Calculation of the Economic Benefit of Noncompliance in EPA's Civil Penalty Enforcement Cases, 50326-50345 [05-17033]
Download as PDF
50326
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
A. What Action Is EPA Taking?
We are notifying the public of a final
decision by the EAB on the Permit
Amendment issued by EPA Region 10
and EFSEC (‘‘Permitting Authorities’’)
pursuant to 40 CFR 52.21.
B. What Is the Background
Information?
The Facility will be a 660-megawatt
natural gas-fired combined cycle electric
generation facility located in Sumas,
Washington, about one-half mile south
of the Canadian border. The Facility
will combust only natural gas and will
employ selective catalytic reduction
(‘‘SCR’’) and catalytic oxidation
technology.
Both the Province of British Columbia
(‘‘Province’’) and Environment Canada,
Canada’s national environmental
protection agency, filed petitions for
review challenging the issuance of the
Original Permit. On September 6, 2002,
the Permitting Authorities jointly issued
the Original Permit to SE2 pursuant to
section 165 of the CAA, 42 U.S.C. 7475,
40 CFR 52.21, and the terms and
conditions of EFSEC’s delegation of
authority from EPA Region 10 under 40
CFR 52.21(u).
On March 25, 2003, the EAB issued
an order that denied the petitions for
review in part and remanded in part to
correct a typographical error that was
inadvertently retained from the draft
permit. The Original Permit
subsequently became effective on April
17, 2003 and remained in effect until
October 17, 2004.
On June 1, 2004, SE2 applied to the
EFSEC for an extension of the Original
Permit. On January 11, 2005, after
providing an opportunity for public
comments and holding a public hearing,
EFSEC approved the Permit
Amendment. On January 21, 2005, EPA
approved the Permit Amendment. The
Permit Amendment authorizes an 18month extension of the Original Permit.
Subsequent to issuance of the Permit
Amendment, the Province petitioned
the EAB for review of the Permit
Amendment.
C. What Did the EAB Decide?
The Province raised five main issues
in its petition for review: (1) SE2’s
application for permit extension was
untimely; (2) SE2’s application lacked
the required construction schedule; (3)
the best available control technology
(‘‘BACT’’) re-analysis for startup and
shutdown emissions was incomplete;
(4) the BACT analysis for nitrogen oxide
(‘‘NOX’’) emissions was inadequate; and
(5) the Permit Amendment should not
have been granted for an 18-month
period.
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
The EAB denied review of the
Province’s petition for review in its
entirety. First, the EAB concluded that
the Permitting Authorities did not err in
concluding that SE2’s permit extension
application was filed in a timely
manner. Specifically, the EAB found
that SE2 was not required to submit the
permit extension application six months
before expiration of the Original Permit.
Second, the EAB found that the
Province failed to demonstrate that the
Permitting Authorities clearly erred in
determining that SE2 provided a
construction schedule in its application.
Third, the EAB determined that the
Permitting Authorities conducted a
complete BACT re-analysis for startup
and shutdown emissions by reviewing
the Original Permit BACT analysis for
these emissions and concluding that
there was no new information that
would warrant any changes to the
analysis. Moreover, the EAB concluded
that the Province failed to demonstrate
why the Permitting Authorities’ BACT
analysis for NOX emissions was in error.
Finally, the EAB found that the
Permitting Authorities had discretion to
grant an 18-month extension of the
Original Permit and the Provice failed to
show why the Permitting Authorities’
decision to grant an 18-month extension
was in clear error. For these reasons, the
EAB denied the Province’s petition for
review of the Permit Amendment in its
entirety.
Pursuant to 40 CFR 124.19(f)(1), for
purposes of judicial review, final agency
action occurs when a final PSD permit
decision is issued and agency review
procedures are exhausted. This notice is
being published pursuant to 40 CFR
124.19(f)(2), which requires notice of
any final agency action regarding a PSD
permit to be published in the Federal
Register. This notice constitutes notice
of the final agency action denying
review of the Permit Amendment and
consequently, notice of the Permitting
Authorities’ issuance of PSD Permit No.
EFSEC/2001–02 Amendment 1 to SE2. If
available, judicial review of these
determinations under section 307(b)(1)
of the CAA may be sought by filing of
a petition for review in the United
States Court of Appeals for the Ninth
Circuit, within 60 days from the date on
which this notice is published in the
Federal Register. Under section
307(b)(2) of the Clean Air Act, this
determination shall not be subject to
later judicial review in any civil or
criminal proceedings for enforcement.
PO 00000
Frm 00036
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Dated: August 1, 2005.
Ronald A. Kreizenbeck,
Acting Regional Administrator, Region 10.
[FR Doc. 05–17029 Filed 8–25–05; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6560–50–M
ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION
AGENCY
[FRL–7960–3]
Calculation of the Economic Benefit of
Noncompliance in EPA’s Civil Penalty
Enforcement Cases
Environmental Protection
Agency (EPA).
ACTION: Notice of final action and
response to comment.
AGENCY:
SUMMARY: In a Federal Register notice
issued on October 9, 1996, the
Environmental Protection Agency
(‘‘EPA’’) requested comment on how it
calculates the economic benefit that
regulated entities obtain as a result of
violating environmental requirements.
EPA makes this calculation as a part of
establishing an appropriate penalty for
settlement purposes. The Agency’s
policy is that any civil penalty should
at least recapture the economic benefit
the violator has obtained through its
unlawful actions. Because enforcement
staff typically use the BEN (short for
benefit) computer model to perform the
economic benefit calculations, the
Agency requested comments on the BEN
model as well as the larger benefit
recapture issues. In a subsequent
Federal Register notice issued on June
18, 1999, EPA responded to the
comments on the October 1996 Federal
Register notice; provided advance
notice of the changes EPA proposed to
make to its benefit recapture approach
and the BEN computer model; and
requested a second round of comment of
those proposed changes. This notice
responds to the comments on the June
1999 notice and contains the changes
EPA will implement in its benefit
recapture program.
ADDRESSES: The Agency has dedicated a
page of its website to the computers
models the enforcement program uses to
addresses benefit recapture as well as
ability to pay claims and the evaluation
of the costs of supplemental
environmental projects (SEP’s). The web
address for those models is:
www.epa.gov/compliance/civil/
econmodels/.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: For
further information, contact Jonathan
Libber, Office of Civil Enforcement,
Special Litigation and Projects Division,
at (202) 564–6102, or through electronic
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
mail at libber.jonathan@epa.gov.
Government users (Federal, State, or
local) can also obtain assistance with
the model through the Agency’s toll-free
enforcement economics helpline at
(888) ECONSPT or through electronic
mail at benabel@indecon.com.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: In EPA’s
October 1996 Federal Register notice,
the Agency was considering changes in
three areas: (1) Broad economic benefit
recapture issues; (2) the BEN computer
model’s calculation methodology; and
(3) improving the BEN model’s userfriendliness. In regard to the broad
economic benefit recapture issues, the
Agency sought out any legitimate
alternatives to BEN, but found none. In
addition, EPA solicited comments on
the best way to determine the economic
benefit from the violator’s illegal
competitive advantage. The comments
confirmed our initial thoughts that a
model to handle such calculations was
infeasible. The Agency has instead
developed a draft conceptual framework
document for such cases, and has
initiated a peer review process by its
Science Advisory Board to examine this
type of benefit.
With regard to the BEN model’s
calculation methodology, the Agency is
making eight sets of changes that should
improve the model’s precision and
function. Although the combined effect
of these changes will affect individual
cases differently, the overall impact
across all EPA’s enforcement cases
should be insignificant. The two most
significant changes involve tailoring the
discount/compound rate to the case and
using a more precise inflation
adjustment. The new BEN model tailors
the discount rate to the period of
violation through the present, which the
prior version of the model was
incapable of doing. The new BEN model
also adjusts for inflation based on actual
historical month-by-month inflation
data, whereas the prior version simply
applied one single average rate for both
past inflation and projected inflation.
All of these changes reflect the Agency’s
consideration of both rounds of public
comments, as well as an academic peer
review that the Agency completed in
January of 2004. These reviews should
be available by within the next few
months on the Agency’s computer
models web page (see ADDRESSES
section above). Electronic copies of the
BEN computer model (which includes a
comprehensive help system) can be
downloaded from that same site.
The major change in improving the
BEN model’s user-friendliness is that
EPA has moved the model from the old
DOS operating system to the Windows
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
environment. This should address those
concerns that the model was
cumbersome. We have also established
a helpline to assist enforcement
personnel from Federal, State and local
governments in their use of the model.
This notice is organized as follows:
I. Background
A. Overview
B. EPA Policy and Guidance on
Recapturing the Economic Benefit of
Noncompliance
1. Policy Background
2. BEN Calculates the Economic Benefit
From Delayed and Avoided Pollution
Control Expenditures
3. Current Model Usage and Applicability
C. How a Firm Obtains an Economic
Benefit From Delaying and/or Avoiding
Compliance Costs
1. The Economic Benefit Components that
the BEN Model Measures
2. BEN and Cash Flow Analysis
II.Final Changes
A. Broad Economic Benefit Recapture
Issues
1. Alternatives to BEN
2. Illegal Competitive Advantage
B. The BEN Model’s Calculation
Methodology
1. Depreciation Method
2. Tax Rates
3. Differences in On-Time and Delay
Scenarios
4. Capital Equipment Replacement
5. Inflation Treatment
6. Discount/Compound Rate
7. Discounting/Compounding Methodology
8. Investment Tax Credit and Low-Interest
Financing
C. Improving the BEN Model’s Userfriendliness
1. Is BEN Too Complex to Operate?
2. Is the Information BEN Needs Difficult
or Expensive to Obtain?
D. Procedural Issues Regarding the Public
Comment Process
III. Response to Comments
A. Broad Economic Benefit Recapture
Issues
1. Alternatives to BEN
2. Illegal Competitive Advantage
3. Other Broad Economic Benefit Recapture
Issues
B. The BEN Model’s Calculation
Methodology
1. Discounting/Compounding
2. Inflation Adjustments
3. Other Technical Aspects
C. Improving the BEN Model’s UserFriendliness
1. Is BEN Too Complex to Operate?
2. Is the Information BEN Needs Difficult
or Expensive to Obtain?
3. Other Issues Affecting Use of BEN
D. Procedural Issues Regarding the Public
Comment Process
I. Background
A. Overview
One of EPA’s most important
responsibilities is to ensure that
regulated entities comply with Federal
environmental laws. These laws—and
PO 00000
Frm 00037
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50327
their implementing regulations—set
minimum standards for protecting
human health and achieving
environmental protection and for
achieving environmental protection
goals, such as clean air and clean water.
EPA upholds these laws through
vigorous enforcement actions that seek
to correct the violations and
appropriately penalize violators.
A cornerstone of the EPA’s civil
penalty program is at least recapturing
the economic benefit that a violator may
have gained from illegal activity.
Economic benefit recapture helps level
the economic playing field by
preventing violators from obtaining an
unfair financial advantage over their
competitors who make the necessary
expenditures for environmental
compliance. Penalties also serve as
incentives to protect the environment
and public health by encouraging
prompt compliance with environmental
requirements and the adoption of
pollution prevention and recycling
practices. Finally, appropriate penalties
help deter future violations by both the
penalized entity and by similarly
situated regulatees.
EPA has promulgated a generic civil
penalty policy, as well as specific
penalty policies tailored to suit the
needs of particular regulatory programs.
For example, one civil penalty policy
specifically addresses violations of the
Clean Water Act. The civil penalties that
EPA seeks usually embody two
components: gravity and economic
benefit. The gravity component reflects
the seriousness of the violation and is
generally determined through the
application of the appropriate EPA civil
penalty policy.
The economic benefit component, on
the other hand, focuses on the violator’s
economic gain from noncompliance,
i.e., the extent to which the violator is
financially better off because of its
noncompliance. This economic benefit
can accrue to the violator in three basic
ways: (1) Delaying necessary pollution
control expenditures; (2) avoiding
necessary pollution control
expenditures; and/or (3) obtaining an
illegal competitive advantage. The term
‘‘illegal competitive advantage’’ is a
broad catch-all category for economic
benefit that goes beyond that derived
from the mere delay and/or avoidance of
pollution control expenditures. For
example, the violator might have sold a
product that is entirely illegal (and
could not have been produced legally by
incurring any pollution control
expenditures).
The Agency designed the BEN
computer model in 1984 to calculate the
economic benefit from these first two
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50328
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
types of economic gain for settlement
purposes. BEN may not be appropriate
for all cases, and EPA’s regional offices
may use alternative approaches that
produce reasonably accurate benefit
calculations. For example, the pattern of
necessary pollution control
expenditures might be so complicated
that a customized spreadsheet
computation would be more appropriate
than BEN. Alternatively, the pattern of
expenditures might be so simple that a
mere table in a word processing
document would suffice. Nevertheless,
the Agency believes that in the vast
majority of cases BEN is by far the best
approach available for calculating
economic benefit derived from delayed
and/or avoided costs.
The Agency does not have a computer
model for calculating the benefit gained
from an illegal competitive advantage.
EPA considers such gains on a case-bycase basis.
B. EPA Policy and Guidance on
Recapturing the Economic Benefit of
Noncompliance
Since the BEN computer model’s
development in 1984, EPA staff have
used BEN extensively in generating
penalty figures for settlement purposes.
These figures reflect the economic
benefit a violator derived from delaying
and/or avoiding compliance with
environmental statutes.
1. Policy Background
Calculating a violator’s economic
benefit using the BEN computer model
is usually the first step in developing a
civil settlement penalty figure under the
Agency’s Policy on Civil Penalties
(PT.1–1) February 16, 1984, and A
Framework for Statute-Specific
Approaches to Penalty Assessments
(PT.1–2) February 16, 1984. The Agency
developed the BEN computer model to
assist in fulfilling one of the main goals
of the Policy on Civil Penalties: to
recover, at a minimum, the economic
benefit derived from noncompliance.
The BEN computer model is a tool
that is primarily intended to be used in
calculating economic benefit for
purposes of developing a settlement
penalty. In presenting economic benefit
testimony at a judicial trial or in an
administrative hearing, the Agency
relies on an expert in financial
economics to provide an independent
analysis of the economic benefit the
violator obtained from its violations,
reflecting the expert’s own analytical
approach as applied to the particular
facts of that case. Use of an expert in a
trial or hearing allows the parties the
opportunity to examine more closely the
analysis applied to the facts at issue,
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
since a computer model itself cannot be
deposed or cross-examined.1
2. BEN Calculates the Economic Benefit
From Delayed and Avoided Pollution
Control Expenditures
The BEN model calculates the
economic benefit from delaying and/or
avoiding required environmental
expenditures. Delayed costs can include
capital investments in pollution control
equipment, remediation of
environmental damages (e.g., removing
unpermitted fill material and restoring
wetlands), or one-time expenditures
required to comply with environmental
regulations (e.g., establishing a reporting
system, or purchasing land on which to
site a wastewater treatment facility).
Avoided costs typically include
operation and maintenance costs and/or
other annually recurring costs (e.g., offsite disposal of fluids from injection
wells), but can occasionally include
capital investments or one-time
expenditures. BEN does not calculate
the economic benefit that takes the form
of illegal competitive advantage. For
example, the BEN model is not the
appropriate method for calculating the
economic benefit derived from selling
DDT on the black market to U.S.
pesticide applicators.
3. Current Model Usage and
Applicability
The BEN model can be used in all
cases that have delayed and/or avoided
compliance costs. (The only exception
is Clean Air Act Section 120
enforcement actions, which require the
application of a specific computer
model.) EPA designed BEN to be easy to
use for people with little or no
background in economics, financial
analysis, or computers, although it is
also useful for those with such
backgrounds. Because the program
contains standard default values for
many of the variables needed to
calculate the economic benefit, BEN can
be run with only a small number of
required inputs from the user. The
program also allows the user to replace
those standard values with case-specific
information. The table below lists the
inputs to the BEN model, both the
required inputs and also those inputs
1 EPA designed the BEN model as a flexible tool
primarily for use in settlement negotiations; it is not
used, nor was it ever intended to function, as a rule.
An expert witness testifying for the government
may use the new Windows version of BEN as
appropriate, but the responsibility to determine the
economic benefit—as well as explain and defend
the results—still resides with the expert. That
expert may choose to use whatever analytical tool
(e.g., customized computer spreadsheets, the BEN
model, or even a calculator) deemed appropriate for
the particular calculations necessary in the case.
PO 00000
Frm 00038
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
with standard default values that may
be modified.
The BEN model can calculate
economic benefit for many types of
organizations: corporations,
partnerships, sole proprietorships, notfor-profit organizations, federal
facilities, and municipalities. BEN
customizes its standard values to the
entity type, as well as other aspects of
the case. The BEN inputs listed in the
table are discussed in detail in the
model’s help system.
Inputs for BEN
Required Inputs:
—Descriptive Information (case name,
office/agency, analyst name)
—Entity Type and State
—Competitive Advantage Questionnaire
—Penalty Payment Date
—Capital Investment (cost estimate and
estimate date)
—One-Time Nondepreciable
Expenditure (cost estimate and
estimate date)
—Annually Recurring Costs (cost
estimate and estimate date)
—Date of Initial Noncompliance
—Date of Compliance
Inputs with Standard Default Values
that May be Modified:
—Year-Specific Marginal Income Tax
Rates
—Discount/Compound Rate
—Cost Index for Inflation (specified
separately by compliance cost
component)
—Consideration of Future Capital
Replacement
—Useful Life of Capital Equipment
—Delayed v. Avoided (specified
separately for capital and one-time
nondepreciable)
—Tax Deductibility (of one-time
nondepreciable expenditure)
—Specific Cost Estimates (for on-time
and delay scenarios)
C. How a Firm Obtains an Economic
Benefit From Delaying and/or Avoiding
Compliance Costs
An organization’s compliance with
environmental regulations usually
entails a commitment of financial
resources, both initially (in the form of
a capital investment or one-time
expenditure) and over time (in the form
of continuing, annually recurring costs).
These expenditures should result in
better protection of public health or
environmental quality, but they are
unlikely to yield any direct economic
benefit (i.e., net gain) to the
organization. (Otherwise, and with the
assumption of some measure of
foresight, the organization should have
already committed the financial
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
resources, even in the absence of such
environmental regulations.) If these
financial resources are not used for
compliance, then they presumably are
invested in projects with an expected
financial return to the organization. This
concept of alternative investment—that
is, the amount the violator would
normally expect to make by investing in
something other than pollution
control—is the basis for calculating the
economic benefit of noncompliance.
In implementing EPA’s penalty
policies, the Agency invokes its
authority to assess penalties to remove
or neutralize the economic incentive to
violate environmental regulations. In
the absence of enforcement and
appropriate penalties, an organization’s
narrowly construed economic interest
would usually dictate delaying the
commitment of funds for compliance
with environmental regulations and
avoiding certain associated costs, such
as operation and maintenance expenses.
1. The Economic Benefit Components
That the BEN Model Measures
A violator may gain an economic
benefit from either delaying and/or
avoiding compliance costs. By delaying
compliance, the violator can earn a
return on the funds that should have
been committed to the capital
investment or one-time expenditure
required for pollution control
compliance. In other words, violators
have the opportunity to invest their
funds in projects other than those
required to comply with environmental
regulations. These other investments are
expected to generate a financial return,
as opposed to the required pollution
control investments that typically
generate no direct financial return for a
company. Thus, by delaying
compliance, the violator’s economic
benefit is the difference between
investing in pollution control and
investing in other projects.
A violator can also gain an economic
benefit from avoiding pollution control
costs. Avoided costs typically include
the continuing, annually recurring costs
that a violator would have incurred had
it complied with environmental
regulations on time (e.g., the costs of
labor, raw materials, energy, lease
payments and any other expenditures
directly associated with the operation
and maintenance of pollution control
equipment). Annual costs are thereby
avoided entirely, as opposed to capital
investments and one-time expenditures
that are usually only delayed.2 Thus, the
2 Even capital investments and one-time
expenditures may be avoided on occasion. The
typical situation where this happens is when a
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
violator’s economic benefit from
avoided costs is the sum of the total
avoided annual costs plus the return
that could be expected on the funds that
were used for projects other than
pollution control.
2. BEN and Cash Flow Analysis
The BEN model calculates economic
benefit by focusing on the effect that
delayed and/or avoided pollution
control costs have on an entity’s cash
flows. Cash flow analysis is a standard
and widely accepted technique for
evaluating costs and investments. In
essence, cash flow calculations focus on
the real, ‘‘out-of-pocket’’ cash effects
resulting from an expenditure.3 Three
important factors that enter into BEN’s
cash flow analysis are inflation,
taxation, and the time value of money.
a. Inflation
BEN first requires users to enter a
single cost estimate for the capital
investment and another single cost
estimate for the one-time
nondepreciable expenditure. Then, to
adjust for inflation, BEN extrapolates
from this single cost estimate to create
separate estimates for the hypothetical
cost of complying on-time and the
actual cost of complying in a delayed
fashion. Similarly, BEN extrapolates
from the user’s annually recurring cost
estimate to a complete set of cost
estimates for every year during the
noncompliance period. (The BEN
model’s help system provides a more
detailed discussion of these inflation
adjustments.) These adjusted cost
estimates form the basis for the on-time
and delay scenarios: The actions and
associated costs that would have been
necessary for hypothetical on-time
compliance, and the actions and
associated costs that were necessary for
the actual delayed compliance.
b. Taxation
The BEN model computes economic
benefit on an after-tax basis, since
environmental expenditures can reduce
income tax liability.4 Depreciation (from
capital investments), one-time
expenditures, and annual costs all
effectively reduce taxable income and
thereby reduce income tax payments. To
account for these tax effects, BEN
calculates the economic benefit using
violator shuts down a particular operation rather
than install required pollution control equipment.
3 Thus, noncash ‘‘paper’’ expenses, such as
depreciation, are considered only to the extent that
they affect cash flow.
4 The term environmental expenditures refers to
firms’ compliance costs and does not include the
payment of civil penalties. Civil penalties are in
almost all cases not deductible.
PO 00000
Frm 00039
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50329
after-tax cash flows for the on-time
compliance and delayed compliance
scenarios.
c. Time Value of Money
A third factor relates to the timing of
the cash flows, because cash flows
occurring in different years are not
directly comparable. The fundamental
financial concept of the time value of
money is based on the principle that a
dollar today is worth more than a dollar
a year from now, since today’s dollar
can be invested immediately to earn a
return over the coming year.
(Alternatively, a dollar last year is worth
more than a dollar today because
investment opportunities existed for last
year’s dollar.) Therefore, the earlier a
cost (or benefit) is incurred, the greater
its economic impact.
BEN accounts for the time value of
money by adjusting all estimated cash
flows to their present value equivalents.
BEN first discounts back to the initial
noncompliance date all cash flows from
the on-time and delay scenarios. The
initial economic benefit as of this date
is simply the difference in the present
values of these two scenarios. Finally,
BEN compounds the initial economic
benefit forward from the noncompliance
date to the penalty payment date.
To adjust the cash flows for both
discounting and compounding, BEN
uses a discount or compound rate
(depending on the direction of the
adjustment) that reflects the time value
of money. The selection of the
appropriate rate, and the structure of the
discounting and compounding
methodology, is a significant issue in
the BEN model and will be addressed
later in this notice. (The model’s help
system provides a more detailed
discussion of the discounting and
compounding that BEN performs for its
present value adjustments.)
II. Final Changes
In its October 9, 1996, Federal
Register notice, the Agency sought
comment on three categories of issues:
(1) Broad economic benefit recapture
questions, (2) the BEN model’s
calculation methodology and
assumptions, and (3) the model’s userfriendliness. The June 18, 1999, notice
provided responses to these comments,
as well as advance notice of EPA’s
proposed changes to the BEN model.
The June 1999 notice also invited a
second round of public comments,
especially on EPA’s proposed changes.
EPA also conducted a peer review by
academic experts in financial economics
during the spring of 2003 on the draft
proposed changes to the model. This
peer review of the model changes was
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50330
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
specifically requested by the United
States Senate.5
The first area in which we invited
comment covered some fundamental
questions that the benefit recapture
approach has raised. Is there an
alternative to the BEN model that would
be both easier to use and at least as
accurate in calculating the economic
benefit of delayed and/or avoided
pollution control expenditures? How
should EPA evaluate the economic
benefit that companies receive as a
result of any illegal competitive
advantage stemming from
noncompliance?
Second, we invited comment on the
BEN model’s calculation methodology.
While the Agency is confident that the
BEN model’s overall approach is
theoretically sound, we welcomed
constructive and documented comment
on alternative methodologies. In
particular, EPA has been aware of
substantial differences of opinion with
respect to inflation adjustments and
discounting/compounding. EPA
requested comment on the BEN model’s
calculation methodology, or any other
aspect of the model’s assumptions or
methodology.
Third, we requested comment on the
model’s user-friendliness. The Agency
had heard concerns that the model is
too difficult to use, particularly
regarding the necessary data acquisition.
Because EPA had never been presented
with any concrete evidence in support
of these assertions, the Agency wanted
either to substantiate the problems and
address them or to put these issues to
rest.
In the following sections, we address
the final changes that EPA is making in
each of the areas on which we requested
comment. Note that final changes
incorporate EPA’s consideration not
only of the public comments but also of
the previously mentioned academic
peer review that EPA completed in
January of 2004.
A. Broad Economic Benefit Recapture
Issues
1. Alternatives to BEN
a. Background
EPA requested comment on whether
anyone had an approach that would be
simpler and at least as accurate as BEN
in calculating the economic benefit from
delayed and/or avoided pollution
control expenditures. EPA designed the
BEN model to calculate the economic
benefit of noncompliance in settlement
of the vast majority of its civil penalty
enforcement cases. Although BEN has
5 Senate
Report No. 106–410 (2000) at page 81.
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
served this purpose effectively, the
Agency recognizes that it should be
improved or even replaced if a better
alternative exists or could be developed
easily. This concern is particularly
relevant because an increasing number
of State and local government
enforcement personnel use the BEN
model regularly. Any alternative
approach must meet EPA’s policy
objective of ensuring that violators are
put on an even financial footing with
those regulated entities that comply on
time. Alternatives must also be
reasonably accurate, simple to use, and
readily understandable to the vast
majority of the BEN model’s users—
Federal, State and local government
enforcement officials who usually have
limited knowledge of financial
economics.
b. Final Changes
Many commenters expressed various
criticisms on different aspects of the
BEN model. But these criticisms focused
on suggestions for improving BEN. No
commenter proposed an alternative
approach to a stand-alone computer
model that performs net present value
calculations. Therefore, the Agency will
continue its use of BEN, although it will
also implement significant revisions
(see following sections).
On a related topic, two commenters
questioned the entire benefit recapture
framework. Although one comment
along these lines was somewhat unclear,
the other comment presented a
comprehensive approach for basing
penalties on the lesser of economic
benefit or social cost (i.e.,
environmental damages). Under this
proposal, if a violator gained a
significant economic benefit from its
violations but caused only trivial
environmental damage (as monetized
through some unspecified economic
methodology), then the penalty would
be commensurately trivial. The Agency
finds this approach entirely
unacceptable in the context of enforcing
regulatory requirements for individual
violators. The appropriate context for
considering social costs is in the process
of formulating proposed regulations.
Penalties based on social costs (when
less than economic benefit) would
provide an implicit yet clear incentive
to violate the law if a company
anticipated that its economic benefit
would exceed the consequent
measurable environmental damage.
Further, such an approach would be
fundamentally unfair to those firms that
resisted the temptation to violate the
law. In addition, quantifying
environmental damages in a monetary
measure is an exceedingly difficult
PO 00000
Frm 00040
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
analytical problem. Even if this
fundamentally different approach was
theoretically sound, it would be
infeasible for the vast majority of
enforcement cases.
2. Illegal Competitive Advantage
a. Background
Since the issuance of EPA’s Policy on
Civil Penalties in 1984, the Agency has
maintained that any given penalty
should be structured to recover—at a
minimum—the economic benefit a
violator has enjoyed as a result of its
noncompliance. That 1984 policy
recognized that the benefit would be
based on delayed costs, avoided costs
and illegal competitive advantage. In
addition to this economic benefit
component, EPA assesses a gravity
component that reflects the seriousness
of the violation. This gravity component
is designed to ensure that the penalty
puts the violator in a worse position
than those in the regulated community
who complied with the law. The
economic benefit component of EPA’s
civil penalty policy focuses specifically
on identifying and recovering the gain
to a violator in order to remove any
economic incentive to violate
environmental regulations.
The BEN model calculates the
economic benefit from delaying and/or
avoiding required environmental
expenditures. The economic benefit that
arises from situations other than the
delay and/or avoidance of pollution
control expenditures is broadly termed
‘‘illegal competitive advantage,’’ which
BEN is incapable of measuring. The
essential distinction between these two
types of economic benefit is that in the
illegal competitive advantage situation,
the violator’s noncompliant actions
have allowed (or will allow) it to attain
a level of revenues that would have
been unattainable had it always been in
compliance. In delayed and avoided
costs situations, the implicit assumption
is that the revenues from a
noncompliant and compliant state are
identical. Consequently, BEN focuses
exclusively on a violator’s pollution
control costs and does not require any
data on the violator’s revenues.
In either type of situation (BEN-type
economic benefit or illegal competitive
advantage), the fundamental definition
of economic benefit is still the same:
The economic benefit is the difference
in the net present values of the
compliant/on-time and noncompliant/
delay scenarios (i.e., the actions and
cash flows—both historical and possibly
also future—associated with the
hypothetical compliance, and the actual
noncompliance). But in the cases
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
amenable to BEN, the violator’s
revenues from the compliant and
noncompliant states simply cancel each
other out, allowing BEN to measure
economic benefit through a calculation
involving only the costs that would
have differed had the violator been in
compliance. Illegal competitive
advantage encompasses all situations in
which the revenues do not cancel out
each other. Since the revenues were
higher in the noncompliant state than
they would have been in a compliant
state, more detailed research and
analysis is necessary, going beyond the
scope of the BEN model.
The BEN model’s widespread
application is made possible by its
simplifying assumption regarding
revenues, obviating the need for a
detailed examination of a violator’s
business records or competitive market
situation. But in some cases, this
assumption is not valid.6 In such cases,
the violator would not have been able to
generate a given level of revenues were
it not for its noncompliance. In those
cases, EPA’s policy is to seek to
recapture the economic benefit based on
the violator’s illegal competitive
advantage.
b. Final Changes
The Agency received many comments
on illegal competitive advantage. The
first round of comments focused mainly
on the feasibility of developing a standalone computer model analogous to
BEN (or an add-on module to BEN) that
could easily and reliably determine the
economic benefit from the widely
varying examples of illegal competitive
advantage. The broad consensus was
that no such model was feasible, and the
Agency agrees. Without BEN’s
simplifying assumption that the
violator’s revenues from the on-time and
delay scenarios cancel out each other,
no ‘‘one-size-fits-all’’ computer model
can analyze the range of likely
situations.
The second round of comments the
Agency received on illegal competitive
advantage mainly focused on the June
1999 notice’s proposed questions for
BEN’s module and the illegal
competitive advantage examples. But
since the ICA concept is currently under
review by EPA’s Science Advisory
Board (SAB), OECA will not put any
6 The Agency suspects that this relationship may
be reversed for cases involving wetlands. Although
the evidence is largely anecdotal, most wetlands
cases encompass violations that allowed a violator
to engage in operations that would not have been
feasible but for the violation. Therefore, in
evaluating wetlands cases, the Agency will be
particularly sensitive to the possible presence of
illegal competitive advantage.
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
ICA questions in the revised BEN
model.
After careful review of the comments,
and in light of the fact that the SAB is
currently reviewing the ICA issues, EPA
has decided against publishing at this
time any formal guidance delineating
detailed analytical steps. While EPA
remains committed to recapturing
economic benefit based on illegal
competitive advantage, if appropriate,
quantifying illegal competitive
advantage requires a careful
examination of the facts of the particular
case, and EPA believes it is premature
to try to establish formal guidance in
light of these case-specific issues.
Similarly, the Agency does not envision
providing a specific formula for
calculating a benefit component in such
cases.
In summary, EPA will continue to
seek the recovery of illegal competitive
advantage in cases where the BEN
model is incapable of fully assessing the
extent to which a violator is financially
better off as a result of its
noncompliance. The proper evaluation
of illegal competitive advantage will
involve verifying that the use of the BEN
model alone is inappropriate to the
case-specific facts, and then formulating
an analytical approach that captures the
extent of the violator’s gain.
B. The BEN Model’s Calculation
Methodology
Over the years, BEN has received
occasional criticism for alleged flaws in
its calculation methodology,
particularly regarding the model’s
inflation adjustments and discounting/
compounding. The Agency requested
substantive comments on how the BEN
model handles these two issues. In
addition, EPA invited comment on all
aspects of BEN’s calculation
methodology. The Agency also asked
commenters to address whether their
proposed changes would add any
complexity to the computer model and,
if so, why the benefit of the change
justified the added complexity.
1. Depreciation Method
a. Background
The BEN model calculates
depreciation for capital investments,
since the tax deduction for accounting
depreciation charges provides a real
after-tax positive cash flow to
businesses.7 BEN used to calculate
depreciation using a five-year straightIRS does not allow companies to write off
completely a capital investment in the year of
purchase. Companies must spread the expense of
the investment over several years using the
appropriate depreciation schedule.
PO 00000
7 The
Frm 00041
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50331
line methodology for capital
investments made before January 1,
1987, and a seven-year Modified
Accelerated Cost Recovery System for
capital investments made after January
1, 1987. These assumptions represent
the most rapid depreciation periods
available for typical pollution control
investments, thereby producing the
positive depreciation cash flow effects
as early as possible. These particular
depreciation methods generally result in
a conservative economic benefit
calculation (i.e., lower than would
otherwise be calculated) because they
minimize out-of-pocket costs to the
violator. Therefore, BEN is often
producing economic benefit figures that
are very conservative.8
For capital equipment that has a very
short useful life, the selection of
alternative depreciation schedules
might be available and also more
beneficial to a business. In unusual
cases where the violator can
demonstrate that an alternative
depreciation schedule would be both
available and beneficial, more detailed
calculations by a financial analyst in
lieu of the BEN model may be
necessary.
b. Final Changes
EPA received no comments on its
proposal in the June 1999 notice that
although a revised BEN model could
conceivably allow alternative
depreciation schedules, the drawbacks
of the added complexity and potential
user confusion might outweigh the gains
from addressing a rare circumstance.
Nevertheless, EPA has devised a
relatively simple means for BEN to
apply shorter depreciation schedules
when the user enters a capital
equipment useful life less than 10 years
(as opposed to the default 15 years).
The specification of shorter
depreciation schedules will ensure that
BEN does not overestimate economic
benefit in the relatively rare cases that
involve such short-lived capital
equipment. Once the shorter useful life
has been specified, the alternative
depreciation schedule will not require
any additional input from the user. BEN
will also include a provision to account
for legislation that allows for
depreciation bonuses over certain
periods. This provision will key off the
previously required noncompliance and
compliance dates, and it therefore will
8 The IRS requires that many types of pollution
control equipment be depreciated over a longer
period than assumed in the BEN model. Were EPA
to tailor the depreciation to account for that longer
period, the result would be a higher economic
benefit calculation.
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50332
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
not require any additional input from
the user.
2. Tax Rates
a. Background
The DOS versions of BEN that were
issued after 1993 used to apply three
marginal tax rates: a rate for 1986 and
before, one for 1987 through 1992, and
one for 1993 and beyond. Users could
accept the standard values—which
incorporate national averages of State
tax rates—or modify the inputs to reflect
specific State values.9
b. Final Changes
EPA did not receive any objections to
the June 1999 notice’s proposal that the
revised BEN model will require the user
to enter the violator’s State of operation,
then automatically reference an internal
database of State tax rates and perform
the necessary calculations for the
violator’s combined Federal and State
tax rate.10 BEN will calculate the tax
rate for each separate year of
noncompliance, to allow for annual
changes in the relevant State tax rate
(even when the Federal rate remains
constant). Users will have the additional
option of entering year-by-year
combined Federal and State rates in a
spreadsheet-like format.11
Although these options may sound
complex, the only data required of the
user will be the violator’s State. The
other screens for additional data entry
and modification will appear only to
those users who selected such advanced
options.
3. Differences in On-Time and Delay
Scenarios
a. Background
The BEN model’s baseline assumption
is that the violator would have used the
same technology and approach in the
hypothetical on-time compliance as it
9 Tax
rate modification can also reflect a business
whose low net income entails a tax bracket other
than the assumed highest bracket. Note that BEN’s
assumption of the highest marginal tax rate
produces a lower economic benefit calculation than
assuming a lower tax rate because a higher tax rate
decreases the compliance costs’ after-tax value.
Since the model employs an after-tax cost in its
analysis, the lower the tax, the higher the BEN
result.
10 The model will also offer the option of the
national average of all the State tax rates for cases
where the State in which the violator pays taxes is
unclear.
11 This option would allow users to account for,
among other situations, a company whose
profitability (and hence tax bracket) was highly
variable over different years. (As noted before,
BEN’s assumption of the highest marginal tax rate
throughout the noncompliance period results in a
lower economic benefit estimate than would be
produced by a more precise calculation of the
violator-specific marginal tax rate.)
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
did in the actual delayed compliance
scenario. The only allowed differences
are in the two scenarios’ exact costs of
compliance, which BEN adjusts for
automatically in its inflation treatment.
But technological, legal, or other
relevant changes between the on-time
and delay scenarios can conceivably
alter the components of the compliance
scenarios, increasing or decreasing the
compliance costs by a rate other than
general price inflation. Where the delay
case costs are substantially less than the
on-time case costs (e.g., a technological
breakthrough in control equipment),
BEN will understate the benefit. Where
the delay costs are substantially higher
(e.g., regulations become more stringent,
but with ‘‘grandfather’’ clauses for
already-compliant firms) BEN will
overstate the benefit.
Where, in the unusual case, the ontime and delay compliance scenarios are
significantly different, BEN’s baseline
assumption of two identical scenarios is
inappropriate.12 More sophisticated
calculations are necessary.13
b. Final Changes
EPA received only one minor
objection to the June 1999 notice’s
proposal that the revised BEN model
allow users to enter separate on-time
and delayed compliance costs. Although
the standard operation of the revised
model will still entail only a single
compliance scenario, the new screens
for additional data entry/modification of
separate on-time vs. delay scenarios will
be available to those users who select
such advanced options. The availability
of more advanced options will also
enhance the model’s ability to account
for atypical situations such as valid precompliance expenditures and credits for
salvaged capital equipment, thus
decreasing the need for off-line
calculations.
4. Capital Equipment Replacement
a. Background
One of the three components of
compliance costs BEN analyzes is the
capital investment, which represents
depreciable pollution control
equipment. As the name implies,
depreciable equipment wears out with
12 The inexperienced user will become aware that
a more sophisticated analysis is needed because
there are two sets of cost figures, but only one place
to put them. The more experienced user will just
go directly to the ‘‘Specific Cost Estimates’’ option
during data entry.
13 A similar problem arises when no
technologically feasible method of compliance is
available. If the only possible compliance method
that the Agency would have allowed is to cease all
production, then this falls under the category of
illegal competitive advantage, which by definition
is beyond the scope of the BEN model.
PO 00000
Frm 00042
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
usage and the passage of time. BEN used
to ask the user if the violator will need
to replace the equipment at some point
in the future. If the user specified that
the investment in capital equipment is
recurring, then the user could accept the
standard value of 15 years for the useful
life of the capital equipment, or enter
another value.
If the capital equipment does need to
be replaced in the future, then the
violator is financially better off from its
delayed compliance in two distinct yet
related ways: the violator has received
a benefit in the past from delaying the
initial purchase of the capital
equipment, and will receive a benefit in
the future from delaying the
replacement of the capital equipment
when that initial purchase wears out.
For example, if a steel mill delays
installation of a $1,000,000 baghouse for
5 years, it first obtains a benefit from
delaying the purchase of that baghouse
for 5 years. But when that baghouse
needs to be replaced 15 years later, the
violator’s second baghouse is purchased
5 years later than it should have because
the initial purchase lasted five years
later than if it had complied on time.
b. Final Changes
Some commenters characterized any
consideration of future replacement
cycles as ‘‘speculative,’’ as these cycles
have yet to occur in the typical case
(because the noncompliance period is
almost always shorter than the capital
equipment’s useful life). EPA agrees
only to the extent that BEN does make
an assumption about the future, but this
assumption is essentially a baseline one:
BEN assumes that future pollution
control requirements will be neither
more stringent nor more lax than
current requirements, and that the cost
of the replacement equipment will
increase by no more and no less than
the projected rate of inflation. Therefore,
the Agency will retain the BEN model’s
default consideration of capital
equipment replacement.
Some commenters argued that BEN
should not offer infinitely recurring
replacement cycles. The Agency notes
that although modeling infinite cycles
might at first seem excessive, all future
costs are ‘‘discounted’’ back to their
present values (see following sections
for an explanation of discounting).
Thus, the first replacement cycle
typically has a relatively small impact
on the benefit calculation.14 The impact
14 If the initial capital investment is $1 million
and the equipment lasts for 15 years, then the first
replacement cycle is still $1 million (assuming, for
now, the lack of any intervening inflation). But
since it is purchased 15 years later, the $1 million
is discounted to a present value at, for example, 10
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
of later replacement cycles is almost
negligible.
Some commenters, as well as
academic peer reviewers, favored the
approach of a finite number of
replacement cycles (which the Agency
initially proposed to adopt). But one
peer reviewer pointed out that this
approach runs into problems when the
noncompliance period is very long,
especially when it approximates the
useful life of the capital equipment. For
example, assume a 10-year compliance
delay, coupled with a 10-year useful
life. If BEN were to use one replacement
cycle, the on-time scenario would
include two capital equipment
installations, covering the years 1
through 20. The delay scenario would
also include two capital equipment
installations, but run from years 11
through 30. BEN would implicitly be
stating that the violator would need to
have functional equipment in place for
years 21 through 30 (i.e., the delay
scenario’s replacement cycle), but that a
company complying on-time need not
do so (i.e., since the cash flow analysis
for the on-time scenario runs out only
to the year 20).
Therefore, the revised BEN model will
adopt this peer reviewer’s solution by
implementing the concept of economic
depreciation, which essentially
calculates the lease value of pollution
control equipment. In other words,
instead of modeling the on-time
replacement capital investment and the
subsequent depreciation tax shields,
and comparing that to delayed
replacement, the calculation models
leasing the equipment over the period
when the on-time equipment would
have required replacement yet the delay
equipment is still functional. The
avoided lease cost, therefore, serves as
a reasonable approximation of the
Abbr
economic benefit from the delayed
replacement equipment installation, and
also allows the two scenarios to the
modeled out to the same end point.
Furthermore, projections far into the
future are no longer necessary, as the
imputed lease cost is calculated only for
the interim period when the on-time
equipment would have required
replacement yet the delay equipment is
still functional.
This approach will add a few new
cells on one of the pages in the BEN
detailed printouts, yet allow the
elimination of another entire page of
calculations. It will also simplify the
previous 0–5 replacement cycles
optional input to a simple ‘‘yes/no’’
choice for the consideration of future
capital replacement (with the default set
to ‘‘yes’’). The previously included
optional input for the future inflation
rate (which applied only to replacement
cycles in addition to the first one) will
be eliminated.
5. Inflation Treatment
a. Background
The first step in the economic benefit
calculation is to determine the
compliance costs—for both the on-time
and delay scenarios—as of the year in
which they were actually incurred (or
should have been incurred). Therefore,
BEN adjusts the compliance costs from
the date they were estimated to the date
the costs will be incurred to account for
the effects of inflation.
To adjust for inflation, BEN
previously used a standard-value rate
calculated from the prior ten years of
inflation data from the Plant Cost Index
(PCI) in the magazine Chemical
Engineering. (The PCI is generally the
cost index most relevant to the types of
costs typically associated with pollution
control technology.) This simple
Full name
inflation rate adjusted the initial
compliance cost estimates. BEN applied
this simple inflation rate to the
compliance cost figures in order to
determine what compliance would have
cost at the noncompliance date. Then
BEN applied the same simple inflation
rate to determine what the costs actually
were (or will be) at the compliance date.
Finally, the model used the same rate to
go well into the future to determine
what those costs will be for the capital
equipment replacement cycles.
b. Final Changes
Despite the Agency’s specific request
for comment on BEN’s inflation
adjustment, we received almost none.
The issues that the few commenters did
raise were:
(1) The use of a single inflation rate
for both actual and projected inflation,
(2) The basis for the actual inflation
rate, and
(3) The basis for the projected
inflation rate.
For actual historical inflation, the
revised BEN model will adjust each
cash flow automatically from the date of
the cost estimate to the date on which
it is incurred by referencing a look-up
table of cost index values.15 The default
cost index will be the PCI. This
particular index may not be perfectly
appropriate for every single case, but we
have yet to encounter any other cost
index that would form a better basis for
a standard value, nor did any
commenters submit any specific
nominations for a more suitable index.
The revised BEN model will also
allow the user to override the PCI and
instead specify different cost indices for
different compliance components. The
table below describes the alternative
cost indices.
Description
Typical applications
2.5%
CCI ..
2.5-percent constant inflation rate
Construction Cost Index ............................... Constructions costs; based on 1.128 tons
Portland cement, 1,088 bd. ft. 2x4 lumber, 200 hrs. common labor.
ECI ...
Employment Cost Index ...............................
Employment costs ........................................
GDP
Gross Domestic Product price deflator ........
Economy-wide measure of price changes ...
PCI ...
Plant Cost Index ...........................................
Plant equipment and labor costs .................
percent, over 15 years. The first replacement cycle
would only increase the benefit component by
about 30%. The second replacement cycle is
purchased 30 years later. Thus, the $1 million piece
of equipment is discounted at the same 10 percent
over 30 years. The economic benefit from the delay
of that second replacement cycle would only
increase the benefit component by about 7%.
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
15 The model will not apply an explicit inflation
rate, although an annualized rate could be imputed
from the model’s data. For example, suppose a $200
cost estimate from 1991 must be adjusted for
inflation to the same day in 1992. The 1991 cost
index value is 100, whereas the 1992 index value
is 103. The calculation the model performs is $200
x 103 / 100 = $206 (i.e., multiplying the original
cost estimate by the ratio of the cost index values
from the date on which the cost is actually
PO 00000
Frm 00043
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50333
Sensitivity tests; model testing.
General construction costs, especially
where labor costs are a high proportion
of total costs; often used for municipal
wastewater projects.
One-time nondepreciable expenditures or
annual costs that are mainly labor
A very broad, economy-wide measure of inflation is desired.
Standard value.
incurred, and the date on which the estimate is
made). The index change from 1991 to 1992 does
represent an annual inflation rate of three percent
(i.e., 103 / 100 = 1.03 ¥ 1 = 0.03), although the
model would not directly apply this rate. The
calculation that uses the ratio of the index values
is both more precise and more simple than
calculating multiple annual inflation rates over
different periods for historical costs.
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50334
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
Abbr
Full name
Description
Typical applications
PPI ...
Producer Price Index ...................................
Representative producer costs ....................
General costs for producers, not tied to industrial process equipment.
The user may also override BEN’s
inflation adjustments for the capital
investment and one-time
nondepreciable expenditure, and
instead enter separate estimates for
these compliance costs as of the
noncompliance date and compliance
date. This customized data entry could
represent another alternative cost index,
case-specific inflation assumptions, or
entirely different actions for on-time
and delayed compliance (as discussed
in a previous section). For projected
future inflation, the model will project
all the cost indices forward in time at
publically available, consensus-oriented
forecasted rates.
The standard operation of the model
will still entail absolutely no input
whatsoever from the user who is
satisfied with BEN’s default values. The
other screens for additional data entry
and modification will appear only to
those users who selected more advanced
options.
6. Discount/Compound Rate
a. Background
Once the compliance cost estimates
are adjusted for inflation and then for
taxation, the BEN model must adjust
these after-tax cash flows to a common
present value as of the date of
noncompliance. The difference between
the two present values (of the on-time
and delay scenarios) is the initial
economic benefit as of the
noncompliance date. BEN then
compounds this initial economic benefit
forward from the noncompliance date to
the penalty payment date to determine
the final economic benefit. A single rate
adjusts all present values both backward
and forward in time.16 This section
addresses only the calculation of BEN’s
standard value for this single discount
rate, which was previously based upon
a ten-year after-tax weighted average
cost of capital (WACC), with the inputs
representing averages across all
industries.17
16 The Agency received many comments on the
use of a single rate as opposed to two different rates.
The notice addresses this issue in section II. B. 8,
Discounting/Compounding Methodology.
17 The discount rate standard value for not-forprofits is based upon municipal bond yields,
averaged across the four investment-quality ratings
of Aaa, Aa, A, and Baa. The only comment EPA
received on the not-for-profit discount rate was a
suggestion that municipal economic benefit be
calculated using a discount rate for private entities
that perform similar functions (e.g., on a municipal
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
The WACC is the average of the cost
of debt and the cost of equity, weighted
by the portions of debt and equity out
of total financing. The WACC is first
calculated for each year, and then the
prior version of BEN averaged these
annual values over the most recent tenyear period. The (after-tax) cost of debt
is the average return on corporate bonds
averaged across all industries, and then
multiplied by one minus the highest
marginal corporate tax rate (Federal
combined with an average of all States).
The cost of equity is based upon the
widely used Capital Asset Pricing
Model (CAPM), and is equal to a riskfree rate component plus the expected
equity risk premium (i.e., the average
since 1926 of each year’s excess stock
market return over the risk-free rate).
b. Final Changes
Based on the June 1999 notice’s
proposal and the lack of any objections,
the revised BEN model will tailor the
standard value discount rate to the
period from the noncompliance date to
the penalty payment date.18 The
standard value will reference a look-up
table, averaging the annual values over
the relevant years. Each individual
annual calculation will be similar to the
standard value’s previous
methodology.19
Clean Water Act case, the discount rate would be
the average WACC for privately owned wastewater
treatment plants). However, because the Agency is
trying to calculate the economic benefit that the
municipality and its residents or rate payers have
actually gained, the Agency prefers to use an
estimation of the municipal government’s
opportunity cost of financing projects, which is
equal to the interest rate on the municipality’s
bonds. This debt rate—which forms the basis for the
BEN model’s not-for-profit standard value discount
rate—will almost always be substantially lower
than the private-sector-equivalent cost of capital.
The discount rate for Federal facilities is based
upon the yields from five-year U.S. Treasury notes.
18 Although the following discussion focuses on
the for-profit discount rate, the tailoring of the
discount rate to the relevant time period would also
apply to not-for-profit entities.
19 The revised BEN model will implement two
relatively minor changes to the previous model’s
annual WACC calculation. First, the previous
practice of applying the most recent figure for the
expected equity risk premium to all prior years’
calculations will be replaced with the figure that
was actually available at the time for that specific
year’s calculation.
The second change is altering the horizon for the
equity risk premium. The standard value previously
combined the long-term Treasury security rate with
the long-horizon equity risk premium, the latter
being equal to the average of each year’s stock
market return minus the corresponding-maturity
risk-free rate. Because the WACC calculation
PO 00000
Frm 00044
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
The model will also perform
additional customizing in a similar
automated fashion. Since BEN will have
an input for the violator’s State—
thereby customizing the tax rate for
compliance costs—that same
customized tax rate will determine the
after-tax debt cost component of the
WACC. The model will even select the
individual tax rate if the company is not
organized as a C-corporation (as profits
and losses from S-corporations,
partnerships, and sole proprietorships
flow through to the owners’ individual
tax returns).
The standard operation of the model
will still entail absolutely no input
whatsoever from the user who is
satisfied with BEN’s derived WACC for
the discount/compound rate. Another
screen to override BEN’s derived rate
will appear only to those users who
selected such advanced options.
7. Discounting/Compounding
Methodology
a. Background
As stated in the previous section,
once the compliance cost estimates are
adjusted for inflation, and then for
taxation, the BEN model must adjust
these after-tax cash flows to a common
present value as of the noncompliance
date. The difference between the two
present values (of the on-time and delay
scenarios) is the initial economic benefit
as of the noncompliance date. BEN then
compounds this initial economic benefit
forward from the noncompliance date to
the penalty payment date in order to
determine the final economic benefit.
BEN uses a single rate to adjust all
present values both backward and
forward in time. Because BEN uses the
same rate for going both backward and
forward, this calculation is
computationally equivalent to bringing
all cash flows—both past and future—
directly to the penalty payment date at
the WACC rate.
The comments fell into three
categories. Some thought the WACC rate
was too high and especially that the
combines the equity risk premium with the risk-free
rate of the same maturity that is used initially to
calculate the premium, the issue of which horizon
premium to use is largely moot. (The expected
deviations of the resulting WACC will thereby be
both small and nonsystematic.) The new calculation
will switch to the intermediate-horizon risk
premium (and the corresponding risk-free rate) as
a simple compromise between the long-horizon and
short-horizon.
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
compounding part of the calculation
should be based on a risk-free rate.
Some agreed with EPA’s approach.
Others commented that EPA’s discount/
compound rate was too low and should
instead be based on financing pollution
control investments with 100% equity.
The first group of commenters
claimed that BEN’s use of a WACCbased rate in all parts of the benefit
calculation yielded inappropriately high
economic benefit calculations. They
posited that future cash flows represent
uncertainty and risk, while past cash
flows are known, certain, and riskless.
Thus, they generally agreed that
discounting future cash flows should be
done with a WACC-based rate or some
other risk-based rate, but felt that
compounding past cash flows forward
should be done with a riskless rate.
They cited selected academic literature
from economic and financial analysis of
commercial damages in torts cases,
proposing two alternative
methodologies:
• (A) Use BEN’s initial figure for the
economic benefit as of the
noncompliance date (i.e., bring all cash
flows, irrespective of when they occur,
back to the noncompliance date at a rate
reflecting risk), but then bring this
intermediate economic benefit figure
forward to the penalty payment date at
a risk-free rate.
• (B) From the perspective of the
penalty payment date, bring all future
cash flows back in time at a rate
reflecting risk (e.g., the WACC) and
bring all past cash flows forward in time
at a risk-free rate (e.g., the after-tax
return on short-term U.S. Treasury
securities).
Both of these methodologies produce
significantly lower economic benefit
estimates than the BEN model. A range
for the magnitude of the typical
differences is difficult to provide
because of the many different types of
cases. But while alternative A will
generally produce significantly lower
benefit analyses than EPA’s BEN
approach, alternative B is so extreme
that it will often produce negative
economic benefit estimates for the
capital investment portion of the
compliance scenario.
The second group of commenters
agreed that the WACC was appropriate
for discounting all future costs back to
the noncompliance date, and then
compounding the initial economic
benefit forward to the penalty payment
date.20 The third group commented that
20 One
commenter agreed with compounding the
initial benefit forward at the WACC rate, but only
to the compliance date, after which a lower
compounding rate would be appropriate. His
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
BEN’s use of the WACC is incorrect and
leads to economic benefit estimates that
are too low. These commenters instead
favored a company’s higher cost of
equity capital, rather than the weighted
average of the relatively higher-cost
equity capital and the relatively lowercost debt capital. Their rationale was
that excess returns flow to a company’s
equity holders, not to a mixture of its
debt and equity owners.
b. Final Changes
Regarding the first group of
commenters, although both the
conceptual bases and results of their
two risk-free rate methodologies
contradict each other, they share one
similar rationale: Cash flows that have
yet to occur in the future are uncertain
and risky, whereas cash flows that have
occurred in the past are certain and
riskless. These methodologies, therefore,
apply to future cash flows a rate that
includes a risk premium (e.g., a
company’s WACC or some other riskadjusted rate) and apply to past cash
flows a risk-free rate (e.g., the return on
short-term Treasury securities). As
discussed below, the Agency believes
that even if this approach were justified
in the context of calculating damages
owed to plaintiffs in certain types of tort
cases, it is entirely inappropriate in
economic benefit calculations for
enforcement actions. The goal in the tort
damages approach is to make the
plaintiff whole by compensating him for
his losses. The fundamentally different
goal in enforcement actions is to deter
future violations by both this particular
violator and other potential future
violators.
By contrast, the third group of
commenters advocate the use of an
equity-based discount rate. This
approach is more reasonable than the
risk-free rate alternatives, although the
Agency still believes that using the
WACC throughout all aspects of the
calculation is the most reasonable and
hence preferable approach.
(i) Risk-Free Rate Forward: Theoretical
Issues
The goal in a tort action is to make the
plaintiff ‘‘whole.’’ The settlement or
court determination ultimately should
place the plaintiff in the same financial
position as if the wrong had not
rationale was that a company then must set aside
specific funds to pay a penalty; therefore, the
economic benefit estimate should be compounded
either at the actual interest rate on an escrow
account or at the company’s debt rate (which
reflects its risk of going out of business, resulting
in an inability to pay a penalty). Even if EPA took
this approach, it would make no difference in the
calculation where compliance had not yet been
achieved at the time of settlement or trial.
PO 00000
Frm 00045
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50335
occurred. The first step in such a case
is to calculate the necessary
compensation at the time of the actual
wrong. The next step is to adjust the
compensation calculated at the time of
the actual wrong to the time at which
such compensation is to be made.
Certain authors writing about tort
damages have advocated bringing such
compensation forward at a risk-free
rate.21 Otherwise, the plaintiff would be
‘‘having-its-cake-and-eating-it-too’’: The
initial compensation has essentially
been invested at the time of the actual
wrong at a rate reflecting risk taking, yet
the plaintiff is now granted the
compensation which grew at that rate,
without ever bearing the accompanying
risk. (In contrast, the regular investor
would have made the investment and
then had to stand by nervously as the
investment’s value either grew or fell).
This was the reasoning behind some of
the commenters in the first group
advocating that BEN employ such a riskfree rate approach.
While the appropriate focus in a tort
damage action is on compensating the
victim (i.e., plaintiff), this is not
appropriate in an enforcement action.
The enforcement agency is not suing for
damages it has suffered. The goal is not
to make the plaintiff whole (i.e., to
restore to it the amount by which it was
damaged). The goal of the economic
portion of a civil penalty is to return the
defendant to the position it would have
been in had it complied, and thus
disgorge from it the amount it
wrongfully gained. If civil penalties,
comprising the economic benefit and
gravity components, effectively allow
the violator to gain an economic
advantage from its violations, other
companies will see an advantage in
similar noncompliance. This is a
fundamentally different perspective
from a tort case, and demands a
fundamentally different view of
adjusting cash flows to a present value.
The appropriate discount rate for
economic benefit calculations is a
company’s opportunity cost of capital,
reflecting the financing costs for
pollution control investments or the
value of investment opportunities
foregone because of pollution control
purchases. The opportunity cost of
capital is the incremental expected rate
of return a company must earn to pay
back its lenders (i.e., bond holders) and
owners (i.e., stockholders), which is the
weighted-average cost of capital.
21 No consensus exists, however, and many other
authors have advocated other approaches. Judges in
tort cases have arrived at rulings that mandate many
different rates, with many different values and
rationales.
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50336
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
The risk-free rate methodologies use
short-term U.S. Treasury bill rates that
are unrelated to a company’s
opportunity cost of capital. Only the
Treasury of the United States of
America is able to borrow at the U.S.
Treasury bill rate.22 Companies lack the
advantage of such low financing rates.
To finance additional projects, they
must either issue debt at higher interest
rates, and/or issue equity, which
requires returns of even higher rates.
Applying the risk-free rate to a
company’s cash flows presumes an
unattainably low borrowing rate and an
insufficient return on investments.
(With the exception of mutual funds, a
company whose main business was
investing in T-bills would not be in
business for very long.) The true
opportunity cost of capital for a
company far exceeds the T-bill rate. The
risk-free rate will therefore
systematically understate the economic
benefit of pollution control
noncompliance. Penalties based solely
on economic benefit calculated with a
T-bill rate would allow a defendant to
retain a potentially substantial gain.
Because of the precedent of this retained
gain, other regulated companies might
see an economic advantage in similar
noncompliance, and the penalties based
on a risk-free rate approach will fail to
deter potential violators.
(ii) Risk-Free Rate Forward: Practical
Implications
Not only are the theoretical
underpinnings of the risk-free rate
forward methodologies flawed, but their
practical implications are also troubling.
Specifically, the use of the risk-free rate
fails to achieve the overriding goal of
economic benefit recapture: To make
the violator financially indifferent
between compliance and
noncompliance, which in turn
constitutes a critically important
element of deterrence.23 An example
helps to illustrate this point.
Suppose a company is deciding
whether to purchase pollution control
equipment this year (e.g., 2000), or to
wait until the same month in the next
year (e.g., 2001). The company is not
necessarily contemplating a willful
violation of the law—perhaps the law’s
interpretation is unclear, and the
company would like to know the
financial consequences of not
purchasing the equipment, and then
later being found to be in
noncompliance. The company,
therefore, wants to know how much
better or worse off it will be by delaying
the purchase one year.
The company performs three sets of
economic benefit calculations. First, it
calculates the economic benefit as of the
present time (e.g., June 2000). This lets
the company know how much better off
it will be by delaying the purchase (e.g.,
until June 2001), in the absence of any
penalty. Second, it calculates the
economic benefit as of one year later
(i.e., June 2001, when it would
otherwise purchase the equipment, and
also pay any penalty), and then
discounts the calculated economic
benefit back to the present (i.e., June
2000). This lets the company know the
present value of any economic benefit
based penalty that is calculated and
paid the following year in 2001. Third,
it subtracts the second result from the
first result to determine the net amount
by which it is better or worse off (i.e.,
the economic benefit of its
Economic benefit
noncompliance, minus the present
discounted value of the economicbenefit-based penalty it can expect to
pay in 2001).
The first economic benefit calculation
yields the same result regardless of
which economic benefit methodology is
used, because all the cash flows occur
in the future.24 In this example, the only
compliance measure is a one-time—i.e.,
no replacement cycles—capital
investment of $10 million.25 The
company calculates that it is financially
better off now in 2000 by $519,767 from
a projected one-year compliance delay.
The company also needs to know how
much better off it will be on net should
the enforcement agency assess a penalty
in 2001 equal to the calculated
economic benefit from its delayed
compliance. Assuming that the agency
uses BEN, the economic benefit is
brought forward one year by an estimate
of the company’s WACC (in this case 10
percent), so the economic-benefit-based
portion of the penalty the company will
pay is $571,744.26 But because the
company will pay the penalty a year in
the future, it must discount that amount
back to the present. If it discounts the
penalty at the same rate that BEN used
to compound the penalty forward to the
penalty payment date, the present
discounted value of the future penalty
will always be equal to the economic
benefit the company calculates for itself
(in this case, $519,767). The company
can therefore expect to have any
economic benefit disgorged from itself,
which makes the company financially
indifferent between compliance and
noncompliance. The column in the
exhibit below labeled ‘‘BEN’’
summarizes these calculations.
BEN
1. Penalty Payment Date of 6/1/2000 .........................................................................................
2a. Penalty Payment Date of 6/1/2001 .......................................................................................
2b. Result 2a discounted back to 6/1/2000 .................................................................................
3. Net Result (i.e., 1¥2b) ............................................................................................................
$519,767
571,744
519,767
0
Alternative A
$519,767
533,281
484,801
48,480
Alternative B
$519,767
(147,798)
0
519,767
Perhaps, however, the enforcement
agency uses one of the alternative
methodologies. Under alternative A, as
described in Section II B(8)(a), above,
the initial economic benefit as of the
noncompliance date is calculated with
BEN, but is then compounded forward
at the after-tax risk-free rate. In this case,
compounding the initial economic
benefit forward from 2000 to 2001 at an
illustrative risk-free rate of 2.6 percent
yields $533,281. The company
22 This is a very favorable rate, because of the U.S.
Treasury’s over two-century default-free record, its
ability to create money, and also the State tax-free
status of its debt instruments.
23 Because benefit recapture by itself merely
makes the violator indifferent between compliance
and noncompliance, only a total penalty amount
that exceeds the economic benefit (by incorporating
a gravity component) can achieve actual deterrence.
Therefore, a civil penalty should always be at least
equal to the economic benefit calculation plus some
non-trivial gravity component.
24 The results might be slightly different
depending on what ‘‘risk-adjusted rate’’ the risk-free
rate forward methodologies use for the future cash
flows in their calculations. Different practitioners
have used different ‘‘risk-adjusted rates’’ in
different cases, including the same WACC-based
discount rate that the BEN model uses. Therefore,
for the purposes of the examples that follow, we
assume that the alternative methodologies also use
the WACC for future cash flows. If, instead, they
were to use a different rate, the exact figures for the
results would be slightly different, but the overall
implications would remain the same.
25 Other inputs include a 40-percent tax rate, 1.8percent inflation rate, and 10-percent WACC.
26 Because the time between the noncompliance
date and the penalty payment is only one year, the
compounding takes the form of simply multiplying
the initial economic benefit by the sum of one plus
the discount/compound rate (i.e., $519,767×(1 +
0.10)=$571,744).
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
PO 00000
Frm 00046
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
discounts this future penalty back to the
present (i.e., 2000) at its WACC, and
arrives at $484,801.27 Because this is
less than the current economic benefit
of $519,767, the company realizes a net
gain of $48,480. This approach fails to
make the company indifferent between
compliance and noncompliance and, in
the absence of any additional gravitybased penalty components, the
company will have an incentive to delay
compliance.
If the enforcement agency instead
uses alternative B, as described in
Section II B(8)(a), the economic benefit
as expected to be calculated a year from
now in 2001 is a negative $147,798.28
The company realizes that an
enforcement agency using this approach
will conclude a year from now in 2001
that no economic benefit has been
gained, and therefore the economic
benefit-based portion of the penalty will
be zero. But the company currently
calculates its economic benefit in 2000
to be a positive $519,767. At the time of
initial noncompliance in 2000, the
company concludes that delaying the
equipment purchase will result in an
economic gain, but that it will never
have to pay any economic-benefit-based
portion of the penalty. Once again, a
risk-free approach fails to make the
company indifferent between
compliance and noncompliance and,
therefore, in the absence of any
additional gravity-based penalty
components, the company will have a
27 Even if the company were to discount the
future penalty back at a rate lower than its WACC,
this rate would still exceed the risk-free rate that
alternative A uses to compound the economic
benefit forward, and therefore the discounted future
penalty would still exceed the currently calculated
economic benefit.
28 A negative economic benefit result for the
capital investment portion of compliance is typical
for alternative B. In many recent cases, the
violators’ witnesses implementing this approach
have arrived at negative economic benefit results for
delayed capital investments, despite the fact that no
changes occurred in technological or legal
requirements over time between the dates of
noncompliance and compliance. (In other words,
the negative economic benefit result was derived
from on-time and delay scenarios involving the
same piece of capital equipment, with the passage
of time affecting only inflationary adjustments for
the cost estimate.) Applying the combination of an
extremely low risk-free rate for past cash flows and
a higher risk-adjusted rate for future cash flows to
delayed capital investments (with their past cash
outflows for the actual investment and their future
cash inflows for depreciation tax shields) can
produce aberrant results that defy common sense.
These perverse negative economic benefit estimates
do not reflect any real economic losses because of
the expenditure delay. Furthermore, even if the
parameters in this example were different, the
economic benefit—although perhaps positive—
would still be much smaller than even under
alternative A, and would similarly fail to make the
company indifferent between compliance and
noncompliance.
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
significant incentive to delay
compliance.
(iii) Equity Rate Approach
By contrast, an approach that employs
a company’s equity rate focuses solely
on the company’s equity owners, as
opposed to its other stakeholders (who
hold the company’s debt). Because the
company’s cost of equity capital will
always exceed or at least be equal to a
company’s WACC, the economic benefit
estimate—with all other assumptions
held constant—will be higher or at least
the same.29 While the Agency believes
that a reasonable argument supports the
use of equity, we nevertheless prefer the
WACC, because it better represents
firms’ total capital structures and their
own typical business decision-making
practices.
(iv) Final Change: Use WACC, Except
for a Possible Early Penalty Payment
For the above reasons, the Agency
believes that the current basic
discounting methodology is appropriate
and should not be changed, except a
minor modification in certain contexts.
The United States may consider
allowing the violator to escrow funds for
the economic benefit portion of the
penalty demand (whether at the
compliance date or at any other time).
Then, when EPA runs the BEN model,
it will use the date the funds were
escrowed as the penalty payment date.
The violator would have to furnish
proof that it established the escrow
account, as well as placed on the
account appropriate restrictions (e.g., all
accrued interest would go to the
Agency).30 This modification, when
applied to certain cases, may reduce
some of the deviation in results between
the competing discounting
methodologies. BEN will incorporate
this guidance into its help system.
8. Investment Tax Credit and LowInterest Financing
a. Background
Economic benefit calculations for
cases with noncompliance dates prior to
the mid-1980s must account for two
important tax-code effects: The
investment tax credit (ITC) and lowinterest financing (LIF).
29 The WACC will equal the equity cost of capital
if the company has no long-term debt. Note also
that an economic benefit calculation using the
equity rate should first net out any cash flows
attributable to debt financing, as the focus in such
a calculation is on the returns to the company’s
equity holders only.
30 Should the escrowed amount exceed the
benefit component, then the interest on the amount
that exceeded the economic benefit component
would accrue to the violator.
PO 00000
Frm 00047
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50337
Prior to 1986, the Federal government
allowed companies an ITC on capital
investments.31 The ITC effectively
reduced the after-tax cost of a capital
investment. Complicated and changing
rules governed the depreciation basis for
a capital investment with an associated
ITC.
Early versions of BEN used to account
for the ITC that was available on
projects completed before January 1,
1986, but did not do so for the transition
years of 1986 and 1987. The transitional
rules allowed companies to obtain an
ITC for projects completed after
December 31, 1985, if the project met
one of three criteria regarding the level
of planning and construction that had
occurred by that date.32 Because the
allowance of the ITC in these years was
far from automatic (although still
possible), BEN warned the user about
this issue for noncompliance dates
between January 1, 1986, and June 30,
1987. If further research and analysis
showed that the granting of an ITC was
likely in a particular case, then a
financial analyst could adjust the BEN
result through an ‘‘off-line’’ calculation.
Prior to 1987, LIF was available for a
business’s investment in pollution
control. A much earlier version of the
BEN model included a variable that
accounted for LIF. The 1993 version of
BEN removed this variable because it
was relevant only for cases with
noncompliance dates before 1987. Once
this variable was removed, BEN would
then issue a warning to the user about
LIF for noncompliance dates before
January 1, 1987. If further research and
analysis showed that LIF was probably
available in a particular case, then a
financial analyst could adjust the BEN
result through an off-line calculation.
b. Final Changes
A few commenters suggested that EPA
could revise the BEN model to allow an
option for ITCs during the 1986–87
transition years, as well as to account
for LIF in years prior to 1987. These
revisions would, however, add
considerable complexity to the model.
31 Note that this and other tax-related adjustments
are irrelevant for municipalities, federal facilities,
and other not-for-profit entities because their
marginal tax rate is equal to zero.
32 The criteria are: ‘‘1. It is constructed,
reconstructed, or acquired under a written contract
binding on December 31, 1985; 2. it is constructed
or reconstructed by the taxpayer, construction was
begun by December 31, 1985, and the lesser of $1
million or five percent of the cost was incurred or
committed by December 31, 1985; or 3. it is an
equipped building or plant facility, construction
was begun by December 31, 1985, under a written
specific plan, and more than one-half of its cost was
incurred or committed by December 31, 1985.’’
(Commerce Clearing House, Inc., Explanation of
Tax Reform Act of 1986, page 328.)
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50338
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
Furthermore, the Agency did not receive
any comments documenting recent
instances in which an off-line
calculation was necessary to account for
ITCs or LIF. This is not surprising EPA
Headquarters had received only one call
in response to the older BEN model’s
previous warning about LIF.
Furthermore, the already low likelihood
of the need to account for ITCs or LIF
continues to decline with the passage of
time, as EPA is not likely to see many
enforcement actions now in the mid2000s for violations that began in the
early to mid-1980s.
The June 1999 notice’s proposal on
this issue ‘‘that the revised BEN model
not accept noncompliance dates before
July 1, 1987 ‘‘did not receive any
objections from commenters. This cutoff date will ensure that BEN’s omission
of ITCs and LIF is not leading to
incorrect economic benefit estimates.
EPA will provide assistance in
performing the necessary calculations
for cases that involve noncompliance
dates before July 1, 1987.
C. Improving the BEN Model’s Userfriendliness
EPA understands that some users find
the BEN model difficult to use. While
that has not been EPA’s experience, the
Agency expressed interest in learning of
any difficulties users encountered when
running the model. The Agency
particularly requested suggestions for
realistic alternatives that would
preserve the model’s degree of
precision.
1. Is BEN Too Complex To Operate?
a. Background
EPA invited comments on whether
any aspect of BEN’s operation or user’s
documentation is too complex.
Although the Agency designed BEN to
be straightforward and easy to use, we
welcomed any suggestions to make the
model easier to use without
compromising BEN’s degree of
precision.
b. Final Changes
Many commenters thought that
although the old BEN model was
generally easy to use, certain aspects of
the prior version’s operation were
cumbersome. The Agency agrees, given
the model’s origins as a mainframe
computer application and then its
prolonged existence in the DOS
operating environment. Because
essentially all computer users are now
long accustomed to the WindowsTM
operating environment, the Agency has
decided that the revised BEN model will
continue to run in Windows (version 95
or higher). This makes basic data entry
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
and benefit calculations much easier to
perform, as well as allowing the
addition of various advanced features
without burdening the user with
additional complexity.
EPA has also established a toll-free
helpline for Federal, State, and local
government enforcement staff who need
additional assistance in using the BEN
model. The helpline provides Federal,
State, and local environmental
enforcement agencies with advice
regarding financial issues that impact
enforcement cases. The main types of
inquiries EPA is addressing with this
helpline are:
• The calculation of a violator’s
economic benefit from noncompliance;
• The evaluation of a violator’s claim
that it cannot afford to comply, clean
up, or pay a civil penalty, and the
application of the three computer
models—ABEL, INDIPAY, and
MUNIPAY 33—that address these issues;
and
• The calculation of the actual costs
of a supplemental environmental
project, and the application of the
computer model—PROJECT 34—that
addresses this issue.
Callers can obtain assistance in
downloading the BEN model and the
previously mentioned other models, as
well as relevant policies and guidance
documents. In addition, callers can
obtain advice on how to access training
courses on the models and related
subjects. Inquiries regarding the
interpretation of Federal statutes and
EPA policies will be referred to the EPA,
as will inquiries from nongovernment
employees except for relatively
straightforward technical inquiries (e.g.,
installation problems).
The toll-free helpline phone number
is 888–ECONSPT (326–6778), and is
staffed by a contractor, Industrial
Economics, Incorporated, located in
Cambridge, Massachusetts. The helpline
is in operation from 8:30 AM to 6:00 PM
Eastern time and will accept voice mail
messages when it is not in operation. In
addition, the contractor has provided a
companion e-mail address:
benabel@indecon.com. When requesting
help, enforcement staff should identify
their governmental affiliation. As
mentioned at the beginning of this
notice, anyone can download the model
through the EPA’s Web site at:
33 ABEL, INDIPAY and MUNIPAY evaluate
inability to pay claims from for-profit entities,
individuals and municipalities, respectively.
34 As most supplemental environmental projects
(SEP’s) are completed long after the cases are
settled, any stated SEP cost is usually far above the
‘‘real’’ cost to the violator. Therefore, PROJECT
calculates the SEP’s actual costs to the violator.
PO 00000
Frm 00048
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
www.epa.gov/compliance/civil/
programs/econmodels/.
2. Is the Information BEN Needs
Difficult or Expensive to Obtain?
a. Background
One of the main breakthroughs BEN
achieved over its predecessor model
was its streamlining of the data needed
to operate the model. While the model
requires a minimum of only seven data
inputs (mainly just three dates and up
to three cost estimates), some users
apparently feel the data is difficult to
obtain. This has not been EPA’s
experience, as most (if not all) of the
required data inputs are based on facts
that are already or should be known to
the litigation team as the data are
important to other parts of the
settlement. Nevertheless, the Agency
welcomed any suggestions on how to
make this data easier to obtain as long
as the model’s degree of precision is
preserved.
b. Final Changes
The Agency received a wide range of
responses on this issue. Most users
thought the necessary data was easy to
obtain; others thought it was
prohibitively difficult to obtain. EPA
did not receive any specific suggestions
on how to streamline the model’s data
requirements even further. The Agency
did receive suggestions that the BEN
model incorporate some basic, generic
compliance data.
The Agency has cost information on
its Web site for the UST (Underground
Storage Tanks) and Clean Air Act
(Stationary Sources) 35 programs. In
addition, it produced a written manual
on standardized RCRA (Hazardous
Waste) costs. These information sources
should assist users in determining
compliance costs, and then using them
in the BEN model to calculate an
economic benefit figure. Although these
information sources are not a substitute
for case-specific data, they will at least
provide a starting point and a
reasonably accurate estimate when a
violator refuses to provide any detailed
cost information.
Also, as noted at end of Section II C
(1)(b), above, EPA has established a tollfree helpline to provide assistance to
government enforcement personnel
regarding financial economics issues in
environmental enforcement cases.
Helpline staff can provide suggestions
on how to obtain the necessary data to
run the BEN model.
35 The web address for the Clean Air Act
Stationary Source information is: https://
www.epa.gov/ttn/catc/products.html.
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
the stolen food. The commenter argues
that EPA’s approach in this context
would be analogous to attempting to
Although the Agency did not request
recover the private gain, presumably the
any comment on the public comment
value of the individual’s life.
process itself, the Agency did receive
Response: As discussed in the main
several comments regarding procedural
text of this notice, the Agency finds this
issues. EPA’s responses to the major
approach unacceptable, inconsistent,
requests are as follows:
and infeasible with regard to its
• Extend the initial public comment
objectives to enforce regulatory
period: In response to such concerns,
requirements. More specifically, in the
the Agency extended the deadline for
example of the starving person, society
the initial round of public comments
has implicitly agreed that the individual
from the originally stated January 1,
may violate the normal respect for
1997, to a significantly later March 3,
private property and steal the food,
1997 (see Federal Register notice on
being required later to repay only the
December 12, 1996, at 61 FR 65391).
cost of the food. By contrast, society has
• Follow up on the public comment
period by first drafting the findings, then not agreed that companies may violate
requesting and evaluating further public environmental statutes at will whenever
they expect their private gain to exceed
comment, and finally publishing a
the social costs. To use another example
formal draft on the final decision: In
at the individual level, motorists are
response to such concerns, the Agency
required to stop at red lights even at
has done exactly that. The June 1999
deserted intersections. If a driver is
notice responded to the comments,
caught running a red light, financial
came out with a proposal, and then
compensation to other parties may not
requested further comment on that
be necessary if no accident has
proposal. This notice contains the final
occurred, but a regulatory penalty in the
findings.
• Provide a separate public comment form of a moving violation ticket is still
appropriate. A police officer is generally
process for the illegal competitive
not convinced by a violator’s argument
advantage guidance document: Since
that the lack of social damage is
the Agency has already solicited public
outweighed by the violator’s gain (in
comment on illegal competitive
terms of time saved in this example),
advantage issues, a separate public
comment process would be duplicative. and EPA is similarly not convinced by
such an analogous argument.
But as was mentioned earlier in this
notice, the EPA’s Science Advisory
2. Illegal Competitive Advantage
Board has initiated a peer review of the
Comment: Several commenters felt
draft illegal competitive advantage
that EPA has not demonstrated a clear
guidance document.
need to broaden the benefit recapture
• Submit the BEN model to a formal
framework to consider illegal
peer review process: As noted earlier,
competitive advantage, and questioned
EPA submitted its draft BEN model
whether the scenarios described in the
changes to an academic peer review in
June 1999 notice were realistic and
the spring of 2003. The process
supported by actual data. These
concluded at the beginning of 2004.
commenters felt that consideration of
III. Response to Comments
illegal competitive advantage is
appropriate only under rare and limited
A. Broad Economic Benefit Recapture
circumstances.
Issues
Response: The Agency agrees that
1. Alternatives to BEN
consideration of illegal competitive
Comment: One commenter challenged advantage will occur far less frequently
than the typical BEN-type of benefit, but
the economic rationale of the entire
it does not agree that such occurrences
benefit recapture ideology, concluding
that EPA’s current approach encourages will be rare. As the main text of this
notice explains, specifically those
compliance disproportionate with
resultant social benefits. The alternative situations are where revenues in both
the actual noncompliant and
recommendation was to base penalties
hypothetically compliant states are not
on violations’ social costs rather than
identical (as BEN implicitly assumes).
the private gains, thus providing the
As previously noted, the Agency is not
possibility of an ‘‘efficient breach,’’ a
planning to issue any guidance on the
concept from contract law. The
subject of illegal competitive advantage
illustrative example was an individual
at this time. Therefore it is premature to
lost in the woods who steals food from
address the comments that were
a cabin to avoid starvation. Under the
directed at the scenarios that appeared
social cost approach the individual
in the June 1999 notice.
would be required to repay the cost of
D. Procedural Issues Regarding the
Public Comment Process
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
PO 00000
Frm 00049
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50339
Comment: Two commenters
recommended that the Agency adopt
alternative terminology for ‘‘competitive
advantage,’’ because the scenarios
described in the June 1999 notice do not
necessarily involve ‘‘competition,’’ as in
antitrust cases.
Response: The Agency agrees that the
term may not be ideal, and has been
open to alternative suggestions.
Unfortunately, no commenter proposed
any. The underlying concept is
economic benefit that goes beyond the
BEN model’s simplifying paradigm of
delayed and/or avoided pollution
control costs, but unfortunately this is
difficult to convey in merely two or
three words.
Comment: Many commenters
expressed concern over the additional
resources necessary for the data and
analysis associated with illegal
competitive advantage. One commenter
questioned whether such analyses were
feasible altogether, and another
questioned whether EPA staff was
sufficiently qualified to undertake them.
Finally, one commenter suggested that
attempts to calculate illegal competitive
advantage should not be made until
EPA has issued formal guidance.
Response: Illegal competitive
advantage cases may involve more
detailed financial data and analysis than
typical BEN cases, although in some
cases they will involve less. When such
cases do arise, the Agency will rely
heavily on expert support, just as it
currently does for much of its more
complex economic benefit recapture
work. Moreover, the absence of formal
guidance in the interim should not
preclude staff from identifying and
analyzing illegal competitive advantage.
Recapture of economic benefit based on
illegal competitive advantage has been
EPA’s position since the inception of
the policy in 1984 to recapture all the
economic benefit from noncompliance.
There are now a series of case decisions
that have already based 100 percent of
the violator’s economic benefit on
illegal competitive advantage. It is
worth noting that in one of the cases,
the benefit calculation was so simple
that the Agency did not even need to
present expert testimony on illegal
competitive advantage.
Comment: One commenter disagreed
with the June 1999 notice’s
characterization of the role of marginal
production costs regarding illegal
competitive advantage from increased
market share. Figure 1 below reproduces
the graph that the commenter attached.
As in the classic textbook example of a
‘‘price-taking’’ firm facing a competitive
market, the firm produces up to the
point where its marginal cost of
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50340
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
production (as depicted by the line MCc
for a compliant firm) is equal to the
market equilibrium price (as depicted
by the horizontal line, P). The firm
produces quantity Qc, with a profit
equal to the triangle described by the
points P–A–B (i.e., the area lying below
the market price but above the marginal
cost curve). Although noncompliance
may alter marginal costs such that the
firm is at the lower MCnc, if it
anticipates with 100-percent certainty
the imposition of and magnitude of a
BEN-based penalty, then it will
continue to produce at Qc (not the
higher Qnc,) since the marginal costs
will eventually be retroactively incurred
in the form of the penalty. Therefore,
the BEN model captures the entire
economic benefit.
BILLING CODE 6050–50–C
Comment: The same commenter
continued with this example, but
assumed alternatively that the
noncompliant firm does not anticipate a
BEN-based penalty, for whatever reason.
With the lower marginal cost of
production MCc it produces at the
higher Qnc. A BEN-type calculation
would be based on the difference
between MCc and MCnc (i.e., the per-unit
compliance cost), multiplied by the
number of units (i.e., Qnc), and therefore
equal the area described by the points
A–C–D–E. But this overestimates the
economic benefit the company has
actually received, which is A–C–D–B
(i.e., the actual profit P–C–D, minus the
compliant profit P–A–B). Therefore,
even if the firm does gain market share
from its noncompliance, BEN would
overestimate the economic benefit, not
underestimate it.
Response: The Agency has never
encountered such a situation, especially
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
PO 00000
Frm 00050
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
EN26AU05.007
Response: If the many economic
assumptions necessary for this
hypothetical scenario are accepted
(particularly the certain anticipation of
the size of the BEN component of a
penalty), then the conclusion is correct.
But the complicated analysis necessary
to arrive at this conclusion is moot: if
the firm has not altered its behavior and
not gained any market share, then
market share from illegal competitive
advantage is not an issue.
BILLING CODE 6050–50–P
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
since such textbook graphs—while
helpful for understanding broad
economic concepts and aggregate
market behavior—may not be very
relevant for many individual firms. For
example, marginal cost curves for
individual firms are often not smooth
curvilinear functions, but rather
approximate more crude step functions.
Combined with the relatively small
magnitude of typical compliance costs
compared to total variable production
costs, the Agency is unaware of any
violator claiming that it would have
produced less had it incurred the
compliance costs on-time. Nevertheless,
this graph does illustrate the theoretical
possibility that a BEN-type calculation
could overestimate the economic benefit
if all these conditions were present. The
opposite, however, is also possible: if
the compliance costs calculation is
based upon a compliant level of
production (i.e., Qc), then the resulting
area A–C–F–B will underestimate the
actual economic benefit (i.e., A–C–D–B).
This further emphasizes the need for a
detailed examination of the company’s
actual noncompliant and hypothetically
compliant behavior (and cash flows), if
the noncompliance is reasonably
believed to have increased a violator’s
market share.
Comment: One commenter suggested
that a warning message be incorporated
in the BEN module that advises the user
that an affirmative answer to any of the
questions regarding illegal competitive
advantage indicates only the possibility
that such a situation exists and that any
presumed illegal competitive advantage
may reduce the conventional BEN
result.
Response: The Agency agrees with the
goals of this comment. The Agency has
requested the Science Advisory Board to
look at this issue as part of its review
of the ICA type of economic savings.
Thus for the immediate future, the BEN
model will not contain any questions,
references or guidance regarding ICA.
Comment: Many commenters
expressed concern over the potential for
double counting in situations where
illegal competitive advantage is
considered. In particular, several
commenters indicated that conventional
BEN calculations and those related to
illegal competitive advantage should be
mutually exclusive options for penalty
arbitration. One commenter suggested
that a penalty that incorporated both
would constitute double counting
because the violator would have forgone
some profits that are captured in the
BEN calculation. Another commenter
suggested that an illegal competitive
advantage component should not be
considered unless evidence suggests
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
that it is likely to outweigh the
conventional BEN result.
Response: The Agency agrees that
simply adding an estimate of illegal
competitive advantage to the BEN
model’s result would create the
potential for double counting. But this
is only a potential. In some cases it will
be appropriate to seek benefit recapture
based upon both types of benefit. In In
re: Lawrence John Crescio III, No. 5–
CWA–98–004, 2001 WL 537494 (May
17, 2001), an administrative law judge
assessed a civil penalty that recaptured
both types of benefit. Nevertheless, the
emphasis for illegal competitive
advantage is on a unified approach,
laying out all the relevant cash flows
associated with the on-time and delayed
compliance scenarios. The economic
benefit is then equal to the difference
between the two scenarios’ after-tax net
present values. This is the same
approach that the BEN model follows,
although the scenario construction
under illegal competitive advantage
will—almost by definition—be more
complex than under the BEN model.
Comment: Several commenters
referred to the language of the penalty
provisions of many of the statutes that
EPA is responsible for along with the
legislative history of those provisions.
They claimed that those provisions
authorize neither the recovery of illegal
competitive advantage nor the
mandated recovery of economic benefit
as a necessary penalty minimum.
Similarly, another commenter
questioned EPA’s position that the
recovery of economic benefit is ‘‘no
fault’’ in nature and suggested that it
would be incorrect to assert that it must
be recovered in every enforcement case.
Response: The passages these
commenters cite clearly show that
various members of Congress were often
equating economic benefit with
delayed/avoided compliance cost
savings. But they made this association
only because economic benefit typically
results from delayed and/or avoided
expenditures. There is nothing in the
legislative history cited by these
commenters to suggest that Congress
intended to exclude the possibility of
other kinds of economic benefit
accruing from noncompliant actions
(i.e., illegal competitive advantage).
Furthermore, the minimum recovery of
economic benefit in a penalty—
regardless of the violator’s motives or
the violation’s impacts—is a commonsense notion that need not rely entirely
on the legislative record for its support.
Even if the argument is confined to
statutory interpretation, the trier of fact,
in imposing a civil penalty, is not
limited to consider only those factors
PO 00000
Frm 00051
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50341
present in the applicable statute’s
penalty provisions. For example, judges
have recaptured economic benefit in
RCRA cases even though RCRA is silent
as to the consideration of economic
savings.
3. Other Broad Economic Benefit
Recapture Issues
Comment: Several commenters
asserted that in cases of technological
infeasibility, shutdown as a means of
compliance is an inappropriate
suggestion, both because EPA does not
have the statutory authority to mandate
shutdowns and because of the
consequential economic and social
displacement.
Response: The issue of whether the
enforcement agency should request a
judge to order a violating firm to shut
down is not germane to the discussion
of how to calculate the economic benefit
of noncompliance. What is relevant is
that the economic benefit analysis
should as a general rule (though with
reasonable exceptions) be modeled on
the actual or anticipated means of
compliance. If the facility has complied
(or will comply) by shutting down, then
the baseline assumption for the
economic benefit analysis is that the
violator should have complied on-time
by shutting down at an earlier date.
Comment: Several commenters stated
that penalties should not be assessed in
cases of industry-wide noncompliance.
In particular, some commenters argued
that penalties should not be assessed in
situations where EPA has re-interpreted
relevant regulations or failed to provide
‘‘fair notice’’.
Response: If an entire industry has
failed to comply, then all of the firms in
that industry have gained an economic
benefit that should be disgorged.
Otherwise, firms in a given industry
would have an incentive to collude in
noncompliance. In addition, one
industry may be competing against
another (hydroelectric power versus
fossil fuel based electric power) such
that the industry that fails to comply
obtains a significant advantage in that
competition. Finally, if for some reason
all the firms in a particular industry are
out of compliance, each violating firm
still obtains an economic benefit. By
delaying and/or avoiding compliance
expenditures, each of the firms is saving
money even if the playing field is level.
The Agency needs to recapture that
benefit from any violating member of
that industry if it wants to produce
deterrence.
EPA’s perspective is that the
economic benefit gained is ‘‘no fault’’ in
nature. By this the Agency means that
a company need not have intentionally
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50342
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
violated the law, or been aware of the
violation, to have accrued economic
benefit. Nevertheless, the concept of
‘‘fair notice’’ can be relevant to penalty
assessment and may be an exception to
this ‘‘no fault’’ approach. Some courts
have found that fair notice is a defense
to a penalty action if established by the
defendant. This is not saying that the
violator failed to obtain an economic
benefit from its noncompliance. Fair
notice is thus a legal defense, not an
economic one. As a policy matter, the
Agency generally does not seek any
penalties where that defense has been
clearly established.
Comment: Two commenters stated
that the BEN model does not accurately
measure regulated utilities’ economic
benefit. Specifically, one commenter
noted that because regulated utilities are
able to recover their compliance
expenditures and earn a rate of return
on those investments, the timing of
periodic rate adjustments should be
considered. For example, if compliance
expenditures associated with a new
facility are delayed until after a rate
assessment, the utility forfeits returns
on that investment until the subsequent
rate assessment, a tacit loss that is not
reflected in BEN model calculations
Response: The Agency generally
agrees that the BEN model does not
reflect that potential loss in some
situations, but it does not agree with the
implications. Specifically, the violator
has created an economic benefit, which,
depending upon the particular
circumstances, has accrued either to the
utility or to its customers in the form of
lower rates. In some cases, both the
utility and the customers obtain the
benefit. Either way, this economic
benefit should be recaptured.
Otherwise, given the joined-at-the-hips
relationship between a traditional rateof-return regulated utility and its
ratepayers, the financial incentive
would arise to avoid compliance and
thus create goodwill among ratepayers
(knowing that the economic benefit
would not be recaptured) that could
help the utility in the next rate hearing.
To ignore this benefit generated by such
a regulated utility creates a very strong
incentive to evade compliance
responsibilities.
The analogy of a landlord-tenant
relationship helps to illustrate this
concept. Suppose that the lease
conditions allow pollution control costs
to be passed through to the tenant, and
suppose that the regulatory agency
agrees that the economic benefit that the
landlord created through its violations
should not be recaptured via a civil
penalty since the economic benefit was
passed through to the tenant (in the
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
form of lower rent payments). The
landlord now has an incentive to avoid
compliance, since and thus create
goodwill with its tenant (knowing that
the economic benefit will not be
recaptured) that could help the landlord
in the next round of lease
renegotiations.
Comment: Two commenters
questioned whether economic benefit
was appropriate for Federal agencies
and facilities.
Response: Federal agencies and
facilities are no different from local,
regional, and State governmental
jurisdictions in the context of economic
benefit. Although governmental entities
do not have the same profit motive as
for-profit businesses, they may still
benefit economically from their
noncompliance, and that benefit must
be recaptured.
Comment: One commenter suggested
that by increasing focus on the recovery
of economic benefit, EPA will in fact
create an ‘‘unlevel playing field’’
because it will limit the extent of the
gravity component it can assess given
the statutory penalty maximum of
$25,000 per day.
Response: The Agency has not seen
many cases in which the economic
benefit exceeds (or is very close to) the
statutory maximum, but concedes that
in those cases even the statutory penalty
maximum may not be sufficient for
optimal deterrence. Ignoring or reducing
the economic benefit in all our penalty
actions in order to address this situation
would make little sense. The solution
required is probably a legislative issue.
Comment: One commenter felt that
EPA’s abilities to recover economic
benefit should not be permitted to
supercede the statute of limitations.
Response: The application of the
statute of limitations to a benefit
calculation is a legal issue and is well
beyond the scope of this notice. The
purpose of this notice is to determine
the best economic methodology for the
Agency employ when calculating the
economic benefit of noncompliance.
From a financial economics perspective,
the statute of limitations issue is
irrelevant. The benefit accrues to the
violator regardless of whether the first
day of noncompliance was two years
ago or ten years ago.
B. The BEN Model’s Calculation
Methodology
1. Discounting/Compounding
Comment: Many commenters
indicated that the risk-free rate is the
appropriate compounding rate for BEN
calculations. This is because
investments in pollution control carry
PO 00000
Frm 00052
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
very little, if any, systematic risk and do
not add value to a firm. Similarly, the
probability of the violation attracting an
enforcement action and the subsequent
penalty not being paid is not a relevant
risk for the present value adjustments.
Because penalty payment cash flows are
certain, a risk-free rate is the appropriate
compounding rate.
Response: The Agency is puzzled by
the critical assertion in this line of
reasoning that pollution control
investments do not add value to a firm:
would these commenters pay the same
price to purchase two firms that were
identical but for their investments in
required control equipment? As
discussed in this notice’s main text, a
risk-free rate does not accurately reflect
the benefit a company could gain
through alternative use of compliance
funds. For these reasons, the Agency
maintains that an estimate of a violator’s
cost of capital is appropriate for both
discounting and compounding purposes
in the BEN model.
Comment: Two commenters criticized
EPA’s distinction between tort damages
and economic benefit and advocated the
adoption of a risk-free compounding
rate.
Response: The Agency maintains that
tort damages and economic benefit
differ fundamentally in that the goal of
the former is to restore to the plaintiff
the amount by which it was damaged,
while that of the latter is to return the
defendant to the position it would have
been in had it complied, and thus
remove from it the amount it wrongfully
gained. Therefore, the relevant rate to
apply to the violator’s cash flows is its
cost of capital, which reflects the
minimum rate of return it can expect to
earn on average from funds not invested
in pollution control.
Comment: One commenter suggested
that a risk-free interest-forward rate be
used in BEN model calculations because
a violator would have to place funds in
a risk-free vehicle to pay the required
penalty.
Response: Outside of cases in which
a violator formally agrees during
settlement negotiations to escrow
penalty funds, the Agency is unaware of
any violator that has ever done so, and
therefore feels that this suggested
theoretical construct is highly unlikely.
Comment: One commenter pointed
out that a risk-based discount rate,
specific to the project in question,
should be utilized in BEN model
calculations.
Response: Because the project is an
investment in required pollution control
equipment, it is essentially an
investment in the continuing operations
of the firm as a whole (or the relevant
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
operations division). Thus, the WACC
accurately reflects the risk of the project.
2. Inflation Adjustments
Comment: One commenter felt that
the cost indices relied upon in the BEN
model should include an installation
component.
Response: The BEN model’s default
cost index, the Plant Cost Index (PCI),
includes such an installation
component.
Comment: One commenter believed
that future inflation rates should not be
linked to the Consumer Price Index
(CPI).
Response: Publicly available forecasts
are available only for the CPI and the
GDP price deflator. Both forecasts are
fairly close to one another, plus the
chosen value has a very small impact
upon the economic benefit result. The
Agency plans to evaluate all available
information during each year’s update
of the projected cost indices.
Comment: One commenter felt that
future inflation rates should be
adjustable or, at a minimum, EPA
should recognize analyses that
incorporate a more complex future
inflation scenario.
Response: The revised BEN model
allows the user to specify estimates of
compliance costs as of the
noncompliance and compliance dates to
reflect an alternative cost index, casespecific inflation assumptions, or
entirely different actions for on-time
and delayed compliance.
3. Other Technical Aspects
Comment: Two commenters
commended EPA’s proposal to allow for
differences in delayed and on-time
compliance scenarios. A third
commenter suggested that only in cases
where the technology necessary for
compliance was unavailable at the time
of noncompliance should such
adjustments be allowed. Otherwise, in
the on-time scenario, violators will be
encouraged to seek lower penalties by
searching for and advocating less costly
compliance measures.
Response: The Agency recognizes that
certain technological, legal, or other
circumstances may occasionally cause
on-time and delay compliance scenarios
to differ significantly. The revised BEN
model still maintains the default
assumption that the on-time and delay
scenarios are identical (but for
inflationary effects), reserving more
complicated scenarios only as an
advanced option. The burden is
implicitly always upon the violator to
provide convincing evidence that: (1) A
less-costly compliance method was
available as of when timely compliance
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
was required; and, (2) the only reason
the violator invested in the more
expensive equipment was to improve
the environment. If, as we usually find,
that the motivation to purchase the
more expensive equipment was
business-related (e.g., the more
expensive equipment was more reliable,
fit better with on-board equipment,
allowed for expansion, etc.) the Agency
assumes that the company would have
chosen that more expensive system as
its compliance option had it decided to
comply on time. Thus the cost entry for
BEN would be based on the actual
option selected by the violator for its
delayed compliance.
Comment: One commenter urged EPA
to maintain the BEN model’s previous
assumption of infinite replacement
cycles, suggesting that it is essential
when the delay period is longer (or
shorter) than the useful life of the
control equipment or when compliance
involves controls with different life
expectancies.
Response: As noted earlier in section
III.B.5, the revised BEN model will solve
this problem by implementing the
concept of economic depreciation,
which essentially calculates the lease
value of pollution control equipment. In
other words, instead of modeling the ontime replacement capital investment
and the subsequent depreciation tax
shields, and comparing that to delayed
replacement, the calculation models
leasing the equipment over the period
when the on-time equipment would
have required replacement yet the delay
equipment is still functional. The
avoided lease cost therefore serves as a
reasonable approximation of the
economic benefit from the delayed
replacement equipment installation, and
also allows the two scenarios to the
modeled out the same end point.
Comment: One commenter felt that
the BEN model default should not
consider capital replacement because
(with rare exceptions) process and
control equipment are typically
matched in terms of life expectancy.
Response: The Agency disagrees. The
control equipment will still have to be
replaced in the future, and then the
violator will benefit again as its control
equipment will still be functional
whereas the equipment would have
already required replacement had the
company complied on time.
Comment: Two commenters felt that
the BEN model should provide for a
broader range of costs, such as those
additional costs that would not have
been incurred given timely compliance
and precompliance expenditures.
Response: The revised BEN model’s
ability to accommodate different on-
PO 00000
Frm 00053
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50343
time and delayed compliance cost
scenarios, when justified, allows for
incorporation of supplementary costs, as
this comment suggests.
Comment: One commenter proposed
that when a defendant can justify doing
so, EPA should allow for alternative
depreciation strategies.
Response: The BEN model’s current
depreciation schedule reflects the most
rapid recovery available for typical
pollution control investments, resulting
in a conservative estimate of economic
benefit. The revised BEN model will
default to shorter schedules when the
useful life is less than 10 years. BEN
will also include a provision for the Job
Creation and Worker Assistance Act of
2002 depreciation bonus, which will be
keyed off the previously required
noncompliance and compliance dates,
and therefore will not require any
additional input from the user.
Comment: Many commenters
endorsed EPA’s proposed changes with
respect to investment tax credits and
low interest financing, specific tax rates,
and increased flexibility with respect to
depreciation assumptions and inflation
indices.
Response: The Agency appreciates
these comments, and hopes both
regulators and the regulated community
will find the revised BEN model a more
useful and accurate tool.
Comment: One commenter felt that
many of the changes described in the
June 1999 notice reflected ex post
factors and recommended that EPA
maintain its ex ante perspective in
calculating economic benefit.
Response: The Agency feels that the
distinction between an ex post (i.e.,
known only today, looking back in time)
and ex ante (i.e., restricted to what was
known at the time) perspective is not an
important one, and that almost all
models necessarily use a mixture of ex
ante and ex post data. The BEN model
has always used a mixture of ex ante
and ex post data, the latter of which can
be viewed as reasonable approximations
for the ex ante data that was actually
available at the time. The changes
described in the June 1999 notice
merely make the ex post data more
precise (e.g., month-by-month inflation
data, rather than a simple 10-year
average).
C. Improving the BEN Model’s UserFriendliness
1. Is BEN Too Complex To Operate?
Comment: One commenter noted that
BEN is easy to use, requires minimal
data and expertise and is well
supported.
Response: The Agency similarly feels
that BEN’s ease of use and technical
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
50344
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
support are attractive features of the
model.
2. Is the Information BEN Needs
Difficult or Expensive to Obtain?
Comment: One commenter doubted
that reliable information will be readily
available regarding on-time compliance
costs that differ from delayed costs.
Response: The use of different ontime and delayed compliance scenarios
is valid only in exceptional cases. In
these situations, the violator’s best
interest will be to provide complete
information. Otherwise, the default
assumption is that the scenarios are
identical, except for inflationary effects
over time.
3. Other Issues Affecting Use of BEN
Comment: One commenter
encouraged EPA to abandon its position
that the intended use of the BEN model
is primarily for settlement purposes.
Response: An expert witness in
litigation may use any analytical tool
the expert deems appropriate, which
may include the BEN model. But the
reality is that the Agency designed BEN
with the goal of assisting its staff for
settlement purposes. This is not a policy
position, but rather a statement of fact,
although BEN users are free to use BEN
for whatever purposes they deem
appropriate. Should a witness in a case
wish to use the BEN model in court, that
witness is free to do so, but the Agency’s
position is that the model is primarily
intended for calculating the economic
benefit for settlement purposes.
Comment: One commenter asserted
that information regarding the BEN
methodology, assumptions and
applications should be shared with the
regulated community. In addition, all
parties should have access to EPA’s
helpline. Finally, EPA should provide
all of BEN’s equations and assumptions.
Response: The Agency has made
precisely this information regarding
how the model functions available to
the public for almost twenty years. EPA
does not necessarily share all of its casespecific calculations with a violator as
that information is enforcement
sensitive, but all of the BEN model’s
formulas and databases are completely
transparent to the user. In regard to the
helpline, the regulated community’s
access to this service is restricted to
straightforward issues regarding
software installation and execution. For
resource and policy issues, EPA feels
that it would be inappropriate to
provide free consulting advice to
regulatees who are usually the subject of
enforcement actions.
Comment: One commenter felt that to
ensure consistency in penalty
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
calculations, EPA should provide
detailed guidance on economic benefit
calculations to its enforcement staff.
Response: In addition to the BEN
model’s user documentation and
assistance through the helpline, the
Agency has provided extensive on-site
in-person training to Federal, State and
local enforcement personnel. Since,
1988 EPA has presented over 80 BEN
courses. The Agency has conducted
over 42 ‘‘live’’ BEN training courses at
EPA facilities and invited State
enforcement staff to attend nearly all of
them. In addition, EPA has conducted
45 BEN training courses primarily for
State and local government personnel
in: Hartford, Connecticut (three times);
Indianapolis, Indiana (three times);
Little Rock, Arkansas; Baton Rouge,
Louisiana (twice); Trenton, New Jersey;
Boise, Idaho (three times); Ft.
Lauderdale, Florida; El Monte,
California; Baltimore, Maryland;
Richmond, Virginia (twice); Phoenix,
Arizona (twice); Lacey, Yakima and
Seattle, Washington (for State of
Washington personnel); Anchorage,
Alaska (twice); Atlanta, Georgia (for
State of Georgia personnel); Miles City,
Montana (for the State enforcement
staffs of Montana, North Dakota, and
South Dakota); Frankfort, Kentucky;
Montpelier Vermont; Raleigh, North
Carolina; Charleston, West Virginia;
Columbus, Ohio; St. Paul Minnesota;
Nashville, Tennessee; Denver, Colorado
(for the State enforcement staffs of Utah,
Colorado and Wyoming); Santa Fe, New
Mexico; Yakima and Seattle,
Washington (for State of Washington
personnel) Boston, Massachusetts (for
State of Massachusetts personnel)
(twice); Lansing, Michigan; Concord,
New Hampshire; Providence, Rhode
Island; Austin, Texas; and Honolulu,
Hawaii (twice). EPA also presented a
BEN course via satellite in 1994, and
made videotapes of that broadcast
available to government enforcement
staff on request. In addition, EPA will
soon be delivering this training to
enforcement personnel at their desks
through WebEx presentations.
Comment: One commenter
recommended that EPA assemble an
‘‘internal appeal board’’ of experts to
resolve disputes over economic benefit
issues in settlement negotiations.
Response: Creation of such a board is
not feasible. The Agency’s view is that
the decision on the appropriate civil
penalty is best worked out between the
Agency and the violator. Where
appropriate, the negotiations may
involve experts. If an agreement on the
appropriate penalty cannot be worked
out, then the matter must be resolved by
a trier of fact.
PO 00000
Frm 00054
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
Comment: One commenter felt that
EPA should disclose its methods for
calculation of economic benefit in
litigation settings (as opposed to
settlement negotiations) and that the
regulated community should be allowed
to comment on these methods.
Response: The methods employed in
litigation follow the same general
principles of the BEN model, but the
Agency is unable to predict what each
independent expert may do in each
case. Experts must testify as to their
own expertise regarding the economic
benefit of noncompliance, not as to an
Agency methodology designed to
produce settlements. In addition, parties
in litigation have very limited amounts
of time in which to produce expert
reports, depose experts, etc. It would
therefore be impossible to put these
independent experts’ testimony through
some sort of public review in the middle
of litigation. In addition, it would also
be superfluous, since such testimony is
already subject to legal discovery, and
also the focus of considerable scrutiny
in each case by the violator’s counsel
and experts.
D. Procedural Issues Regarding the
Public Comment Process
Comment: Many commenters
expressed concern over the form and
substance of the proposed guidance
document on illegal competitive
advantage and felt that the document
should be made available for public
comment.
Response: As stated previously, the
Agency feels that a separate public
comment process would be redundant.
Instead, it has initiated a peer review
process by the Agency’s Science
Advisory Board.
Comment: Two commenters advised
EPA to subject the BEN model to expert
review. In addition, one commenter
suggested that EPA should open its
broader civil penalty policy to public
comment.
Response: As noted earlier, the
Agency submitted the draft BEN model
changes to an academic peer review in
spring of 2003. With respect to broader
policy issues, the Agency has attempted
to solicit relevant comments through
this current informal notice and
comment effort. This has given the
public and interested experts extensive
opportunities to comment on these
issues. We would note that this eightyear effort was not required by law.
Comment: One commenter alleged
that the BEN model has no history of
peer review.
Response: The BEN model is exempt
from peer review because the Agency’s
peer review policy, issued in 1994,
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Federal Register / Vol. 70, No. 165 / Friday, August 26, 2005 / Notices
applies only prospectively, not
retroactively. Nevertheless, the Agency
put the BEN model through two peer
reviews in 1988 and 1991. As
mentioned in the June 1999 Federal
Register notice, copies of those peer
reviews are available to the public. In
addition, since that comment was made,
the Agency has put the model through
a third peer review. That review focused
on the changes to the model that we
were proposing as part of this Federal
Register process.
Comment: One commenter felt that
EPA should publish any final decisions
on economic benefit issues arising from
the current public comment process.
Response: All the final decisions are
detailed in the main text of this notice.
Of course, as stated previously, the
illegal competitive advantage guidance
document is not final and has instead
been submitted to a peer review by the
Agency’s Science Advisory Board.
Dated: August 18, 2005.
Granta Y. Nakayama,
Assistant Administrator, Office of
Enforcement and Compliance Assurance.
[FR Doc. 05–17033 Filed 8–25–05; 8:45 am]
BILLING CODE 6050–50–C
ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION
AGENCY
[ER-FRL–6666–8]
Environmental Impact Statements and
Regulations; Availability of EPA
Comments
Availability of EPA comments
prepared pursuant to the Environmental
Review Process (ERP), under section
309 of the Clean Air Act and Section
102(2)(c) of the National Environmental
Policy Act as amended. Requests for
copies of EPA comments can be directed
to the Office of Federal Activities at
202–564–7167. An explanation of the
ratings assigned to draft environmental
impact statements (EISs) was published
in FR dated April 1, 2005 (70 FR 16815).
Draft EISs
EIS No. 20050165, ERP No. D–NPS–
L61228–AK, Denali National Park and
Preserve Revised Draft Backcountry
Management Plan, General
Management Plan Amendment,
Implementation, AK
Summary: EPA expressed
environmental concerns due to potential
adverse impacts to water quality,
wetlands, permafrost soils and wildlife
from increased snowmobile use. EPA
requested that the final EIS include
additional monitoring plans and
contingent mitigation measures that can
VerDate jul<14>2003
16:18 Aug 25, 2005
Jkt 205001
be used with adaptive management
plans to minimize adverse impacts or
unexpected outcomes. Rating EC2.
EIS No. 20050186, ERP No. D–AFS–
C65005–NY, Finger Lakes National
Forest Project, Proposed Land and
Resource Management Plan, Forest
Plan Revision, Implementation,
Seneca and Schuyler Counties, NY.
Summary: EPA expressed
environmental concerns due to potential
adverse impacts to water quality,
riparian areas, wetlands, vernal pools
and perched oak swamps. EPA suggests
the final EIS include specific forest wide
standards and guidelines or special
resource area designations to protect
these resources. In addition, the final
EIS should consider impacts to these
areas from hydrological changes caused
by management actions on adjacent or
near by parcels. Rating EC2.
EIS No. 20050234, ERP No. D–FHW–
G40185–LA, Interstate 69, Section of
Independent Utility (SIU) 15 Project,
Construct between U.S. Highway 171
near the Town of Stonewall in DeSoto
Parish, and Interstate Highway 20 (I–
20) near the Town of Haughton in
Bossier Parish, LA.
Summary: EPA has environmental
concerns due to the proposed project
regarding air quality impacts and
transportation conformity. Rating EC2.
EIS No. 20050236, ERP No. D–AFS–
J65445–MT, Rocky Mountain Ranger
District Travel Management Plan,
Proposes to Change the Management
of Motorized and Non-Motorized
Travel, Lewis and Clark National
Forest, Glacier, Pondera, Teton and
Lewis and Clark Counties, MT.
Summary: EPA expressed
environmental concerns due to adverse
impacts from motorized uses on
watersheds and water quality, wildlife
habitat and cultural resources. EPA
believes alternative 3 best balances
conserving and protecting water quality,
fisheries and reducing impacts from
road sedimentation.
Rating EC2.
EIS No. 20050239, ERP No. D–CGD–
G39043–00, Main Pass Energy Hub
Deepwater Port License Application,
Proposes to Construct a Deepwater
Port and Associated Anchorages, U.S.
Army COE Section 10 and 404
Permits, Gulf of Mexico (GOM),
southeast of the coast of Louisiana in
Main Pass Lease Block (MP) 299 and
from the Mississippi coast in MP 164.
Summary: EPA expressed objections
to the open rack re-gasification system
due to adverse environmental impacts
to Gulf waters and habitat. EPA believes
that these impacts can be corrected by
PO 00000
Frm 00055
Fmt 4703
Sfmt 4703
50345
the project modifications or other
feasible technology, and requested
additional information to evaluate and
resolve the outstanding issues.
Rating EO2.
EIS No. 20050248, ERP No. D–COE–
G39044–TX, Upper Trinity River
Basin Project, To Provide Flood
Damage Reduction, Ecosystem
Improvement, Recreation and Urban
Revitalization, Trinity River, Central
City, Forth Worth, Tarrant County,
TX.
Summary: EPA expressed concerns
regarding the proposed project, with a
focus on potential air quality impacts.
EPA requested additional information
regarding emissions from construction
activities and how the proposed project
relates to the State Implementation Plan.
Rating EC2.
EIS No. 20050251, ERP No. D–AFS–
K65286–CA, Watdog Project, Proposes
to Reduce Fire Hazards, Harvest
Trees, Using Group Selection
Methods, Feather River Ranger
District, Plumas National Forest, Butte
and Plumas Counties, CA.
Summary: EPA expressed
environmental concerns due to the
potential for adverse impacts from
timber harvest and increased road
density to watersheds. The final EIS
should address impacts to soils, aquatic
and riparian resources, wildlife habitat
and the increased potential for noxious
weed proliferation.
Rating EC2.
EIS No. 20050264, ERP No. D–NPS–
L65491–ID, Minidoka Internment
National Monument (Former
Minidoka Relocation Center), General
Management Plan, Implementation,
Jerome County, ID.
Summary: EPA has no objections to
the proposed action.
Rating LO.
EIS No. 20050268, ERP No. D–NOA–
A91072–00, Programmatic—Codified
Regulations at 50 CFR 300 subparts A
and G Implementing Conservation
and Management Measures Adopted
by the Commission for the
Conservation of Antarctic Marine
Living Resources.
Summary: EPA expressed a lack of
objections to the proposed project.
Rating LO.
EIS No. 20050253, ERP No. DS–COE–
D35057–MD, Poplar Island
Restoration Project (PIERP) To
Evaluate the Vertical and/or Lateral
Expansion, Dredging Construction
and Placement of Dredged Materials,
Chesapeake Bay, Talbot County, MD.
Summary: EPA had no objections to
the proposed project.
E:\FR\FM\26AUN1.SGM
26AUN1
Agencies
[Federal Register Volume 70, Number 165 (Friday, August 26, 2005)]
[Notices]
[Pages 50326-50345]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 05-17033]
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
[FRL-7960-3]
Calculation of the Economic Benefit of Noncompliance in EPA's
Civil Penalty Enforcement Cases
AGENCY: Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).
ACTION: Notice of final action and response to comment.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
SUMMARY: In a Federal Register notice issued on October 9, 1996, the
Environmental Protection Agency (``EPA'') requested comment on how it
calculates the economic benefit that regulated entities obtain as a
result of violating environmental requirements. EPA makes this
calculation as a part of establishing an appropriate penalty for
settlement purposes. The Agency's policy is that any civil penalty
should at least recapture the economic benefit the violator has
obtained through its unlawful actions. Because enforcement staff
typically use the BEN (short for benefit) computer model to perform the
economic benefit calculations, the Agency requested comments on the BEN
model as well as the larger benefit recapture issues. In a subsequent
Federal Register notice issued on June 18, 1999, EPA responded to the
comments on the October 1996 Federal Register notice; provided advance
notice of the changes EPA proposed to make to its benefit recapture
approach and the BEN computer model; and requested a second round of
comment of those proposed changes. This notice responds to the comments
on the June 1999 notice and contains the changes EPA will implement in
its benefit recapture program.
ADDRESSES: The Agency has dedicated a page of its website to the
computers models the enforcement program uses to addresses benefit
recapture as well as ability to pay claims and the evaluation of the
costs of supplemental environmental projects (SEP's). The web address
for those models is: www.epa.gov/compliance/civil/econmodels/ index.
html.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: For further information, contact
Jonathan Libber, Office of Civil Enforcement, Special Litigation and
Projects Division, at (202) 564-6102, or through electronic
[[Page 50327]]
mail at libber.jonathan@epa.gov. Government users (Federal, State, or
local) can also obtain assistance with the model through the Agency's
toll-free enforcement economics helpline at (888) ECONSPT or through
electronic mail at benabel@indecon.com.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: In EPA's October 1996 Federal Register
notice, the Agency was considering changes in three areas: (1) Broad
economic benefit recapture issues; (2) the BEN computer model's
calculation methodology; and (3) improving the BEN model's user-
friendliness. In regard to the broad economic benefit recapture issues,
the Agency sought out any legitimate alternatives to BEN, but found
none. In addition, EPA solicited comments on the best way to determine
the economic benefit from the violator's illegal competitive advantage.
The comments confirmed our initial thoughts that a model to handle such
calculations was infeasible. The Agency has instead developed a draft
conceptual framework document for such cases, and has initiated a peer
review process by its Science Advisory Board to examine this type of
benefit.
With regard to the BEN model's calculation methodology, the Agency
is making eight sets of changes that should improve the model's
precision and function. Although the combined effect of these changes
will affect individual cases differently, the overall impact across all
EPA's enforcement cases should be insignificant. The two most
significant changes involve tailoring the discount/compound rate to the
case and using a more precise inflation adjustment. The new BEN model
tailors the discount rate to the period of violation through the
present, which the prior version of the model was incapable of doing.
The new BEN model also adjusts for inflation based on actual historical
month-by-month inflation data, whereas the prior version simply applied
one single average rate for both past inflation and projected
inflation. All of these changes reflect the Agency's consideration of
both rounds of public comments, as well as an academic peer review that
the Agency completed in January of 2004. These reviews should be
available by within the next few months on the Agency's computer models
web page (see ADDRESSES section above). Electronic copies of the BEN
computer model (which includes a comprehensive help system) can be
downloaded from that same site.
The major change in improving the BEN model's user-friendliness is
that EPA has moved the model from the old DOS operating system to the
Windows environment. This should address those concerns that the model
was cumbersome. We have also established a helpline to assist
enforcement personnel from Federal, State and local governments in
their use of the model.
This notice is organized as follows:
I. Background
A. Overview
B. EPA Policy and Guidance on Recapturing the Economic Benefit
of Noncompliance
1. Policy Background
2. BEN Calculates the Economic Benefit From Delayed and Avoided
Pollution Control Expenditures
3. Current Model Usage and Applicability
C. How a Firm Obtains an Economic Benefit From Delaying and/or
Avoiding Compliance Costs
1. The Economic Benefit Components that the BEN Model Measures
2. BEN and Cash Flow Analysis
II.Final Changes
A. Broad Economic Benefit Recapture Issues
1. Alternatives to BEN
2. Illegal Competitive Advantage
B. The BEN Model's Calculation Methodology
1. Depreciation Method
2. Tax Rates
3. Differences in On-Time and Delay Scenarios
4. Capital Equipment Replacement
5. Inflation Treatment
6. Discount/Compound Rate
7. Discounting/Compounding Methodology
8. Investment Tax Credit and Low-Interest Financing
C. Improving the BEN Model's User-friendliness
1. Is BEN Too Complex to Operate?
2. Is the Information BEN Needs Difficult or Expensive to
Obtain?
D. Procedural Issues Regarding the Public Comment Process
III. Response to Comments
A. Broad Economic Benefit Recapture Issues
1. Alternatives to BEN
2. Illegal Competitive Advantage
3. Other Broad Economic Benefit Recapture Issues
B. The BEN Model's Calculation Methodology
1. Discounting/Compounding
2. Inflation Adjustments
3. Other Technical Aspects
C. Improving the BEN Model's User-Friendliness
1. Is BEN Too Complex to Operate?
2. Is the Information BEN Needs Difficult or Expensive to
Obtain?
3. Other Issues Affecting Use of BEN
D. Procedural Issues Regarding the Public Comment Process
I. Background
A. Overview
One of EPA's most important responsibilities is to ensure that
regulated entities comply with Federal environmental laws. These laws--
and their implementing regulations--set minimum standards for
protecting human health and achieving environmental protection and for
achieving environmental protection goals, such as clean air and clean
water. EPA upholds these laws through vigorous enforcement actions that
seek to correct the violations and appropriately penalize violators.
A cornerstone of the EPA's civil penalty program is at least
recapturing the economic benefit that a violator may have gained from
illegal activity. Economic benefit recapture helps level the economic
playing field by preventing violators from obtaining an unfair
financial advantage over their competitors who make the necessary
expenditures for environmental compliance. Penalties also serve as
incentives to protect the environment and public health by encouraging
prompt compliance with environmental requirements and the adoption of
pollution prevention and recycling practices. Finally, appropriate
penalties help deter future violations by both the penalized entity and
by similarly situated regulatees.
EPA has promulgated a generic civil penalty policy, as well as
specific penalty policies tailored to suit the needs of particular
regulatory programs. For example, one civil penalty policy specifically
addresses violations of the Clean Water Act. The civil penalties that
EPA seeks usually embody two components: gravity and economic benefit.
The gravity component reflects the seriousness of the violation and is
generally determined through the application of the appropriate EPA
civil penalty policy.
The economic benefit component, on the other hand, focuses on the
violator's economic gain from noncompliance, i.e., the extent to which
the violator is financially better off because of its noncompliance.
This economic benefit can accrue to the violator in three basic ways:
(1) Delaying necessary pollution control expenditures; (2) avoiding
necessary pollution control expenditures; and/or (3) obtaining an
illegal competitive advantage. The term ``illegal competitive
advantage'' is a broad catch-all category for economic benefit that
goes beyond that derived from the mere delay and/or avoidance of
pollution control expenditures. For example, the violator might have
sold a product that is entirely illegal (and could not have been
produced legally by incurring any pollution control expenditures).
The Agency designed the BEN computer model in 1984 to calculate the
economic benefit from these first two
[[Page 50328]]
types of economic gain for settlement purposes. BEN may not be
appropriate for all cases, and EPA's regional offices may use
alternative approaches that produce reasonably accurate benefit
calculations. For example, the pattern of necessary pollution control
expenditures might be so complicated that a customized spreadsheet
computation would be more appropriate than BEN. Alternatively, the
pattern of expenditures might be so simple that a mere table in a word
processing document would suffice. Nevertheless, the Agency believes
that in the vast majority of cases BEN is by far the best approach
available for calculating economic benefit derived from delayed and/or
avoided costs.
The Agency does not have a computer model for calculating the
benefit gained from an illegal competitive advantage. EPA considers
such gains on a case-by-case basis.
B. EPA Policy and Guidance on Recapturing the Economic Benefit of
Noncompliance
Since the BEN computer model's development in 1984, EPA staff have
used BEN extensively in generating penalty figures for settlement
purposes. These figures reflect the economic benefit a violator derived
from delaying and/or avoiding compliance with environmental statutes.
1. Policy Background
Calculating a violator's economic benefit using the BEN computer
model is usually the first step in developing a civil settlement
penalty figure under the Agency's Policy on Civil Penalties (PT.1-1)
February 16, 1984, and A Framework for Statute-Specific Approaches to
Penalty Assessments (PT.1-2) February 16, 1984. The Agency developed
the BEN computer model to assist in fulfilling one of the main goals of
the Policy on Civil Penalties: to recover, at a minimum, the economic
benefit derived from noncompliance.
The BEN computer model is a tool that is primarily intended to be
used in calculating economic benefit for purposes of developing a
settlement penalty. In presenting economic benefit testimony at a
judicial trial or in an administrative hearing, the Agency relies on an
expert in financial economics to provide an independent analysis of the
economic benefit the violator obtained from its violations, reflecting
the expert's own analytical approach as applied to the particular facts
of that case. Use of an expert in a trial or hearing allows the parties
the opportunity to examine more closely the analysis applied to the
facts at issue, since a computer model itself cannot be deposed or
cross-examined.\1\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\1\ EPA designed the BEN model as a flexible tool primarily for
use in settlement negotiations; it is not used, nor was it ever
intended to function, as a rule. An expert witness testifying for
the government may use the new Windows version of BEN as
appropriate, but the responsibility to determine the economic
benefit--as well as explain and defend the results--still resides
with the expert. That expert may choose to use whatever analytical
tool (e.g., customized computer spreadsheets, the BEN model, or even
a calculator) deemed appropriate for the particular calculations
necessary in the case.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. BEN Calculates the Economic Benefit From Delayed and Avoided
Pollution Control Expenditures
The BEN model calculates the economic benefit from delaying and/or
avoiding required environmental expenditures. Delayed costs can include
capital investments in pollution control equipment, remediation of
environmental damages (e.g., removing unpermitted fill material and
restoring wetlands), or one-time expenditures required to comply with
environmental regulations (e.g., establishing a reporting system, or
purchasing land on which to site a wastewater treatment facility).
Avoided costs typically include operation and maintenance costs and/or
other annually recurring costs (e.g., off-site disposal of fluids from
injection wells), but can occasionally include capital investments or
one-time expenditures. BEN does not calculate the economic benefit that
takes the form of illegal competitive advantage. For example, the BEN
model is not the appropriate method for calculating the economic
benefit derived from selling DDT on the black market to U.S. pesticide
applicators.
3. Current Model Usage and Applicability
The BEN model can be used in all cases that have delayed and/or
avoided compliance costs. (The only exception is Clean Air Act Section
120 enforcement actions, which require the application of a specific
computer model.) EPA designed BEN to be easy to use for people with
little or no background in economics, financial analysis, or computers,
although it is also useful for those with such backgrounds. Because the
program contains standard default values for many of the variables
needed to calculate the economic benefit, BEN can be run with only a
small number of required inputs from the user. The program also allows
the user to replace those standard values with case-specific
information. The table below lists the inputs to the BEN model, both
the required inputs and also those inputs with standard default values
that may be modified.
The BEN model can calculate economic benefit for many types of
organizations: corporations, partnerships, sole proprietorships, not-
for-profit organizations, federal facilities, and municipalities. BEN
customizes its standard values to the entity type, as well as other
aspects of the case. The BEN inputs listed in the table are discussed
in detail in the model's help system.
Inputs for BEN
Required Inputs:
--Descriptive Information (case name, office/agency, analyst name)
--Entity Type and State
--Competitive Advantage Questionnaire
--Penalty Payment Date
--Capital Investment (cost estimate and estimate date)
--One-Time Nondepreciable Expenditure (cost estimate and estimate date)
--Annually Recurring Costs (cost estimate and estimate date)
--Date of Initial Noncompliance
--Date of Compliance
Inputs with Standard Default Values that May be Modified:
--Year-Specific Marginal Income Tax Rates
--Discount/Compound Rate
--Cost Index for Inflation (specified separately by compliance cost
component)
--Consideration of Future Capital Replacement
--Useful Life of Capital Equipment
--Delayed v. Avoided (specified separately for capital and one-time
nondepreciable)
--Tax Deductibility (of one-time nondepreciable expenditure)
--Specific Cost Estimates (for on-time and delay scenarios)
C. How a Firm Obtains an Economic Benefit From Delaying and/or Avoiding
Compliance Costs
An organization's compliance with environmental regulations usually
entails a commitment of financial resources, both initially (in the
form of a capital investment or one-time expenditure) and over time (in
the form of continuing, annually recurring costs). These expenditures
should result in better protection of public health or environmental
quality, but they are unlikely to yield any direct economic benefit
(i.e., net gain) to the organization. (Otherwise, and with the
assumption of some measure of foresight, the organization should have
already committed the financial
[[Page 50329]]
resources, even in the absence of such environmental regulations.) If
these financial resources are not used for compliance, then they
presumably are invested in projects with an expected financial return
to the organization. This concept of alternative investment--that is,
the amount the violator would normally expect to make by investing in
something other than pollution control--is the basis for calculating
the economic benefit of noncompliance.
In implementing EPA's penalty policies, the Agency invokes its
authority to assess penalties to remove or neutralize the economic
incentive to violate environmental regulations. In the absence of
enforcement and appropriate penalties, an organization's narrowly
construed economic interest would usually dictate delaying the
commitment of funds for compliance with environmental regulations and
avoiding certain associated costs, such as operation and maintenance
expenses.
1. The Economic Benefit Components That the BEN Model Measures
A violator may gain an economic benefit from either delaying and/or
avoiding compliance costs. By delaying compliance, the violator can
earn a return on the funds that should have been committed to the
capital investment or one-time expenditure required for pollution
control compliance. In other words, violators have the opportunity to
invest their funds in projects other than those required to comply with
environmental regulations. These other investments are expected to
generate a financial return, as opposed to the required pollution
control investments that typically generate no direct financial return
for a company. Thus, by delaying compliance, the violator's economic
benefit is the difference between investing in pollution control and
investing in other projects.
A violator can also gain an economic benefit from avoiding
pollution control costs. Avoided costs typically include the
continuing, annually recurring costs that a violator would have
incurred had it complied with environmental regulations on time (e.g.,
the costs of labor, raw materials, energy, lease payments and any other
expenditures directly associated with the operation and maintenance of
pollution control equipment). Annual costs are thereby avoided
entirely, as opposed to capital investments and one-time expenditures
that are usually only delayed.\2\ Thus, the violator's economic benefit
from avoided costs is the sum of the total avoided annual costs plus
the return that could be expected on the funds that were used for
projects other than pollution control.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\2\ Even capital investments and one-time expenditures may be
avoided on occasion. The typical situation where this happens is
when a violator shuts down a particular operation rather than
install required pollution control equipment.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
2. BEN and Cash Flow Analysis
The BEN model calculates economic benefit by focusing on the effect
that delayed and/or avoided pollution control costs have on an entity's
cash flows. Cash flow analysis is a standard and widely accepted
technique for evaluating costs and investments. In essence, cash flow
calculations focus on the real, ``out-of-pocket'' cash effects
resulting from an expenditure.\3\ Three important factors that enter
into BEN's cash flow analysis are inflation, taxation, and the time
value of money.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\3\ Thus, noncash ``paper'' expenses, such as depreciation, are
considered only to the extent that they affect cash flow.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
a. Inflation
BEN first requires users to enter a single cost estimate for the
capital investment and another single cost estimate for the one-time
nondepreciable expenditure. Then, to adjust for inflation, BEN
extrapolates from this single cost estimate to create separate
estimates for the hypothetical cost of complying on-time and the actual
cost of complying in a delayed fashion. Similarly, BEN extrapolates
from the user's annually recurring cost estimate to a complete set of
cost estimates for every year during the noncompliance period. (The BEN
model's help system provides a more detailed discussion of these
inflation adjustments.) These adjusted cost estimates form the basis
for the on-time and delay scenarios: The actions and associated costs
that would have been necessary for hypothetical on-time compliance, and
the actions and associated costs that were necessary for the actual
delayed compliance.
b. Taxation
The BEN model computes economic benefit on an after-tax basis,
since environmental expenditures can reduce income tax liability.\4\
Depreciation (from capital investments), one-time expenditures, and
annual costs all effectively reduce taxable income and thereby reduce
income tax payments. To account for these tax effects, BEN calculates
the economic benefit using after-tax cash flows for the on-time
compliance and delayed compliance scenarios.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\4\ The term environmental expenditures refers to firms'
compliance costs and does not include the payment of civil
penalties. Civil penalties are in almost all cases not deductible.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
c. Time Value of Money
A third factor relates to the timing of the cash flows, because
cash flows occurring in different years are not directly comparable.
The fundamental financial concept of the time value of money is based
on the principle that a dollar today is worth more than a dollar a year
from now, since today's dollar can be invested immediately to earn a
return over the coming year. (Alternatively, a dollar last year is
worth more than a dollar today because investment opportunities existed
for last year's dollar.) Therefore, the earlier a cost (or benefit) is
incurred, the greater its economic impact.
BEN accounts for the time value of money by adjusting all estimated
cash flows to their present value equivalents. BEN first discounts back
to the initial noncompliance date all cash flows from the on-time and
delay scenarios. The initial economic benefit as of this date is simply
the difference in the present values of these two scenarios. Finally,
BEN compounds the initial economic benefit forward from the
noncompliance date to the penalty payment date.
To adjust the cash flows for both discounting and compounding, BEN
uses a discount or compound rate (depending on the direction of the
adjustment) that reflects the time value of money. The selection of the
appropriate rate, and the structure of the discounting and compounding
methodology, is a significant issue in the BEN model and will be
addressed later in this notice. (The model's help system provides a
more detailed discussion of the discounting and compounding that BEN
performs for its present value adjustments.)
II. Final Changes
In its October 9, 1996, Federal Register notice, the Agency sought
comment on three categories of issues: (1) Broad economic benefit
recapture questions, (2) the BEN model's calculation methodology and
assumptions, and (3) the model's user-friendliness. The June 18, 1999,
notice provided responses to these comments, as well as advance notice
of EPA's proposed changes to the BEN model. The June 1999 notice also
invited a second round of public comments, especially on EPA's proposed
changes. EPA also conducted a peer review by academic experts in
financial economics during the spring of 2003 on the draft proposed
changes to the model. This peer review of the model changes was
[[Page 50330]]
specifically requested by the United States Senate.\5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\5\ Senate Report No. 106-410 (2000) at page 81.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The first area in which we invited comment covered some fundamental
questions that the benefit recapture approach has raised. Is there an
alternative to the BEN model that would be both easier to use and at
least as accurate in calculating the economic benefit of delayed and/or
avoided pollution control expenditures? How should EPA evaluate the
economic benefit that companies receive as a result of any illegal
competitive advantage stemming from noncompliance?
Second, we invited comment on the BEN model's calculation
methodology. While the Agency is confident that the BEN model's overall
approach is theoretically sound, we welcomed constructive and
documented comment on alternative methodologies. In particular, EPA has
been aware of substantial differences of opinion with respect to
inflation adjustments and discounting/compounding. EPA requested
comment on the BEN model's calculation methodology, or any other aspect
of the model's assumptions or methodology.
Third, we requested comment on the model's user-friendliness. The
Agency had heard concerns that the model is too difficult to use,
particularly regarding the necessary data acquisition. Because EPA had
never been presented with any concrete evidence in support of these
assertions, the Agency wanted either to substantiate the problems and
address them or to put these issues to rest.
In the following sections, we address the final changes that EPA is
making in each of the areas on which we requested comment. Note that
final changes incorporate EPA's consideration not only of the public
comments but also of the previously mentioned academic peer review that
EPA completed in January of 2004.
A. Broad Economic Benefit Recapture Issues
1. Alternatives to BEN
a. Background
EPA requested comment on whether anyone had an approach that would
be simpler and at least as accurate as BEN in calculating the economic
benefit from delayed and/or avoided pollution control expenditures. EPA
designed the BEN model to calculate the economic benefit of
noncompliance in settlement of the vast majority of its civil penalty
enforcement cases. Although BEN has served this purpose effectively,
the Agency recognizes that it should be improved or even replaced if a
better alternative exists or could be developed easily. This concern is
particularly relevant because an increasing number of State and local
government enforcement personnel use the BEN model regularly. Any
alternative approach must meet EPA's policy objective of ensuring that
violators are put on an even financial footing with those regulated
entities that comply on time. Alternatives must also be reasonably
accurate, simple to use, and readily understandable to the vast
majority of the BEN model's users--Federal, State and local government
enforcement officials who usually have limited knowledge of financial
economics.
b. Final Changes
Many commenters expressed various criticisms on different aspects
of the BEN model. But these criticisms focused on suggestions for
improving BEN. No commenter proposed an alternative approach to a
stand-alone computer model that performs net present value
calculations. Therefore, the Agency will continue its use of BEN,
although it will also implement significant revisions (see following
sections).
On a related topic, two commenters questioned the entire benefit
recapture framework. Although one comment along these lines was
somewhat unclear, the other comment presented a comprehensive approach
for basing penalties on the lesser of economic benefit or social cost
(i.e., environmental damages). Under this proposal, if a violator
gained a significant economic benefit from its violations but caused
only trivial environmental damage (as monetized through some
unspecified economic methodology), then the penalty would be
commensurately trivial. The Agency finds this approach entirely
unacceptable in the context of enforcing regulatory requirements for
individual violators. The appropriate context for considering social
costs is in the process of formulating proposed regulations. Penalties
based on social costs (when less than economic benefit) would provide
an implicit yet clear incentive to violate the law if a company
anticipated that its economic benefit would exceed the consequent
measurable environmental damage. Further, such an approach would be
fundamentally unfair to those firms that resisted the temptation to
violate the law. In addition, quantifying environmental damages in a
monetary measure is an exceedingly difficult analytical problem. Even
if this fundamentally different approach was theoretically sound, it
would be infeasible for the vast majority of enforcement cases.
2. Illegal Competitive Advantage
a. Background
Since the issuance of EPA's Policy on Civil Penalties in 1984, the
Agency has maintained that any given penalty should be structured to
recover--at a minimum--the economic benefit a violator has enjoyed as a
result of its noncompliance. That 1984 policy recognized that the
benefit would be based on delayed costs, avoided costs and illegal
competitive advantage. In addition to this economic benefit component,
EPA assesses a gravity component that reflects the seriousness of the
violation. This gravity component is designed to ensure that the
penalty puts the violator in a worse position than those in the
regulated community who complied with the law. The economic benefit
component of EPA's civil penalty policy focuses specifically on
identifying and recovering the gain to a violator in order to remove
any economic incentive to violate environmental regulations.
The BEN model calculates the economic benefit from delaying and/or
avoiding required environmental expenditures. The economic benefit that
arises from situations other than the delay and/or avoidance of
pollution control expenditures is broadly termed ``illegal competitive
advantage,'' which BEN is incapable of measuring. The essential
distinction between these two types of economic benefit is that in the
illegal competitive advantage situation, the violator's noncompliant
actions have allowed (or will allow) it to attain a level of revenues
that would have been unattainable had it always been in compliance. In
delayed and avoided costs situations, the implicit assumption is that
the revenues from a noncompliant and compliant state are identical.
Consequently, BEN focuses exclusively on a violator's pollution control
costs and does not require any data on the violator's revenues.
In either type of situation (BEN-type economic benefit or illegal
competitive advantage), the fundamental definition of economic benefit
is still the same: The economic benefit is the difference in the net
present values of the compliant/on-time and noncompliant/delay
scenarios (i.e., the actions and cash flows--both historical and
possibly also future--associated with the hypothetical compliance, and
the actual noncompliance). But in the cases
[[Page 50331]]
amenable to BEN, the violator's revenues from the compliant and
noncompliant states simply cancel each other out, allowing BEN to
measure economic benefit through a calculation involving only the costs
that would have differed had the violator been in compliance. Illegal
competitive advantage encompasses all situations in which the revenues
do not cancel out each other. Since the revenues were higher in the
noncompliant state than they would have been in a compliant state, more
detailed research and analysis is necessary, going beyond the scope of
the BEN model.
The BEN model's widespread application is made possible by its
simplifying assumption regarding revenues, obviating the need for a
detailed examination of a violator's business records or competitive
market situation. But in some cases, this assumption is not valid.\6\
In such cases, the violator would not have been able to generate a
given level of revenues were it not for its noncompliance. In those
cases, EPA's policy is to seek to recapture the economic benefit based
on the violator's illegal competitive advantage.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\6\ The Agency suspects that this relationship may be reversed
for cases involving wetlands. Although the evidence is largely
anecdotal, most wetlands cases encompass violations that allowed a
violator to engage in operations that would not have been feasible
but for the violation. Therefore, in evaluating wetlands cases, the
Agency will be particularly sensitive to the possible presence of
illegal competitive advantage.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Final Changes
The Agency received many comments on illegal competitive advantage.
The first round of comments focused mainly on the feasibility of
developing a stand-alone computer model analogous to BEN (or an add-on
module to BEN) that could easily and reliably determine the economic
benefit from the widely varying examples of illegal competitive
advantage. The broad consensus was that no such model was feasible, and
the Agency agrees. Without BEN's simplifying assumption that the
violator's revenues from the on-time and delay scenarios cancel out
each other, no ``one-size-fits-all'' computer model can analyze the
range of likely situations.
The second round of comments the Agency received on illegal
competitive advantage mainly focused on the June 1999 notice's proposed
questions for BEN's module and the illegal competitive advantage
examples. But since the ICA concept is currently under review by EPA's
Science Advisory Board (SAB), OECA will not put any ICA questions in
the revised BEN model.
After careful review of the comments, and in light of the fact that
the SAB is currently reviewing the ICA issues, EPA has decided against
publishing at this time any formal guidance delineating detailed
analytical steps. While EPA remains committed to recapturing economic
benefit based on illegal competitive advantage, if appropriate,
quantifying illegal competitive advantage requires a careful
examination of the facts of the particular case, and EPA believes it is
premature to try to establish formal guidance in light of these case-
specific issues. Similarly, the Agency does not envision providing a
specific formula for calculating a benefit component in such cases.
In summary, EPA will continue to seek the recovery of illegal
competitive advantage in cases where the BEN model is incapable of
fully assessing the extent to which a violator is financially better
off as a result of its noncompliance. The proper evaluation of illegal
competitive advantage will involve verifying that the use of the BEN
model alone is inappropriate to the case-specific facts, and then
formulating an analytical approach that captures the extent of the
violator's gain.
B. The BEN Model's Calculation Methodology
Over the years, BEN has received occasional criticism for alleged
flaws in its calculation methodology, particularly regarding the
model's inflation adjustments and discounting/compounding. The Agency
requested substantive comments on how the BEN model handles these two
issues. In addition, EPA invited comment on all aspects of BEN's
calculation methodology. The Agency also asked commenters to address
whether their proposed changes would add any complexity to the computer
model and, if so, why the benefit of the change justified the added
complexity.
1. Depreciation Method
a. Background
The BEN model calculates depreciation for capital investments,
since the tax deduction for accounting depreciation charges provides a
real after-tax positive cash flow to businesses.\7\ BEN used to
calculate depreciation using a five-year straight-line methodology for
capital investments made before January 1, 1987, and a seven-year
Modified Accelerated Cost Recovery System for capital investments made
after January 1, 1987. These assumptions represent the most rapid
depreciation periods available for typical pollution control
investments, thereby producing the positive depreciation cash flow
effects as early as possible. These particular depreciation methods
generally result in a conservative economic benefit calculation (i.e.,
lower than would otherwise be calculated) because they minimize out-of-
pocket costs to the violator. Therefore, BEN is often producing
economic benefit figures that are very conservative.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\7\ The IRS does not allow companies to write off completely a
capital investment in the year of purchase. Companies must spread
the expense of the investment over several years using the
appropriate depreciation schedule.
\8\ The IRS requires that many types of pollution control
equipment be depreciated over a longer period than assumed in the
BEN model. Were EPA to tailor the depreciation to account for that
longer period, the result would be a higher economic benefit
calculation.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
For capital equipment that has a very short useful life, the
selection of alternative depreciation schedules might be available and
also more beneficial to a business. In unusual cases where the violator
can demonstrate that an alternative depreciation schedule would be both
available and beneficial, more detailed calculations by a financial
analyst in lieu of the BEN model may be necessary.
b. Final Changes
EPA received no comments on its proposal in the June 1999 notice
that although a revised BEN model could conceivably allow alternative
depreciation schedules, the drawbacks of the added complexity and
potential user confusion might outweigh the gains from addressing a
rare circumstance. Nevertheless, EPA has devised a relatively simple
means for BEN to apply shorter depreciation schedules when the user
enters a capital equipment useful life less than 10 years (as opposed
to the default 15 years).
The specification of shorter depreciation schedules will ensure
that BEN does not overestimate economic benefit in the relatively rare
cases that involve such short-lived capital equipment. Once the shorter
useful life has been specified, the alternative depreciation schedule
will not require any additional input from the user. BEN will also
include a provision to account for legislation that allows for
depreciation bonuses over certain periods. This provision will key off
the previously required noncompliance and compliance dates, and it
therefore will
[[Page 50332]]
not require any additional input from the user.
2. Tax Rates
a. Background
The DOS versions of BEN that were issued after 1993 used to apply
three marginal tax rates: a rate for 1986 and before, one for 1987
through 1992, and one for 1993 and beyond. Users could accept the
standard values--which incorporate national averages of State tax
rates--or modify the inputs to reflect specific State values.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\9\ Tax rate modification can also reflect a business whose low
net income entails a tax bracket other than the assumed highest
bracket. Note that BEN's assumption of the highest marginal tax rate
produces a lower economic benefit calculation than assuming a lower
tax rate because a higher tax rate decreases the compliance costs'
after-tax value. Since the model employs an after-tax cost in its
analysis, the lower the tax, the higher the BEN result.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Final Changes
EPA did not receive any objections to the June 1999 notice's
proposal that the revised BEN model will require the user to enter the
violator's State of operation, then automatically reference an internal
database of State tax rates and perform the necessary calculations for
the violator's combined Federal and State tax rate.\10\ BEN will
calculate the tax rate for each separate year of noncompliance, to
allow for annual changes in the relevant State tax rate (even when the
Federal rate remains constant). Users will have the additional option
of entering year-by-year combined Federal and State rates in a
spreadsheet-like format.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\10\ The model will also offer the option of the national
average of all the State tax rates for cases where the State in
which the violator pays taxes is unclear.
\11\ This option would allow users to account for, among other
situations, a company whose profitability (and hence tax bracket)
was highly variable over different years. (As noted before, BEN's
assumption of the highest marginal tax rate throughout the
noncompliance period results in a lower economic benefit estimate
than would be produced by a more precise calculation of the
violator-specific marginal tax rate.)
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Although these options may sound complex, the only data required of
the user will be the violator's State. The other screens for additional
data entry and modification will appear only to those users who
selected such advanced options.
3. Differences in On-Time and Delay Scenarios
a. Background
The BEN model's baseline assumption is that the violator would have
used the same technology and approach in the hypothetical on-time
compliance as it did in the actual delayed compliance scenario. The
only allowed differences are in the two scenarios' exact costs of
compliance, which BEN adjusts for automatically in its inflation
treatment. But technological, legal, or other relevant changes between
the on-time and delay scenarios can conceivably alter the components of
the compliance scenarios, increasing or decreasing the compliance costs
by a rate other than general price inflation. Where the delay case
costs are substantially less than the on-time case costs (e.g., a
technological breakthrough in control equipment), BEN will understate
the benefit. Where the delay costs are substantially higher (e.g.,
regulations become more stringent, but with ``grandfather'' clauses for
already-compliant firms) BEN will overstate the benefit.
Where, in the unusual case, the on-time and delay compliance
scenarios are significantly different, BEN's baseline assumption of two
identical scenarios is inappropriate.\12\ More sophisticated
calculations are necessary.\13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\12\ The inexperienced user will become aware that a more
sophisticated analysis is needed because there are two sets of cost
figures, but only one place to put them. The more experienced user
will just go directly to the ``Specific Cost Estimates'' option
during data entry.
\13\ A similar problem arises when no technologically feasible
method of compliance is available. If the only possible compliance
method that the Agency would have allowed is to cease all
production, then this falls under the category of illegal
competitive advantage, which by definition is beyond the scope of
the BEN model.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
b. Final Changes
EPA received only one minor objection to the June 1999 notice's
proposal that the revised BEN model allow users to enter separate on-
time and delayed compliance costs. Although the standard operation of
the revised model will still entail only a single compliance scenario,
the new screens for additional data entry/modification of separate on-
time vs. delay scenarios will be available to those users who select
such advanced options. The availability of more advanced options will
also enhance the model's ability to account for atypical situations
such as valid pre-compliance expenditures and credits for salvaged
capital equipment, thus decreasing the need for off-line calculations.
4. Capital Equipment Replacement
a. Background
One of the three components of compliance costs BEN analyzes is the
capital investment, which represents depreciable pollution control
equipment. As the name implies, depreciable equipment wears out with
usage and the passage of time. BEN used to ask the user if the violator
will need to replace the equipment at some point in the future. If the
user specified that the investment in capital equipment is recurring,
then the user could accept the standard value of 15 years for the
useful life of the capital equipment, or enter another value.
If the capital equipment does need to be replaced in the future,
then the violator is financially better off from its delayed compliance
in two distinct yet related ways: the violator has received a benefit
in the past from delaying the initial purchase of the capital
equipment, and will receive a benefit in the future from delaying the
replacement of the capital equipment when that initial purchase wears
out. For example, if a steel mill delays installation of a $1,000,000
baghouse for 5 years, it first obtains a benefit from delaying the
purchase of that baghouse for 5 years. But when that baghouse needs to
be replaced 15 years later, the violator's second baghouse is purchased
5 years later than it should have because the initial purchase lasted
five years later than if it had complied on time.
b. Final Changes
Some commenters characterized any consideration of future
replacement cycles as ``speculative,'' as these cycles have yet to
occur in the typical case (because the noncompliance period is almost
always shorter than the capital equipment's useful life). EPA agrees
only to the extent that BEN does make an assumption about the future,
but this assumption is essentially a baseline one: BEN assumes that
future pollution control requirements will be neither more stringent
nor more lax than current requirements, and that the cost of the
replacement equipment will increase by no more and no less than the
projected rate of inflation. Therefore, the Agency will retain the BEN
model's default consideration of capital equipment replacement.
Some commenters argued that BEN should not offer infinitely
recurring replacement cycles. The Agency notes that although modeling
infinite cycles might at first seem excessive, all future costs are
``discounted'' back to their present values (see following sections for
an explanation of discounting). Thus, the first replacement cycle
typically has a relatively small impact on the benefit calculation.\14\
The impact
[[Page 50333]]
of later replacement cycles is almost negligible.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\14\ If the initial capital investment is $1 million and the
equipment lasts for 15 years, then the first replacement cycle is
still $1 million (assuming, for now, the lack of any intervening
inflation). But since it is purchased 15 years later, the $1 million
is discounted to a present value at, for example, 10 percent, over
15 years. The first replacement cycle would only increase the
benefit component by about 30%. The second replacement cycle is
purchased 30 years later. Thus, the $1 million piece of equipment is
discounted at the same 10 percent over 30 years. The economic
benefit from the delay of that second replacement cycle would only
increase the benefit component by about 7%.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
Some commenters, as well as academic peer reviewers, favored the
approach of a finite number of replacement cycles (which the Agency
initially proposed to adopt). But one peer reviewer pointed out that
this approach runs into problems when the noncompliance period is very
long, especially when it approximates the useful life of the capital
equipment. For example, assume a 10-year compliance delay, coupled with
a 10-year useful life. If BEN were to use one replacement cycle, the
on-time scenario would include two capital equipment installations,
covering the years 1 through 20. The delay scenario would also include
two capital equipment installations, but run from years 11 through 30.
BEN would implicitly be stating that the violator would need to have
functional equipment in place for years 21 through 30 (i.e., the delay
scenario's replacement cycle), but that a company complying on-time
need not do so (i.e., since the cash flow analysis for the on-time
scenario runs out only to the year 20).
Therefore, the revised BEN model will adopt this peer reviewer's
solution by implementing the concept of economic depreciation, which
essentially calculates the lease value of pollution control equipment.
In other words, instead of modeling the on-time replacement capital
investment and the subsequent depreciation tax shields, and comparing
that to delayed replacement, the calculation models leasing the
equipment over the period when the on-time equipment would have
required replacement yet the delay equipment is still functional. The
avoided lease cost, therefore, serves as a reasonable approximation of
the economic benefit from the delayed replacement equipment
installation, and also allows the two scenarios to the modeled out to
the same end point. Furthermore, projections far into the future are no
longer necessary, as the imputed lease cost is calculated only for the
interim period when the on-time equipment would have required
replacement yet the delay equipment is still functional.
This approach will add a few new cells on one of the pages in the
BEN detailed printouts, yet allow the elimination of another entire
page of calculations. It will also simplify the previous 0-5
replacement cycles optional input to a simple ``yes/no'' choice for the
consideration of future capital replacement (with the default set to
``yes''). The previously included optional input for the future
inflation rate (which applied only to replacement cycles in addition to
the first one) will be eliminated.
5. Inflation Treatment
a. Background
The first step in the economic benefit calculation is to determine
the compliance costs--for both the on-time and delay scenarios--as of
the year in which they were actually incurred (or should have been
incurred). Therefore, BEN adjusts the compliance costs from the date
they were estimated to the date the costs will be incurred to account
for the effects of inflation.
To adjust for inflation, BEN previously used a standard-value rate
calculated from the prior ten years of inflation data from the Plant
Cost Index (PCI) in the magazine Chemical Engineering. (The PCI is
generally the cost index most relevant to the types of costs typically
associated with pollution control technology.) This simple inflation
rate adjusted the initial compliance cost estimates. BEN applied this
simple inflation rate to the compliance cost figures in order to
determine what compliance would have cost at the noncompliance date.
Then BEN applied the same simple inflation rate to determine what the
costs actually were (or will be) at the compliance date. Finally, the
model used the same rate to go well into the future to determine what
those costs will be for the capital equipment replacement cycles.
b. Final Changes
Despite the Agency's specific request for comment on BEN's
inflation adjustment, we received almost none. The issues that the few
commenters did raise were:
(1) The use of a single inflation rate for both actual and
projected inflation,
(2) The basis for the actual inflation rate, and
(3) The basis for the projected inflation rate.
For actual historical inflation, the revised BEN model will adjust
each cash flow automatically from the date of the cost estimate to the
date on which it is incurred by referencing a look-up table of cost
index values.\15\ The default cost index will be the PCI. This
particular index may not be perfectly appropriate for every single
case, but we have yet to encounter any other cost index that would form
a better basis for a standard value, nor did any commenters submit any
specific nominations for a more suitable index.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\15\ The model will not apply an explicit inflation rate,
although an annualized rate could be imputed from the model's data.
For example, suppose a $200 cost estimate from 1991 must be adjusted
for inflation to the same day in 1992. The 1991 cost index value is
100, whereas the 1992 index value is 103. The calculation the model
performs is $200 x 103 / 100 = $206 (i.e., multiplying the original
cost estimate by the ratio of the cost index values from the date on
which the cost is actually incurred, and the date on which the
estimate is made). The index change from 1991 to 1992 does represent
an annual inflation rate of three percent (i.e., 103 / 100 = 1.03 -
1 = 0.03), although the model would not directly apply this rate.
The calculation that uses the ratio of the index values is both more
precise and more simple than calculating multiple annual inflation
rates over different periods for historical costs.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The revised BEN model will also allow the user to override the PCI
and instead specify different cost indices for different compliance
components. The table below describes the alternative cost indices.
------------------------------------------------------------------------
Typical
Abbr Full name Description applications
------------------------------------------------------------------------
2.5%...... 2.5-percent constant inflation rate Sensitivity tests;
model testing.
CCI....... Construction Cost Constructions General
Index. costs; based on construction
1.128 tons costs, especially
Portland cement, where labor costs
1,088 bd. ft. 2x4 are a high
lumber, 200 hrs. proportion of
common labor. total costs;
often used for
municipal
wastewater
projects.
ECI....... Employment Cost Employment costs... One-time
Index. nondepreciable
expenditures or
annual costs that
are mainly labor
GDP....... Gross Domestic Economy-wide A very broad,
Product price measure of price economy-wide
deflator. changes. measure of
inflation is
desired.
PCI....... Plant Cost Index... Plant equipment and Standard value.
labor costs.
[[Page 50334]]
PPI....... Producer Price Representative General costs for
Index. producer costs. producers, not
tied to
industrial
process
equipment.
------------------------------------------------------------------------
The user may also override BEN's inflation adjustments for the
capital investment and one-time nondepreciable expenditure, and instead
enter separate estimates for these compliance costs as of the
noncompliance date and compliance date. This customized data entry
could represent another alternative cost index, case-specific inflation
assumptions, or entirely different actions for on-time and delayed
compliance (as discussed in a previous section). For projected future
inflation, the model will project all the cost indices forward in time
at publically available, consensus-oriented forecasted rates.
The standard operation of the model will still entail absolutely no
input whatsoever from the user who is satisfied with BEN's default
values. The other screens for additional data entry and modification
will appear only to those users who selected more advanced options.
6. Discount/Compound Rate
a. Background
Once the compliance cost estimates are adjusted for inflation and
then for taxation, the BEN model must adjust these after-tax cash flows
to a common present value as of the date of noncompliance. The
difference between the two present values (of the on-time and delay
scenarios) is the initial economic benefit as of the noncompliance
date. BEN then compounds this initial economic benefit forward from the
noncompliance date to the penalty payment date to determine the final
economic benefit. A single rate adjusts all present values both
backward and forward in time.\16\ This section addresses only the
calculation of BEN's standard value for this single discount rate,
which was previously based upon a ten-year after-tax weighted average
cost of capital (WACC), with the inputs representing averages across
all industries.\17\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\16\ The Agency received many comments on the use of a single
rate as opposed to two different rates. The notice addresses this
issue in section II. B. 8, Discounting/Compounding Methodology.
\17\ The discount rate standard value for not-for-profits is
based upon municipal bond yields, averaged across the four
investment-quality ratings of Aaa, Aa, A, and Baa. The only comment
EPA received on the not-for-profit discount rate was a suggestion
that municipal economic benefit be calculated using a discount rate
for private entities that perform similar functions (e.g., on a
municipal Clean Water Act case, the discount rate would be the
average WACC for privately owned wastewater treatment plants).
However, because the Agency is trying to calculate the economic
benefit that the municipality and its residents or rate payers have
actually gained, the Agency prefers to use an estimation of the
municipal government's opportunity cost of financing projects, which
is equal to the interest rate on the municipality's bonds. This debt
rate--which forms the basis for the BEN model's not-for-profit
standard value discount rate--will almost always be substantially
lower than the private-sector-equivalent cost of capital. The
discount rate for Federal facilities is based upon the yields from
five-year U.S. Treasury notes.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The WACC is the average of the cost of debt and the cost of equity,
weighted by the portions of debt and equity out of total financing. The
WACC is first calculated for each year, and then the prior version of
BEN averaged these annual values over the most recent ten-year period.
The (after-tax) cost of debt is the average return on corporate bonds
averaged across all industries, and then multiplied by one minus the
highest marginal corporate tax rate (Federal combined with an average
of all States). The cost of equity is based upon the widely used
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), and is equal to a risk-free rate
component plus the expected equity risk premium (i.e., the average
since 1926 of each year's excess stock market return over the risk-free
rate).
b. Final Changes
Based on the June 1999 notice's proposal and the lack of any
objections, the revised BEN model will tailor the standard value
discount rate to the period from the noncompliance date to the penalty
payment date.\18\ The standard value will reference a look-up table,
averaging the annual values over the relevant years. Each individual
annual calculation will be similar to the standard value's previous
methodology.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
\18\ Although the following discussion focuses on the for-profit
discount rate, the tailoring of the discount rate to the relevant
time period would also apply to not-for-profit entities.
\19\ The revised BEN model will implement two relatively minor
changes to the previous model's annual WACC calculation. First, the
previous practice of applying the most recent figure for the
expected equity risk premium to all prior years' calculations will
be replaced with the figure that was actually available at the time
for that specific year's calculation.
The second change is altering the horizon for the equity risk
premium. The standard value previously combined the long-term
Treasury security rate with the long-horizon equity risk premium,
the latter being equal to the average of each year's stock market
return minus the corresponding-maturity risk-free rate. Because the
WACC calculation combines the equity risk premium with the risk-free
rate of the same maturity that is used initially to calculate the
premium, the issue of which horizon premium to use is largely moot.
(The expected deviations of the resulting WACC will thereby be both
small and nonsystematic.) The new calculation will switch to the
intermediate-horizon risk premium (and the corresponding risk-free
rate) as a simple compromise between the long-horizon and short-
horizon.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
The model will also perform additional customizing in a similar
automated fashion. Since BEN will have an input for the violator's
State--thereby customizing the tax rate for compliance costs--that same
customized tax rate will determine the after-tax debt cost component of
the WACC. The model will even select the individual tax rate if the
company is not organized as a C-corporation (as profits and losses from
S-corporations, partnerships, and sole proprietorships flow through to
the owners' individual tax returns).
The standard operation of the model will still entail absolutely no
input whatsoever from the user who is satisfied with BEN's derived WACC
for the discount/compound rate. Another screen to override BEN's
derived rate will appear only to those users who selected such advanced
options.
7. Discounting/Compounding Methodology
a. Background
As stated in the previous section, once the compliance cost
estimates are adjusted for inflation, and then for taxation, the BEN
model must adjust these after-tax cash flows to a common present value
as of the noncompliance date. The difference between the two present
values (of the on-time and delay scenarios) is the initial economic
benefit as of the noncompliance date. BEN then compounds this initial
economic benefit forward from the noncompliance date to the penalty
payment date in order to determine the final economic benefit. BEN uses
a single rate to adjust all present values both backward and forward in
time. Because BEN uses the same rate for going both backward and
forward, this calculation is computationally equivalent to bringing all
cash flows--both past and future--directly to the penalty payment date
at the WACC rate.