Offer Caps in Markets Operated by Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent System Operators, 5951-5965 [2016-01813]

Agencies

[Federal Register Volume 81, Number 23 (Thursday, February 4, 2016)]
[Proposed Rules]
[Pages 5951-5965]
From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
[FR Doc No: 2016-01813]


=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------

DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY

Federal Energy Regulatory Commission

18 CFR Part 35

[Docket No. RM16-5-000]


Offer Caps in Markets Operated by Regional Transmission 
Organizations and Independent System Operators

AGENCY: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Energy.

ACTION: Notice of proposed rulemaking.

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

SUMMARY: The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission is proposing to 
revise its regulations to require that each regional transmission 
organization (RTO) and independent system operator (ISO) cap each 
resource's incremental energy offer to the higher of $1,000/MWh or that 
resource's verified cost-based incremental energy offer.

DATES:  Comments are due April 4, 2016.

ADDRESSES: Comments, identified by docket number, may be filed in the 
following ways:
     Electronic Filing through https://www.ferc.gov. Documents 
created electronically using word processing software should be filed 
in native applications or print-to-PDF format and not in a scanned 
format.
     Mail/Hand Delivery: Those unable to file electronically 
may mail or hand-deliver comments to: Federal Energy Regulatory 
Commission, Secretary of the Commission, 888 First Street NE., 
Washington, DC 20426.
    Instructions: For detailed instructions on submitting comments and 
additional information on the rulemaking process, see the Comment 
Procedures Section of this document.

FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: 
Emma Nicholson (Technical Information), Office of Energy Policy and 
Innovation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street NE., 
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8846, emma.nicholson@ferc.gov.
Pamela Quinlan (Technical Information), Office of Energy Market 
Regulation, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street NE., 
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-6179, pamela.quinlan@ferc.gov.
Anne Marie Hirschberger (Legal Information), Office of the General 
Counsel, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, 888 First Street NE., 
Washington, DC 20426, (202) 502-8387, annemarie.hirschberger@ferc.gov.

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: 

Table of Contents


 
                                                         Paragraph Nos.
 
I. Background........................................                 6.
    A. Offer Caps and Market Power Mitigation in RTOs/                8.
     ISOs............................................
    B. Offer Cap Waivers and Tariff Changes..........                12.
    C. Comments About Offer Caps.....................                18.
        1. Need To Modify the Offer Cap..............                19.
        2. Role of the Offer Cap in Market Power                     23.
         Mitigation..................................
        3. Alternative Offer Cap Designs.............                27.
        4. RTO/ISO Seams and the Offer Cap...........                38.
        5. Other Considerations......................                40.
II. Need for Reform and Commission Proposal..........                42.
    A. Need for Reform...............................                43.

[[Page 5952]]

 
    B. Alternative Offer Cap Proposals Discussed in                  49.
     Comments........................................
    C. Commission Proposal...........................                52.
        1. Offer Cap Structure.......................                53.
        2. Cost-Based Incremental Energy Offer                       56.
         Verification................................
        3. Resource Neutrality.......................                69.
        4. Seams Issues..............................                70.
        5. Other Considerations......................                72.
        6. Comments Sought on This Proposal..........                73.
III. Compliance......................................                74.
IV. Information Collection Statement.................                76.
V. Regulatory Flexibility Act Certification..........                80.
VI. Environmental Analysis...........................                82.
VII. Comment Procedures..............................                83.
VIII. Document Availability..........................                87.
Appendix A:..........................................
List of Short Names/Acronyms of Commenters...........
 


    1. In this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR), the Federal Energy 
Regulatory Commission (Commission) is proposing to revise its 
regulations to require that each regional transmission organization 
(RTO) and independent system operator (ISO) cap each resource's 
incremental energy offer \1\ to the higher of $1,000/MWh or that 
resource's verified cost-based incremental energy offer. Under this 
proposal, verified cost-based incremental energy offers above $1,000/
MWh would be used for purposes of calculating Locational Marginal 
Prices (LMPs).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \1\ The incremental energy offer is the portion of a resource's 
energy supply offer that varies with the output of the generator.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    2. The Commission preliminarily finds that the offer cap \2\ on 
incremental energy offers (offer cap) may no longer be just and 
reasonable for several reasons. The offer cap may unjustly prevent a 
resource from recouping its costs by not permitting that resource to 
include all of its short-run marginal costs within its energy supply 
offer (supply offer). The offer cap may result in unjust and 
unreasonable rates because it can suppress LMPs to a level below the 
marginal cost of production. Further, because of the offer cap, a 
resource with short-run marginal costs above that cap may choose not to 
offer its supply to the RTO/ISO, even though the market may be willing 
to purchase that supply.\3\ Finally, when several resources have short-
run marginal costs above the offer cap but are unable to reflect those 
costs within their incremental energy offers due to the offer cap, the 
RTO/ISO is not able to dispatch the most efficient set of resources 
because it will not have access to the underlying costs associated with 
the multiple incremental energy offers above the offer cap.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \2\ The offer cap for purposes of this NOPR refers to the $/MWh 
limit on day-ahead and real-time incremental energy offers, and not 
any limits or penalty rates that may apply in the capacity or 
ancillary services markets.
    \3\ Resources that are subject to must-offer requirements, such 
as resources with a capacity supply obligation, are required to 
submit a supply offer to the energy market. Many resources are 
subject to must-offer requirements in either the day-ahead or real-
time markets. The proposed reform would ensure that such a resource 
has an economic incentive that matches its tariff obligation. It 
would also provide an economic incentive to those resources that are 
not subject to a must-offer requirement.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    3. To remedy these potential problems associated with the offer 
cap, the Commission proposes to require that each RTO/ISO cap each 
resource's incremental energy offer to the higher of $1,000/MWh or an 
incremental energy offer based on that resource's short-run marginal 
cost (cost-based incremental energy offer). Under the proposal, the 
costs underlying each cost-based incremental energy offer above $1,000/
MWh must be verified before that offer could be used for purposes of 
calculating LMPs. Under this proposal, the Market Monitoring Unit or 
the RTO/ISO, as prescribed in the RTO/ISO tariff and consistent with 
Order No. 719,\4\ must verify the costs within a cost-based incremental 
energy offer.\5\ The proposed offer cap would be resource neutral, that 
is, any resource, regardless of fuel-type, would be eligible to submit 
a cost-based incremental energy offer above $1,000/MWh.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \4\ Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized Electric 
Markets, Order No. 719, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 31,281, at PP 370-375 
(2008), order on reh'g, Order No. 719-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ] 
31,292 (2009), order on reh'g, Order No. 719-B, 129 FERC ] 61,252 
(2009). See also 18 CFR 35.28(g)(3)(iii)(B) (2015).
    \5\ Pursuant to 18 CFR 35.28(g)(3)(iii)(B), either the internal 
or external market monitor can ``provide the inputs required to 
conduct prospective mitigation . . . including, but not limited to 
reference levels, identification of system constraints, and cost 
calculations.'' 18 CFR 35.28(g)(3)(iii)(B) (2015). However, 
prospective mitigation may only be carried out by an internal market 
monitor if the RTO/ISO has a hybrid Market Monitoring Unit 
structure. 18 CFR 35.28(g)(3)(iii)(D) (2015).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    4. The Commission proposes to make a generic change to the offer 
cap applicable to all RTOs/ISOs through a rulemaking to avoid 
exacerbating seams issues. Seams issues could arise if one RTO/ISO has 
an offer cap that materially differed from a neighboring RTO/ISO's 
offer cap. Different offer caps in neighboring RTOs/ISOs could result 
in flows that depend on the level of the two offer caps as opposed to 
economics or reliability needs.
    5. The Commission seeks comment on these proposed reforms sixty 
(60) days after publication of this NOPR in the Federal Register.

I. Background

    6. On June 19, 2014, the Commission initiated the price formation 
proceeding.\6\ In initiating that proceeding, the Commission stated 
that there may be opportunities for the RTOs/ISOs to improve the energy 
and ancillary service price formation process. Staff conducted outreach 
and convened technical workshops on the following four general issues: 
(1) Use of uplift payments; (2) offer price mitigation and offer caps; 
(3) scarcity and shortage pricing; and (4) operator actions that affect 
prices.\7\ During the fall of 2014, Commission staff convened three 
technical workshops and Commission staff issued reports on these 
topics. At the October 28, 2014 technical workshop, Commission staff 
explored, among other topics, the $1,000/MWh offer cap, including the 
purpose of the offer cap and the role it plays in market power 
mitigation.\8\

[[Page 5953]]

While this action proposes to address mitigation relevant to energy 
offers above $1,000/MWh in RTO/ISO markets, the Commission has also 
instructed staff to undertake a more comprehensive review of the market 
power mitigation rules in the RTO/ISO markets.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \6\ Price Formation in Energy and Ancillary Services Markets 
Operated by Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent 
System Operators, Notice, Docket No. AD14-14-000 (June 19, 2014) 
(Price Formation Notice).
    \7\ Id. at 1, 3-4.
    \8\ See Supplemental Notice of Workshop on Price Formation: 
Scarcity and Shortage Pricing, Offer Mitigation, and Offer Caps in 
RTO and ISO Markets, Docket No. AD14-14-000 (Oct. 10, 2014).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    7. Two of the Commission's goals in the price formation proceeding 
are relevant here. First, clearing prices in the energy and ancillary 
services markets should ideally ``reflect the true marginal cost of 
production, taking into account all physical system constraints.'' \9\ 
Second, LMPs should ``ensure that all suppliers have an opportunity to 
recover their costs.'' \10\ Establishing LMPs that accurately reflect 
the marginal cost of production is a central goal of the price 
formation effort. This goal is important because LMPs are an effective 
way to communicate information to market participants about the cost of 
providing the next unit of energy. In the short-run, accurate price 
signals from LMPs are particularly important during high price periods 
because they provide a signal to customers to reduce consumption and a 
signal to suppliers to increase production or to offer new supplies to 
the market. In the long-run, accurate price signals from LMPs are 
important because they inform investment decisions. It is also 
important that RTOs/ISOs give resources the opportunity to recover 
their costs because failing to do so may discourage resources from 
participating in RTO/ISO energy markets. Adequate investment in 
resources and participation of resources in RTO/ISO energy markets are 
necessary to ensure economic and reliable energy for consumers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \9\ Price Formation Notice at 2.
    \10\ See Price Formation in Energy and Ancillary Servs. Mkts. 
Operated by Reg'l Transmission Orgs. & Indep. Sys. Operators, 153 
FERC ] 61,221, at P 2 (2015); see also Price Formation Notice at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

A. Offer Caps and Market Power Mitigation in RTOs/ISOs

    8. Supply offers in day-ahead and real-time energy markets consist 
of both physical components and financial components. The physical 
components of a supply offer describe the resource's physical operating 
parameters, such as its minimum and maximum operating limits in a given 
day-ahead or real-time interval, and are denominated in MW, MWh, time, 
or some combination thereof. The financial components of a supply offer 
are denominated in dollars (e.g., $/start and $/MWh) and represent the 
costs underlying a resource's offer to supply electricity in a given 
interval. The key financial components of a supply offer are the start-
up cost, no-load cost, and incremental energy offers. A resource 
includes its costs that vary with output in its incremental energy 
offer, which typically consists of a supply curve made up of multiple 
(price, quantity) pairs that indicate the price, expressed in $/MWh, 
that a resource is willing to accept to produce a given quantity of 
energy.\11\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \11\ RTOs/ISOs typically restrict incremental energy supply 
curves to ten price and quantity pairs (i.e., ($/MWh, MW)).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    9. The LMP reflects the marginal cost of serving load at a specific 
location, given the set of generators that are dispatched and the 
limitations of the transmission system.\12\ The LMP is calculated by an 
RTO/ISO as the sum of three components: An energy charge, a congestion 
charge, and a charge for transmission losses. The energy and congestion 
components of the LMP are established based on several factors, 
including the marginal resource's incremental energy offer, 
specifically the $/MWh price associated with the MW output of the 
marginal resource.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \12\ See Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Division of 
Energy Market Oversight Office of Enforcement, Energy Primer, at 60 
(Nov. 2015), https://www.ferc.gov/market-oversight/guide/energy-primer.pdf.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    10. All six Commission-jurisdictional RTOs/ISOs have imposed a 
$1,000/MWh cap on incremental energy offers.\13\ The offer cap remains 
at $1,000/MWh in all RTOs/ISOs except PJM because, as discussed further 
below, the Commission recently approved PJM's proposal to raise the 
offer cap on cost-based offers in PJM to $2,000/MWh.\14\ In each RTO/
ISO, a resource's incremental energy offer is subject not only to the 
offer cap, but also to market power mitigation provisions.\15\ The 
Market Monitoring Unit for each RTO/ISO currently oversees, and in some 
cases implements, the market power mitigation provisions. In general, 
when a resource's incremental energy offer is mitigated, that offer is 
replaced with an estimate of a competitive offer or an estimate of that 
resource's short-run marginal cost.\16\ In most instances, once 
mitigated, a resource's offer is eligible to set LMP.\17\ Mechanically, 
the RTOs/ISOs have adopted mitigation rules that either develop a proxy 
for a competitive offer or explicitly estimate short-run marginal cost. 
Because we expect that a competitive offer will closely track a 
resource's short-run marginal cost, both methods for mitigating offers 
should arrive at roughly the same result. The Market Monitoring Units 
in CAISO, MISO, ISO-NE., and NYISO typically mitigate the resource's 
incremental energy offer to the proxy of a competitive offer that is 
calculated by the Market Monitoring Unit.\18\ However, these RTOs/ISOs 
also have provisions whereby the Market Monitoring Unit, often after 
consultation with the resource itself, can estimate the resource's 
short-run marginal cost, which will form the basis of that resource's 
mitigated incremental energy offer. In PJM and SPP, resource owners 
develop cost-based incremental energy offers consistent with the 
requirements of these RTOs' tariffs and business practice manuals and 
those cost-based offers are subject to review by the Market Monitoring 
Unit.\19\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \13\ See, e.g., California Independent System Operator 
Corporation (CAISO), eTariff, 39.6.1.1 (11.0.0); ISO New England 
Inc. (ISO-NE), Transmission, Markets and Services Tariff, Market 
Rule 1, III.1.10.1A(d)(ix), III,1.10.IA(c)(iv), III.2.6(b)(i), and 
III.A.15.1(b) (27.0.0); Midcontinent Independent System Operator, 
Inc. (MISO), FERC Electric Tariff, 39.2.5 (35.0.0), 39.2.5A 
(34.0.0), 39.2.5B (34.0.0), 40.2.5 (35.0.0), 40.2.6 (35.0.0) and 
40.2.7 (33.0.0); New York Independent System Operator, Inc. (NYISO), 
NYISO Tariffs, NYISO Markets and Services Tariff, 21.4 and 21.5.1 
(7.0.0); PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. (PJM), Intra-PJM Tariffs, OATT, 
Tariff Operating Agreement, Attachment K, Appendix, 1.10.1A(d) 
(24.0.0); Southwest Power Pool, Inc. (SPP), OATT, Sixth Revised 
Volume No. 1, Attachment AE, Section 4.1.1 (2.0.0).
    \14\ PJM Interconnection L.L.C., 153 FERC ] 61,289, at P 25 
(2015) (PJM 2015/16 Offer Cap Order). The tariff provisions related 
to the offer cap do not have a sunset date.
    \15\ See 18 CFR 35.28(g)(3)(iii)(B)-(D) (2015).
    \16\ The RTOs/ISOs use different terms for a mitigated offer. 
ISO-NE., MISO, and NYISO mitigate supply offers to a ``Reference 
Level.'' See ISO-NE., Transmission Markets and Services Tariff, 
Market Rule 1, III.A.7.2; MISO FERC Electric Tariff, 64.1.4 
(30.0.0); NYISO, NYISO Tariffs, NYISO Markets and Services Tariff, 
23.3.1.4 (11.0.0). CAISO mitigates supply offers to ``Default Energy 
Bids.'' See CAISO, eTariff, 39.7.1 (11.0.0). PJM mitigates supply 
offers to a ``cost-based offer.'' See PJM Operating Agreement, 
Schedule 1, 1.10.1A (24.0.0) and 6.4.1 (7.0.0). SPP mitigates supply 
offers to a ``Mitigated Energy Bid.'' See SPP OATT, Sixth Revised 
Volume No. 1, Attachment AF, 3.2 (7.0.0). For purposes of this NOPR, 
the offers RTOs/ISOs use for purposes of mitigation will be referred 
to as ``cost-based offers.''
    \17\ There are exceptions to this eligibility, for instance, 
when a resource is committed outside of the market clearing process.
    \18\ See supra n.16.
    \19\ PJM resources develop cost-based offers pursuant to PJM 
Manual 15: Cost Development Guidelines. SPP resources develop 
Mitigated Energy Bids pursuant to SPP's Mitigated Offer Guidelines 
in the SPP Market Protocols.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    11. While the offer cap restricts incremental energy offers, the 
offer cap does not limit LMPs to the level of the offer cap (be it 
$1,000/MWh or $2,000/MWh) because the congestion and loss components of 
the LMP can cause the LMP to exceed the offer cap. Scarcity pricing and 
emergency purchases can

[[Page 5954]]

also cause LMPs to exceed the offer cap even though incremental energy 
offers are limited by the offer cap.

B. Offer Cap Waivers and Tariff Changes

    12. The $1,000/MWh offer cap dates back to 1999 when PJM first 
launched its market.\20\ According to PJM's market monitor, PJM's offer 
cap was then set to a level that stakeholders considered ``beyond the 
possible pale'' of a resource's short-run marginal cost.\21\ PJM states 
that its $1,000/MWh offer cap was never intended to limit incremental 
energy offers below a resource's marginal cost to produce energy.\22\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \20\ See Docket Nos. OA97-261-000 and ER97-1082-000 (Apr. 1, 
1997); Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland Interconnection, 81 FERC ] 
61,257 (1997).
    \21\ Scarcity and Shortage Pricing, Offer Mitigation and Offer 
Caps Workshop, Docket No. AD14-14-000, Tr. 209:18-22 (Oct. 28, 
2014).
    \22\ PJM Comments at 2. All comments cited herein were submitted 
in Docket No. AD14-14-000 on or about March 6, 2015.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    13. Extreme weather during the winter of 2013/14, dubbed the 
``Polar Vortex,'' caused PJM and NYISO to request tariff waivers 
associated with the $1,000/MWh offer cap. During the Polar Vortex, 
various weather-related conditions led to a significant increase in the 
price of natural gas.\23\ Natural gas prices at two key pricing points 
in PJM rose above $120 per million British Thermal Units (MMBtu), which 
could have caused some PJM resources with must-offer requirements to 
operate at a loss because their short-run marginal costs were above the 
$1,000/MWh offer cap.\24\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \23\ See, e.g., FERC Staff, Commission and Industry Actions 
Relevant to Winter 2013-14 Weather Events (Oct. 16, 2014), https://www.ferc.gov/media/news-releases/2014/2014-4/10-16-14-A-4-presentation.pdf.
    \24\ PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 146 FERC ] 61,041, at P 2, 
order on reh'g, 149 FERC ] 61,059 (2014). For example, a natural gas 
resource with a heat rate of 8,350 Btu/kWh could have short-run 
marginal fuel costs above $1,000/MWh if the natural gas price 
exceeds $120/MMBtu.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    14. In response, on January 23, 2014, PJM filed concurrently two 
tariff waiver requests related to its offer cap. In its first request, 
which the Commission granted for the January 24-February 10, 2014 
period, PJM requested that certain resources with cost-based offers 
above $1,000/MWh receive uplift payments to recoup those costs.\25\ In 
its second request, which the Commission granted for the February 11-
March 31, 2014 period, PJM requested that certain resources be allowed 
to submit cost-based offers in excess of $1,000/MWh and cost-based 
offers were used for purposes of calculating LMPs.\26\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \25\ Id. P 1.
    \26\ PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., 146 FERC ] 61,078, at PP 3-4 
(2014).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    15. Similarly, high natural gas prices in New York prompted NYISO 
to file a waiver request related to its offer cap.\27\ Natural gas 
prices at the Transco Zone 6 NY hub in New York rose above $120/MMBtu 
in January 2014. In response, NYISO requested that resources be 
permitted to recover any unrecovered costs above $1,000/MWh through 
uplift payments. The Commission granted NYISO's requested waiver for 
the January 22-February 28, 2014 period.\28\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \27\ N.Y. Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 146 FERC ] 61,061, at PP 
2-4 (2014).
    \28\ Id. P 24.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    16. In the following winter of 2014/15, citing concerns about the 
potential for a repeat of the high natural gas prices experienced 
during the Polar Vortex, PJM and MISO submitted fillings to allow 
recovery of costs above $1,000/MWh during the winter months. Both PJM 
\29\ and MISO \30\ expressed concerns that the $1,000/MWh offer cap 
could prevent a resource from recouping its short-run marginal costs. 
The Commission accepted tariff provisions that temporarily raised PJM's 
offer cap on cost-based offers to $1,800/MWh during the January 16-
March 31, 2015 period.\31\ The Commission granted a waiver that 
permitted resources in MISO to include incremental energy costs in 
excess of $1,000/MWh in the no-load component of their supply offers 
during the December 20, 2014-April 30, 2015 period.\32\ When accepting 
PJM's proposal and granting MISO's waiver request, the Commission 
reasoned that market conditions during the previous 2013/14 winter 
demonstrated that the $1,000/MWh offer cap could prevent resources from 
submitting incremental energy offers that reflect their marginal costs 
and could therefore force resources to offer to sell electricity below 
cost.\33\ Tariff provisions related to the offer cap in both MISO and 
PJM reverted back to their original form in spring 2015.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \29\ PJM Interconnection L.L.C., 150 FERC ] 61,020, at P 5 
(2015) (PJM 2014/15 Offer Cap Order).
    \30\ Midcontinent Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 150 FERC ] 61,083, 
at P 3 (2015) (MISO 2014/15 Offer Cap Order).
    \31\ PJM 2014/15 Offer Cap Order, 150 FERC ] 61,020.
    \32\ MISO 2014/15 Offer Cap Order, 150 FERC ] 61,083.
    \33\ See PJM 2014/15 Offer Cap Order, 150 FERC ] 61,020 at P 34; 
MISO 2014/15 Offer Cap Order, 150 FERC ] 61,083 at P 17.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    17. For the winter of 2015/16, PJM \34\ and MISO \35\ again filed 
requests to modify their respective offer caps. The Commission accepted 
tariff revisions in PJM that would raise the offer cap on cost-based 
offers to $2,000/MWh for purposes of calculating LMPs going 
forward.\36\ In accepting the changes, the Commission reasoned that 
PJM's proposal would send transparent market signals, promote efficient 
resource selection, and address the risks caused by high natural gas 
prices while protecting consumers by requiring cost verification of 
incremental energy offers above $1,000/MWh.\37\ The Commission granted 
MISO's request to waive provisions related to the offer cap for the 
January 1, 2016-April 30, 2016 period. The MISO waiver for the winter 
of 2015/16 was virtually identical to the waiver for the winter of 
2014/15 and allowed MISO resources to include incremental energy costs 
in excess of $1,000/MWh in the no-load component of their offers.\38\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \34\ PJM, Proposed Tariff Revisions, Docket No. ER16-76-000 
(filed Oct. 14, 2015).
    \35\ MISO, Request for Waiver, Docket No. ER16-248-000 (filed 
Nov. 2, 2015).
    \36\ PJM 2015/16 Offer Cap Order, 153 FERC ] 61,289 at P 25. The 
tariff provisions related to the offer cap do not have a sunset 
date.
    \37\ Id. PP 25-26. Resources can submit cost-based offers above 
$2,000/MWh and PJM will use such offers for merit order dispatch, 
but incremental energy offers used for purposes of calculating LMP 
are capped at $2,000/MWh.
    \38\ Midcontinent Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 154 FERC ] 61,006 
(2015) (MISO 2015/16 Offer Cap Order).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

C. Comments About Offer Caps

    18. In its January 2015 notice inviting post-technical workshop 
comments in the price formation proceeding, the Commission asked 
specific questions about the $1,000/MWh offer cap and asked 
stakeholders to comment on various alternative offer cap designs.\39\ 
Comments about the $1,000/MWh offer cap focus on the need to modify the 
offer cap, the role that the offer cap plays in market power 
mitigation, alternative offer cap designs, potential seams issues, and 
other considerations.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \39\ Price Formation in Energy and Ancillary Services Markets 
Operated by Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent 
System Operators, Notice Inviting Post-Technical Workshop Comments, 
Docket No. AD14-14-000, at 2-3 (Jan. 16, 2015). A list of commenters 
and the abbreviated names the Commission will use for them in this 
document appears in Appendix A.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

1. Need To Modify the Offer Cap
    19. Commenters differ about the need to raise or remove the $1,000/
MWh offer cap. Several commenters argue that the $1,000/MWh offer cap 
should be raised or removed entirely, given recent occurrences of high 
natural gas prices.

[[Page 5955]]

Some commenters cite the recent offer cap waiver orders as evidence 
that the current offer cap is not just and reasonable.\40\ Several 
commenters reference the Polar Vortex in the winter of 2013/14, when 
resources experienced marginal production costs in excess of $1,000/
MWh, as evidence that the current offer cap is inappropriate.\41\ For 
example, OMS states that it is appropriate to consider an upward 
revision or removal of the offer cap to ensure supply adequacy during 
extreme events such as those that occurred during the winter of 2013/
14.\42\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \40\ ANGA Comments at 2; Brookfield Comments at 7; EPSA Comments 
at 24; Entergy Nuclear Power Marketing Comments at 11-12; Exelon 
Comments at 10-11; PJM Comments at 2-3; PJM Power Providers Comments 
at 2-4; SPP Comments at 1; Western Power Trading Forum Comments at 
5-6.
    \41\ EPSA Comments at 21-24; Exelon Comments at 10-12; OMS 
Comments at 2; PJM Comments at 2-3; PJM Power Providers Comments at 
2.
    \42\ OMS Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    20. Several commenters also assert that the offer cap distorts 
price signals and creates market inefficiencies.\43\ Commenters state 
that the offer cap artificially suppresses clearing prices.\44\ Some 
commenters believe that the offer cap restricts market participants 
from receiving appropriate compensation for costs incurred 
legitimately.\45\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \43\ PJM Utilities Coalition Comments at 3-4; Western Power 
Trading Forum Comments at 5.
    \44\ Direct Energy Comments at 2; EPSA Comments at 21.
    \45\ ANGA Comments at 2-3; Xcel Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    21. Several commenters stress that the offer cap should be high 
enough to ensure that resources can reflect their actual costs in 
supply offers.\46\ EPSA maintains that the offer cap was never intended 
to suppress marginal cost bidding.\47\ MISO states that the offer cap 
should be modified to ensure that all resources are able to recover at 
least the costs they incur to produce energy.\48\ MISO and PJM contend 
that an offer cap that prevents resource cost recovery can increase the 
likelihood that resources will be unavailable to system operators.\49\ 
SPP and Western Power Trading Forum state that raising the offer cap 
might reduce out-of-market operator actions and uplift.\50\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \46\ ANGA Comments at 2; Brookfield Comments at 7; Entergy 
Nuclear Power Marketing Comments at 11-12; ISO-NE Comments at 5; IRC 
Comments at 2-3; MISO Comments at 4; PJM Comments at 2; PJM Power 
Providers Group Comments at 2-4; Potomac Economics Comments at 3; 
Powerex Comments at 29-30; PSEG Companies Comments at 5-6; Western 
Power Trading Forum Comments at 5-6.
    \47\ EPSA Comments at 21-22.
    \48\ MISO Comments at 4.
    \49\ Id.; PJM Comments at 2.
    \50\ SPP Comments at 1; Western Power Trading Forum Comments at 
5-6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    22. Some commenters oppose modifying the $1,000/MWh offer cap.\51\ 
CAISO, ISO-NE, and NYISO assert that, because resource marginal costs 
are well below $1,000/MWh, there is no evidence that the $1,000/MWh 
offer cap should be raised in their respective markets.\52\ CAISO 
opposes any effort to increase the offer cap until sufficient benefits 
are identified.\53\ NCPA, PG&E, and SCE state that the current offer 
cap ensures just and reasonable rates and mitigates market power in 
CAISO.\54\ NCPA and SCE state that the offer cap is sufficient in CAISO 
because generators there have never experienced costs above $1,000/
MWh.\55\ SCE adds that the marginal cost of the least efficient CAISO 
resource at the highest natural gas price seen in the region is only 
$390/MWh.\56\ APPA and NRECA assert that there is insufficient 
justification to remove offer caps nationwide.\57\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \51\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 30; CAISO Comments at 3; ELCON 
Comments at 6.
    \52\ CAISO Comments at 3; ISO-NE Comments at 3 & n.2; NYISO 
Comments at 4.
    \53\ CAISO Comments at 3.
    \54\ NCPA Comments at 2; PG&E Comments at 3; SCE Comments at 3; 
see also California State Water Project Comments at 2; New York 
Transmission Owners Comments at 2.
    \55\ NCPA Comments at 2-3; SCE Comments at 2.
    \56\ SCE Comments at 2. According to SCE, the $390/MWh figure 
assumes a heat rate of 17,000 Btu/kWh, slightly higher than the 
least efficient unit in CAISO, and a natural gas price of $23/MMBtu.
    \57\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 32.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. Role of the Offer Cap in Market Power Mitigation
    23. At the October 28, 2014 price formation technical workshop, 
several market monitors discussed the backstop role that the $1,000/MWh 
offer cap plays in market power mitigation. NYISO's internal market 
monitor stated that the offer cap provided a ``backstop'' assurance to 
protect consumers in the event that NYISO's market mitigation measures 
fail.\58\ Similarly, ISO-NE's internal market monitor stated that the 
offer cap is a device that limits the potential damage to consumers or 
the market in the event that market power mitigation measures are 
unsuccessful.\59\ CAISO's internal market monitor stated that the offer 
cap primarily functions as a ``damage control cap'' but also noted that 
the offer cap affects the penalty prices of constraints in CAISO's 
market software.\60\ Potomac Economics, which serves as an external 
market monitor for MISO, ISO-NE., and NYISO, stated that the offer cap 
is too high to address general market power concerns, but explained 
that the offer cap addresses gaming strategies that market participants 
may engage in to collect undue uplift payments.\61\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \58\ Scarcity and Shortage Pricing, Offer Mitigation and Offer 
Caps Workshop, Docket No. AD14-14-000, Tr. 205:6-15 (Oct. 28, 2014).
    \59\ Id. at 206:24-207:7.
    \60\ Id. at 210:14-23.
    \61\ Id. at 211:25-212:14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    24. In response to the Commission's request for comments on price 
formation topics, several commenters suggest that the offer cap's 
purpose has been supplanted by improvements in market monitoring and 
mitigation and the Commission's enforcement activity.\62\ Wisconsin 
Electric asserts that the offer cap is irrelevant because RTO/ISO 
market monitors have effective mitigation measures in place and can 
refer suspected manipulation to the Commission's Office of 
Enforcement.\63\ Direct Energy states that an offer cap is not 
necessary when resources cannot exercise market power because 
competition will discipline offers.\64\ GDF SUEZ argues that offer caps 
are the least efficient method of protection against uncompetitive 
offers because offer caps are indifferent to the specifics of a supply 
offer and do not reflect potentially changed circumstances since the 
offer cap level was established over ten years ago.\65\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \62\ ANGA Comments at 2-3; Entergy Nuclear Power Marketing 
Comments at 11; EPSA Comments at 22-23; Exelon Comments at 11-12; 
Wisconsin Electric Comments at 2-3; Xcel Comments at 2.
    \63\ Wisconsin Electric Comments at 2.
    \64\ Direct Energy Comments at 2.
    \65\ GDF SUEZ Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    25. Several other commenters assert that the offer cap is a 
backstop measure to protect consumers against the exercise of market 
power during tight system conditions.\66\ Other commenters emphasize 
the importance of strengthening market monitoring and mitigation 
provisions if offer caps are eliminated or increased.\67\ ISO-NE 
asserts that while the offer cap has become less important with market 
power mitigation, the offer cap still serves as a ``fail-safe'' 
mechanism to protect consumers in the unlikely event that the market is 
not competitive and market power mitigation fails to assure competitive 
supply offers.\68\ OMS warns that any effort to raise or remove the 
offer cap must be based on the Commission's confidence not only in the 
ability of RTO/ISO market power mitigation provisions to prevent

[[Page 5956]]

generator market power abuses, but also in whether the prices of input 
costs were developed in a competitive market.\69\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \66\ ISO-NE Comments at 4; MISO Comments at 5-6; New York 
Transmission Owners Comments at 2-3; NYISO Comments at 3; TAPS 
Comments at 10-11; California State Water Project Comments at 2-3.
    \67\ Direct Energy Comments at 2; MISO Comments at 9; NCPA 
Comments at 3; New York Transmission Owners Comments at 4; Wisconsin 
Electric Comments at 2-3.
    \68\ ISO-NE Comments at 4.
    \69\ OMS Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    26. Potomac Economics maintains that the offer cap is necessary to 
keep resources from exploiting any previously unknown flaws in market 
rules.\70\ Some commenters assert that due to load's inelastic demand 
for electricity, offer caps are necessary to protect consumers from 
excessive prices and to maintain confidence that rate structures are 
fair and nondiscriminatory.\71\ TAPS states that on normal days when 
there are no generators with marginal costs ``anywhere close to'' 
$1,000/MWh, there are still 3,000 to 4,000 MW offered at the offer 
cap.\72\ TAPS suggests that weakening the offer cap is particularly 
dangerous because energy markets cannot be halted, so if widespread 
abuse occurs, after-the-fact resettlements incur massive costs and 
diversion of resources.\73\ APPA and NRECA assert that the offer cap 
should only be increased if RTOs/ISOs can guarantee that all offers are 
cost-based in order to guarantee appropriate prices and prevent the 
need to re-run markets after-the-fact.\74\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \70\ Potomac Economics Comments at 3-4.
    \71\ ELCON Comments at 6; TAPS Comments at 10-11.
    \72\ TAPS Comments at 12-13 (citing Scarcity and Shortage 
Pricing, Offer Mitigation and Offer Caps Workshop, Docket No. AD14-
14-000, Tr. 217:17-21 (Oct. 28, 2014)).
    \73\ TAPS Comments at 11 (citing Written Statement of Patrick T. 
Connors on Behalf of WPPI Energy and the Transmission Access Policy 
Study Group Regarding Impacts of Offer Caps and Market Power 
Mitigation, at 5 (Dec. 3, 2014)).
    \74\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 31-32.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Alternative Offer Cap Designs
    27. In its January 2015 notice inviting post-technical workshop 
comments in the price formation proceeding, the Commission sought 
comment on potential alternative offer cap designs, including (1) 
maintaining the $1,000/MWh offer cap and compensating resources for 
incremental energy costs above the $1,000/MWh offer cap through uplift; 
(2) adopting a floating offer cap that changes with natural gas prices; 
(3) raising the offer cap to a higher fixed level; and (4) allowing 
resources to submit cost-based offers above $1,000/MWh and allowing 
verified cost-based offers above $1,000/MWh to set LMP.
a. Maintain Current Offer Cap With Uplift
    28. Some commenters assert that infrequent events where production 
costs exceed $1,000/MWh can be addressed effectively through uplift 
payments without raising the offer cap or otherwise including such 
costs in the LMP.\75\ APPA and NRECA state they support generator 
recovery of legitimate and verified costs but assert that such costs 
should not necessarily be included in LMP.\76\ APPA and NRECA add that 
uplift will ensure cost recovery without risking market power abuse and 
what APPA and NRECA say would be the attendant increased unjust and 
unreasonable rates.\77\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \75\ Id. at 29-31; California State Water Project Comments at 2-
3; New York Transmission Owners Comments at 2-3.
    \76\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 31.
    \77\ Id. at 31.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    29. APPA and NRECA assert that the market clearing process does not 
allow sufficient time to verify whether incremental energy offers above 
$1,000/MWh are in fact cost-based; thus, these commenters argue, such 
cost verification should occur after-the-fact, with costs in excess of 
the offer cap recovered through uplift.\78\ SCE and PG&E state that 
CAISO has tools to accommodate the rare instances when the $1,000/MWh 
offer cap is insufficient to recover a resource's costs.\79\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \78\ Id. at 31-32.
    \79\ PG&E Comments at 3-4; SCE Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

b. Floating Offer Cap
    30. Several commenters support a floating offer cap that changes 
with generator input costs, such as the price of natural gas. Calpine 
asserts that offer caps should be flexible and responsive to changes in 
natural gas prices,\80\ and recommends that the Commission encourage 
each RTO/ISO to implement a floating offer cap.\81\ Powerex suggests 
that the offer cap could equal the higher of $1,000/MWh or some 
multiple of a pre-defined regional natural gas index.\82\ SPP states 
that a seasonal fixed offer cap might be appropriate.\83\ Similarly, 
OMS maintains that the offer cap need not be constant throughout the 
year if resource costs vary throughout the year.\84\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \80\ Calpine Comments at 4-6.
    \81\ Id. at 21.
    \82\ Powerex Comments at 30.
    \83\ SPP Comments at 1.
    \84\ OMS Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    31. ISO-NE and MISO, however, argue that a floating offer cap would 
be difficult to implement.\85\ ISO-NE opposes basing the offer cap on 
an index that attempts to track fuel prices, arguing that doing so 
would be complex and difficult to implement because intra-day natural 
gas indices are opaque and day-ahead natural gas indices, while 
arguably less opaque, can become ``stale'' during the operating 
day.\86\ MISO argues that although it may consider a floating offer cap 
in the longer term, a transition to such an offer cap would likely 
require substantial system changes.\87\ ISO-NE asserts that if the 
Commission is concerned that a fixed offer cap lacks flexibility, the 
Commission should revisit the offer cap over time as the markets for 
the major fuels used in power generation continue to evolve.\88\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \85\ ISO-NE Comments at 4-6; MISO Comments at 5-7.
    \86\ ISO-NE Comments at 6.
    \87\ MISO Comments at 5-6.
    \88\ ISO-NE Comments at 6-7.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

c. Higher Fixed Offer Cap
    32. Some commenters support raising the offer cap to a higher 
level. ANGA states that, at a minimum, the offer cap should be 
increased significantly to reduce unnecessary market distortions.\89\ 
Exelon argues that the current $1,000/MWh cap on market-based offers in 
PJM should be eliminated, but maintains that, if the offer cap remains 
in place, it should be raised to account for the highest reasonably 
expected offer, and that cost-based offers should be allowed to exceed 
the market-based offer cap.\90\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \89\ ANGA Comments at 3.
    \90\ Exelon Comments at 12.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    33. If the Commission chooses to raise the offer cap, ISO-NE urges 
using a simple numerical value rather than a more complicated 
formula.\91\ ISO-NE is neutral on raising the offer cap but suggests 
that any changes to the offer cap level be made in a straightforward 
manner so that participants know with certainty what the offer cap will 
be when they make advance fuel-supply arrangements.\92\ MISO does not 
oppose raising the offer cap but favors a fixed offer cap to a floating 
offer cap in the short term.\93\ MISO states that a fixed offer cap 
simplifies the process of implementing related market mechanisms such 
as scarcity or shortage pricing, ancillary services, and transmission 
demand curves and notes that MISO's current market software systems 
were designed based upon a fixed offer cap.\94\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \91\ ISO-NE Comments at 6.
    \92\ Id. at 3-4.
    \93\ MISO Comments at 4-5.
    \94\ Id. at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    34. TAPS asserts that permanently increasing the offer cap to allow 
incremental energy offers above $1,000/MWh ``day-in and day-out'' would 
sacrifice the benefits of the current offer cap as a ``backstop'' 
protection against market power abuse to address ``extreme 
circumstances'' that rarely, if ever,

[[Page 5957]]

occur.\95\ APPA and NRECA argue that it is not necessary to increase 
the offer cap broadly because APPA and NRECA say there is no evidence 
that the $1,000/MWh offer cap is persistently flawed.\96\ APPA and 
NRECA add that resources' incremental energy offers only exceeded 
$1,000/MWh in PJM on ``just a few days in one month of one year.'' \97\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \95\ TAPS Comments at 13.
    \96\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 30-31.
    \97\ Id. at 30-31.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

d. Permitting Cost-Based Incremental Energy Offers Above $1,000/MWh
    35. Some commenters argue that cost-based incremental energy offers 
should not be capped.\98\ PJM states that cost-based offers should not 
be subject to offer caps because offer caps impose arbitrary 
limits.\99\ PJM suggests that one approach may be to set a market-based 
offer cap on an annual basis at some percentage above the highest cost-
based incremental energy offer from previous time periods.\100\ PJM 
Power Providers and PSEG Companies assert that cost-based offers should 
not be capped and should be eligible to set the LMP.\101\ APPA and 
NRECA state that if the Commission wishes to revise the offer cap, it 
should limit any increase in the offer cap to periods when production 
costs exceed $1,000/MWh and ensure that any changes to the offer cap 
are accompanied by assurances that protect consumers against market 
power abuse.\102\ Although TAPS does not support increasing the $1,000/
MWh offer cap, TAPS similarly states that if the Commission wants to 
take temporary or seasonal action, the Commission should at the very 
least require that any incremental energy offer above $1,000/MWh be 
verified by the market monitor to be cost-justified.\103\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \98\ Direct Energy Comments at 2; Exelon Comments at 12; PJM 
Comments at 3; PJM Power Providers Comments at 3-4; PSEG Companies 
Comments at 5.
    \99\ PJM Comments at 2-3.
    \100\ Id. at 4.
    \101\ PJM Power Providers Comments at 4; PSEG Companies Comments 
at 6.
    \102\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 30-32.
    \103\ TAPS Comments at 13-14.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    36. APPA and NRECA, CAISO and NCPA, however, argue that cost-based 
incremental offers must be verified before the market clears in order 
to avoid potentially disruptive after-the-fact corrections to clearing 
prices, and these commenters raise concerns that it is not feasible to 
do so.\104\ CAISO does not believe there is a firm basis to verify the 
natural gas price included in supply offers because market participants 
might not purchase natural gas before submitting offers and because 
natural gas quotes might not be available. CAISO also states that 
natural gas prices and quotes may be subject to manipulation, thereby 
making fuel cost verification difficult.\105\ CAISO requests that if 
the Commission directs RTOs/ISOs to pay resources uplift for fuel costs 
above the offer cap, then only incremental fuel costs associated with 
the incremental energy offer be reimbursable. In contrast, CAISO states 
that costs such as natural gas pooling, imbalance penalties, or risk 
premiums should be recovered through capacity payments.\106\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \104\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 32; CAISO Comments at 6-7, NCPA 
Comments at 2.
    \105\ CAISO Comments at 4-6.
    \106\ Id. at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    37. TAPS contends that advance review and verification of cost-
based incremental offers should be possible for most generators.\107\ 
Direct Energy states that RTOs/ISOs have sufficient time to verify 
natural gas costs in the day-ahead and real-time markets and suggests 
that LMPs can be ``flagged'' and revised after-the-fact should the 
RTOs/ISOs have any concerns.\108\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \107\ TAPS Comments at 14-15.
    \108\ Direct Energy Comments at 3-4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

4. RTO/ISO Seams and the Offer Cap
    38. Most commenters state that offer caps should be the same for 
each RTO/ISO, to minimize potential seams issues.\109\ IRC, PJM, and 
PSEG Companies assert that transmission congestion and other market-to-
market coordination will be disrupted if offer caps differ across 
markets.\110\ ISO-NE and NYISO contend that different offer caps in 
neighboring markets could create perverse interchange flows resulting 
from the level of the offer caps instead of based on economic merit or 
reliability needs.\111\ NYISO states that materially different offer 
caps between regions that depend on the same natural gas supply could 
require out-of-market operator actions to avoid reliability issues when 
natural gas prices are high.\112\ MISO maintains that consistent offer 
caps across RTOs/ISOs will also establish consistent shortage pricing 
between neighboring RTOs/ISOs.\113\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \109\ Brookfield Comments at 8; Calpine Comments at 5; EEI 
Comments at 9; EPSA Comments at 21; Exelon Comments at 13-14; IRC 
Comments at 2; ISO-NE Comments at 6-7; MISO Comments at 8; New York 
Transmission Owners Comments at 3-4; NYISO Comments at 4; PJM 
Comments at 4; PJM Power Providers Comments at 5-6; PJM Utilities 
Coalition Comments at 6; PSEG Companies Comments at 6-7; Potomac 
Economics Comments at 5; Western Power Trading Forum Comments at 6; 
Wisconsin Electric Comments at 4.
    \110\ IRC Comments at 2; PJM Comments at 4; PSEG Companies 
Comments at 6-7.
    \111\ ISO-NE Comments at 7; NYISO Comments at 5.
    \112\ NYISO Comments at 4-5.
    \113\ MISO Comments at 8.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    39. In contrast, APPA and NRECA and NCPA state that offer cap 
levels should be set according to the needs of each individual RTO/
ISO.\114\ APPA and NRECA assert that the Commission should only 
consider raising the offer cap on a region-by-region basis where the 
evidence demonstrates a need for a higher offer cap.\115\ Direct Energy 
and PJM Utilities Coalition, respectively, state that different offer 
caps may be appropriate if the RTOs/ISOs use the same methodology to 
determine the offer caps or where the different offer cap levels 
represent true differences in cost.\116\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \114\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 29-30; NCPA Comments at 3.
    \115\ APPA and NRECA Comments at 32.
    \116\ Direct Energy Comments at 4; PJM Utilities Coalition 
Comments at 6.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

5. Other Considerations
    40. CAISO and MISO note that the offer cap level impacts other 
market parameters that affect LMPs, such as penalty prices associated 
with violating thermal or operating constraints that are contained in 
the RTO/ISO software used to calculate LMPs. SCE explains that when 
CAISO relaxes a transmission constraint, it uses the offer cap to set 
the congestion price.\117\ CAISO states it would have to increase 
constraint penalty prices, currently set to levels above the offer cap, 
to ensure that the market operators would dispatch economic offers 
prior to relaxing transmission constraints.\118\ MISO notes that some 
market parameters may be intrinsically tied to the maximum LMP in the 
energy market, including transmission constraint demand curves, 
emergency or scarcity pricing regimes, and some pricing of ancillary 
services.\119\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \117\ SCE Comments at 2.
    \118\ CAISO Comments at 5.
    \119\ MISO Comments at 5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    41. IRC and New York Transmission Owners state that changing the 
offer cap could affect natural gas markets.\120\ New York Transmission 
Owners argue that allowing higher offers to set the LMP might increase 
the price generators will pay for spot natural gas beyond competitive 
levels since there is no mitigation procedure to test whether resources 
paid too much for natural gas.\121\ IRC states that the Commission 
should focus on ensuring transparency and flexibility in natural gas 
markets to

[[Page 5958]]

assist RTOs/ISOs with gas price verification and to ameliorate natural 
gas price spikes.\122\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \120\ IRC Comments at 3; New York Transmission Owners Comments 
at 5.
    \121\ New York Transmission Owners Comments at 5.
    \122\ IRC Comments at 3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

II. Need for Reform and Commission Proposal

    42. In the following section, the Commission first explains the 
need to reform the current offer caps. The Commission next summarizes 
the alternative proposals that the Commission considered but declined 
to adopt. Finally, the Commission describes its proposal and the three 
requirements that underlie it.

A. Need for Reform

    43. As stated above, five of the six Commission-jurisdictional 
RTOs/ISOs currently have a $1,000/MWh offer cap.\123\ As noted 
previously, PJM currently has a $2,000/MWh offer cap on cost-based 
incremental energy offers used for purposes of calculating LMPs.\124\ 
When the Commission first accepted these offer caps, the Commission did 
so, in many instances, as temporary measures until larger market 
reforms were implemented.\125\ The offer caps have persisted, and are 
now viewed as a component of the market power mitigation measures 
adopted by RTOs/ISOs.\126\ The Commission has reviewed the offer caps 
and preliminarily finds that the offer caps currently in effect in all 
RTOs/ISOs are unjust and unreasonable for several reasons.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \123\ See supra P 10.
    \124\ See supra P 17.
    \125\ See, e.g., Midwest Indep. Transmission Sys. Operator, 
Inc., 108 FERC ] 61,163, at PP 380-381, order on reh'g, 109 FERC ] 
61,157 (2004), order on clarification, 111 FERC ] 61,367 (2005); 
N.Y. Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 97 FERC ] 61,095, at 61,496-97 
(2001); ISO New England, Inc., 97 FERC ] 61,090, at 61,471.
    \126\ See supra PP 23-26.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    44. First, the offer cap can prevent a resource from recouping its 
short-run marginal costs. With the current $1,000/MWh offer cap, a 
resource whose short-run marginal cost exceeds $1,000/MWh may operate 
at a loss. For example, in January 2014, resources in PJM faced high 
natural gas prices that caused their short-run marginal costs to exceed 
the $1,000/MWh offer cap in place at the time.\127\ Similarly, MISO 
states that high natural gas prices in January and March 2014 caused 
some MISO resources to experience costs in excess of the $1,000/MWh 
offer cap.\128\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \127\ PJM 2014/15 Offer Cap Order, 150 FERC ] 61,020 at P 2.
    \128\ MISO 2014/15 Offer Cap Order, 150 FERC ] 61,083 at P 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    45. Second, the offer cap can impair price formation because it can 
result in LMPs that are suppressed below the marginal cost of 
production. An LMP that is less than the marginal cost of production 
may not be just and reasonable because it sends an inaccurate signal to 
load about the actual cost of producing the electricity, and to 
resources about the value of the next increment of supply. For example, 
if the marginal resource at a given location has a $1,100/MWh short-run 
marginal cost but faces a $1,000/MWh cap, that resource's incremental 
energy offer will be constrained to $1,000/MWh, and as a result, the 
energy component of LMP will be $100/MWh below the marginal cost of 
production. In a properly functioning market, the LMP should accurately 
reflect the costs of serving load and both customers and resources will 
be aware of that cost through an accurate and transparent price signal.
    46. Third, the offer cap may discourage resources from offering 
their supply to the RTO/ISO when their short-run marginal costs exceed 
the offer cap, even though market participants may be willing to 
purchase that supply. For example, a resource may not be subject to a 
must-offer requirement, and thus be under no obligation to offer its 
supply to the energy market and therefore simply decide not to offer 
its supply to the market if its short-run marginal cost exceeds the 
offer cap. Both PJM and MISO state that an offer cap that prevents cost 
recovery can reduce the likelihood that resources with short-run 
marginal costs above the cap will offer their supply to the RTO/
ISO.\129\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \129\ MISO Comments at 4; PJM Comments at 2.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    47. Fourth and finally, if several resources have short-run 
marginal costs above $1,000/MWh, the $1,000/MWh offer cap requires 
those resources to submit incremental energy offers equal to $1,000/
MWh, even if the resources face different costs. Under this scenario, 
the $1,000/MWh offer cap will prevent the RTO/ISO from observing the 
cost differences among these resources and the RTO/ISO will not be able 
to select the most efficient resources because the resources with costs 
above $1,000/MWh were not able to submit incremental energy offers 
consistent with their short-run marginal cost. For these reasons, the 
Commission preliminarily finds that the current offer caps result in 
rates that are unjust and unreasonable. In addition, these reasons 
illustrate that the current offer caps may not achieve the price 
formation goals discussed above.
    48. The Commission considered several alternatives to achieve the 
price formation goals. On balance, the Commission has preliminarily 
determined that the alternative that best achieves the price formation 
goals is to retain the existing $1,000/MWh offer cap except in 
circumstances when a resource has verifiable short-run marginal costs 
in excess of $1,000/MWh. The discussion at the technical workshop and 
subsequent comments received suggest that the $1,000/MWh offer cap is 
appropriate in most circumstances and serves as an appropriate backstop 
to the existing market power mitigation rules. However, recent 
experience also suggests that some resources may face short-run 
marginal costs greater than $1,000/MWh and, in such infrequent 
circumstances, the $1,000/MWh offer cap inappropriately limits those 
resources' incremental energy offers and the resulting LMP. To the 
extent incremental energy offers can be verified, we believe a generic 
reform to allow offers and LMPs to exceed $1,000/MWh will enhance 
market efficiency and mitigate the potential for seams issues.

B. Alternative Offer Cap Proposals Discussed in Comments

    49. This section briefly discusses why the Commission has not 
proposed the other alternative offer cap designs. The Commission is not 
proposing the alternative that uses uplift payments to compensate 
resources with costs above the offer cap because, while uplift payments 
may ensure that a resource recoups its costs, such a proposal would not 
ensure that LMPs accurately reflect the marginal cost of production--a 
key goal of the price formation effort.\130\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \130\ Price Formation in Energy and Ancillary Services Markets 
Operated by Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent 
System Operators, Notice Inviting Post-Technical Workshop Comments, 
Docket No. AD14-14-000, at 2 (Jan. 16, 2015).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    50. The Commission is not proposing a floating offer cap that would 
change with natural gas prices. This alternative proposal would be 
unduly preferential to natural gas-fueled resources and discriminatory 
towards resources that do not use natural gas as fuel because such a 
cap would only vary with the cost inputs of resources that use natural 
gas as fuel. As such, this alternative proposal could prevent a 
resource that does not use natural gas as a fuel to generate 
electricity from submitting a legitimate cost-based incremental energy 
offer if that offer is above the natural gas-based floating cap. 
Although natural gas fueled resources are currently the most likely 
resources to have short-run marginal costs above $1,000/MWh, this may 
not always be

[[Page 5959]]

the case. Furthermore, setting the offer cap for all resources based on 
the price of natural gas would allow non-natural gas resources to 
submit offers above $1,000/MWh and below the natural-gas based offer 
cap with no cost basis for doing so, thereby potentially allowing them 
to exercise market power when natural gas prices rise but when these 
resources' costs do not similarly rise.
    51. Finally, the Commission is not proposing to raise the offer cap 
to a higher fixed level. A higher fixed offer cap could still limit a 
resource's increment
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.