
[[Page 4363]]
In order to implement a negotiated rate transaction, a pipeline must
file either the negotiated rate agreement itself or a tariff sheet
describing the agreement, since, unlike a discount, a negotiated rate
is a material deviation from the pipeline's tariff.\5\ Until the
issuance of the modification of the policy statement, the Commission
permitted pipelines to use price indices in pricing their negotiated
rate transactions.\6\ However, on July 9, 2003, the Commission issued a
policy statement, revising its negotiated rate policies so that the use
of gas basis differentials would no longer be permitted.\7\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ The Commission's negotiated rate policies were originally
established in Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service
Ratemaking for Natural Gas Pipelines, Regulation of Negotiated
Transportation Services, 74 FERC ] 61,076, order on clarification,
74 FERC ] 61,194, order on reh'g, 75 FERC ] 61,024 (1996).
\4\ Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for
Natural Gas Pipelines, 74 FERC ] 61,076 at 61,238-242, order on
clarification, 74 FERC ] 61,194, order on reh'g, 75 FERC ] 61,024
(1996).
\5\ NorAm Gas Transmission Co., 75 FERC ] 61,091 at 61,309,
order on reh'g, 77 FERC ] 61,011 at 61,037 (1996).
\6\ Before the modification of the Commission's negotiated rate
policies, pipelines were permitted to negotiate pricing mechanisms
for transportation based upon the difference between gas commodity
price indices at different points (referred to here as the ``basis
differential''). These gas commodity price indices, when used as a
negotiated pricing mechanism, usually reflect gas prices at
different points such as at gas basins or certain receipt and
delivery points and citygates. The pricing mechanism is based upon
the difference between the gas price indices at the two points. The
foundation for this pricing mechanism is that the difference in
price between two points, as shown by the respective price indices,
reflects the value of transportation between the two points.
\7\ In its July 9, 2003 Order, the Commission also clarified its
filing requirements for negotiated rates, particularly where the
negotiated agreement contained material deviations from the form of
service agreement. July 2003 Order, 104 FERC at P 31-34.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
3. In its modification of the original negotiated rate policy
statement, the Commission stated that it was concerned that the use of
basis differentials could provide pipelines with an incentive to
withhold capacity in an attempt to manipulate the gas commodity market
to widen the differences between the relevant price indices. The
Commission explained that the manner in which it regulated
transportation rates would ordinarily minimize any incentive for a
pipeline to withhold capacity. That was because even if a pipeline
created scarcity, it could not charge rates above the maximum just and
reasonable rate based upon the pipeline's cost of service. Therefore,
if a pipeline withheld capacity, its revenues would not increase.\8\
However, because the negotiated rate policy permits a pipeline to
charge a rate above the maximum cost of service rate, a pipeline
charging negotiated rates tied to basis differentials could increase
its revenues by withholding capacity in order to increase the relevant
basis differentials.\9\ The Commission concluded that pricing
mechanisms that invest pipelines with an incentive to use market power
to manipulate the commodity price of gas would hinder the Commission's
attempt to maintain and improve the competitive natural gas market.
Therefore, the Commission prohibited the use of natural gas indices in
pricing negotiated rate transactions.\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\8\ Id. at P 17-18.
\9\ Id. at P 19-20.
\10\ Id. at P 23-24.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
4. In reaching this determination, the Commission recognized that
these basis differential pricing mechanisms are useful in permitting
parties to the negotiated agreement to engage in various hedging
programs and gas supply cost-management programs, but the Commission
found that such flexibility could not justify the increased risk of
market manipulation faced by market participants. The Commission
determined that this limitation of flexibility was offset by the fact
that negotiated rates may still be based upon a virtually unlimited
number of indices or other mechanisms that have no relationship with
the commodity price of gas, and are, therefore, not as subject to
manipulation through the withholding of pipeline capacity.
5. Subsequent to its modification of the negotiated rate policy
statement, the Commission modified its selective discounting policies
which had prohibited the use of formulas in discounted rates. On remand
from the court in Northern Natural Gas Company, the Commission
determined that it would permit the use of formulas, including those
tied to basis differentials in discounted rate transactions.\11\ In
reaching this determination, the Commission stated that its concerns
about the use of basis differentials in negotiated rates were not
present to the same degree in the context of discounted rates. The
Commission reasoned that because discounted rates, unlike negotiated
rates, were capped by the pipeline's maximum cost-of-service rate, use
of pricing differentials in discounted rates did not present the
pipeline with an incentive to withhold capacity in order to achieve
higher revenues. Given this fact, the Commission found that the
benefits of allowing the use of basis differentials to price
transportation service in discounted rate agreements outweighed any
potential harm.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\11\ Northern Natural Gas Co., 105 FERC ] 61,299 (2003).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Discussion
6. A number of parties have filed requests for rehearing of the
revised policy statement, objecting not only to the revised policy
concerning the use of pricing differentials in negotiated rates but
also to other aspects of the revised policy statement. The revised
policy statement is not a final action of the Commission but an
expression of policy intent. As the U.S. Court of Appeals for the
District of Columbia Circuit has held, a statement of policy ``is not
finally determinative of the issues or rights to which it is
addressed''; rather, it only ``announces the agency's tentative
intentions for the future.'' \12\ Therefore, the parties are not
aggrieved by the revised policy statement, and rehearing does not
lie.\13\ The Commission accordingly dismisses the requests for
rehearing.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ Pacific Gas & Electric Co. v. FPC, 506 F.2d 33, 38 (D.C.
Cir. 1974).
\13\ See Alternatives to Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking
for Natural Gas Pipelines, 75 FERC ] 61,024 at 61,076, citing,
American Gas Association v. FERC, 888 F.2d 136 (1989); Interstate
Natural Gas Pipeline Rate Design, 47 FERC ] 61,295 (1985), order on
reh'g, 48 FERC ] 61,122 at 61,442 (1989).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
7. Nevertheless, the Commission has further considered the basis
differential issue, and has determined to modify its negotiated rate
policy to again permit the use of gas commodity basis differentials in
negotiated rate transactions without regard to the existence of a
revenue cap. The Commission finds that a generic policy against the use
of gas basis differentials in negotiated rate transactions is overly
restrictive, given the benefits such pricing mechanisms yield and the
fact that there are other less restrictive means to ensure that the
pipelines do not utilize market power to influence the gas commodity
market.
8. The Commission has long recognized that the ``commodity and
transportation markets are closely interdependent in the natural gas
business with changes in one market affecting the other.'' \14\
Further, the Commission itself has stated that the market conditions it
has fostered create a ``market-driven value for transportation * * *
the implicit value of transportation between two such points is the
spot price of gas at the delivery point minus the spot price of gas at
the receipt point.'' \15\ Thus, the
[[Page 4364]]
use of basis differentials to price transportation services enables the
pipeline to negotiate market sensitive transportation rates, consistent
with the Commission's goal of encouraging competition in the
transportation capacity market. Such market sensitive rates provide
greater efficiency in the production and distribution of gas across the
pipeline grid. For example, such rates minimize the distorting effect
of transportation costs on producer decisions concerning exploration
and production. They also help the pipeline to more accurately assess
when new construction is needed, because a high basis differential
indicates a need for more capacity between the points.\16\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ Order No. 637 at 31,258.
\15\ Id. at 33,436. In this vein, the Commission also added
that, ``The implicit price for transportation represents the most
any shipper purchasing delivered gas at a downstream market would
pay to move gas from the lower priced market to the higher priced
market. For instance, the implicit value of transportation between
the Henry Hub and the Chicago city gate was $.07 in September 1999
(the difference between the $2.67 price for gas in Chicago and the
$2.60 price at Henry Hub).'' Id. at 31,271. The difference between
the downstream delivered gas price and the market price at upstream
market centers in the production area shows the market value of
transportation service between those two points. As the Commission
observed in Order No. 637, ``gas commodity markets now determine the
economic value of pipeline transportation services in many parts of
the country. Thus, even as FERC has sought to isolate pipeline
services from commodity sales, it is within the commodity markets
that one can see revealed the true price for gas transportation.''
Order No. 637 at 31,274 (quoting M. Barcella, How Commodity Markets
Drive Gas Pipeline Values, Public Utilities Fortnightly, February 1,
1998 at 24-25).
\16\ See Policy for Selective Discounting by Natural Gas
Pipelines, 111 FERC ] 61,309 at P 32-37 (2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
9. In implementing its policy against the use of gas basis
differentials, the Commission recognized that the use of basis
differential pricing mechanisms yielded significant benefits, but
stated that such increased flexibility could not justify the increased
risk that the pipelines may utilize their market power over
transportation service to manipulate the commodity market to increase
basis differentials.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\17\ July 2003 Order, 104 FERC at P 23.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
10. However, in the Commission's view, the ability of pipelines to
manipulate the gas commodity market is tempered by several factors.
First, part 284 of the Commission's regulations and its policies
provide that pipelines must sell capacity to maximum rate bidders.\18\
Therefore, pipelines may not hoard desired capacity in an attempt to
widen basis differential without violating the Commission's existing
regulations. Second, pipelines must file all negotiated rate agreements
with the Commission for approval. Those filing negotiated rate
contracts are noticed for comments giving all interested parties an
opportunity to raise whatever concerns they have with the agreement.
Moreover, the Commission has access to information regarding available
pipeline capacity and daily gas basis differentials. This allows it to
monitor the transactions to determine if the pipeline is withholding
capacity in order to increase the gas commodity basis differential.
Moreover, subsequent to the modification of the negotiated rate policy
statement, Congress enacted new legislation designed to prohibit
manipulation of the gas transportation markets. Concurrently with the
issuance of this order, the Commission is approving a final rule in
Docket No. RM06-3-000 implementing new section 4A of the Natural Gas
Act.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ See Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 91 FERC ] 61,053 (2000),
order on reh'g, 94 FERC ] 61,097 (2001), aff'd, Process Gas
Consumers Group v. FERC, 292 F.3d 831 (D.C. Cir. 2002). Moreover, in
Order No. 637-A, the Commission reaffirmed its position that the
recourse rate effectively mitigates pipeline market power by stating
that ``[T]he requirement that a pipeline sell its capacity at the
regulated maximum rate prevents tacit collusion between the pipeline
and the shipper to withhold capacity to raise price above the
ceiling * * *'' Id. at 31,564.
\19\ Section 315 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 added the
following provision to the Natural Gas Act:
Prohibition on Market Manipulation
SEC. 4A. It shall be unlawful for any entity, directly or
indirectly, to use or employ, in connection with the purchase or
sale of natural gas or the purchase or sale of transportation
services subject to the jurisdiction of the Commission, any
manipulative or deceptive device or contrivance (as those terms are
used in section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (15
U.S.C. 78j(b))) in contravention of such rules and regulations as
the Commission may prescribe as necessary in the public interest or
for the protection of natural gas ratepayers. Nothing in this
section shall be construed to create a private right of action.
Energy Policy Act of 2005, Pub. L. No. 109-58, Sec. 315, 119
Stat. 594, (2005).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
11. Given these facts and the benefits of the use of basis
differential pricing mechanisms, the Commission finds that it is not
necessary to ban the use of such mechanisms in order to mitigate the
potential for manipulation of the market for either transportation or
gas sales. Rather, the Commission will permit the use of gas commodity
basis differentials and will continue to investigate, on a case by case
basis, allegations of market manipulation or attempted market
manipulation by pipelines. In this manner, the flexibility benefits of
this pricing mechanism may be retained while the Commission maintains
the integrity of the marketplace.
The Commission orders:
(A) The requests for rehearing of the Commission's July 9, 2003
Order are dismissed as discussed in the body of this order.
(B) The Commission's July 9, 2003 Order is clarified as discussed
in the body of this order.
By the Commission.
Magalie R. Salas,
Secretary.
[FR Doc. E6-941 Filed 1-25-06; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6717-01-P